Decentralisation of GST services and vertical imbalances in Pakistan.
Ara, Iffat ; Sabir, Muhammad
In Pakistan, provincial finances largely hinge on federal transfers
from the divisible pool via the National Finance Commission (NFC) Award.
While provincial share in tax revenue is less than 5 percent, provincial
share in expenditure is over 25 percent, indicating dependence on
federal transfers and the extent of vertical fiscal imbalance. The
sustainability of public services provided by the provinces requires
enough "own" revenues rather than reliance on federal
transfers and grants. The 7th NFC Award and the 18th Constitutional
Amendment reinforce the constitutional rights of the provinces to
collect GST services. However, tax decentralisation is a complex issue
in management of public finances in Pakistan. Its implementation seems
difficult due to various factors like the difficulty to distinguish
sales tax revenues from goods and services. This paper is an attempt to
analyse the role of GST services in minimising vertical imbalances. The
findings suggest that the vertical fiscal imbalance can be minimised by
shifting the collection of GST services from the federal government to
the provincial governments. They indicate that with full provincial
share of GST services, provincial share in taxes would have doubled
during 2006-10.
JEL classification: H71, H77, H21
Keywords: GST Service, Vertical Imbalances, Tax Decentralisation,
Intergovernment Fiscal Relations
1. INTRODUCTION
It is generally believed that the 7th National Finance Commission
(NFC) Award and 18th Constitutional Amendment have taken a major step
towards much needed fiscal decentralisation. While these two delegate more fiscal autonomy and transfers additional resources towards
provinces, it seems difficult that tax decentralisation options provided
in these two can practically be implemented. This assertion is based on
historical tax decentralisation debate in Pakistan, which has made it a
very complex issue in management of public finances.
There are arguments both in favour and against tax decentralisation
in Pakistan. Its proponents argue that tax decentralisation is an
important principle of governance. They generally propose three
advantages of fiscal decentralisation including; preference-matching,
efficiency through competition, and increased accountability. In
particular, a rational assignment of taxing powers helps providing each
level of government, a control over its fiscal destiny by allowing it
the choice in the level of spending. It helps assuring taxpayers that
they are getting what they paid for and consequently may stimulate
participation and improve/increase accountability. According to Bahl
(1999), fiscal decentralisation assists in revenue mobilisation,
innovation in economic activity, accountability of elected officials and
grassroots participation in governance. Given this, it is probable that
fiscal decentralisation lead towards improved efficiency in the use of
resources as the residents in the sub-national governments can decide
about their desired mix of public services and revenues that best suits
them.
On the other hand, its opponents counter argue that its
implementation seems difficult due to various factors like provincial
governments do not have capacity to collect taxes, and the bulk of the
taxes in Pakistan are usually paid at the headquarters of the firm that
may lead to an unfair allocation of revenues after decentralisation. At
the same time, the tax administration in Pakistan desires to move from
General Sales Tax (GST) to reformed GST in Value Added Tax (VAT) mode in
order to increase the tax-to-GDP ratio. Implementation of this would
make the tax decentralisation much more complicated as it is difficult
to distinguish the sales tax revenues from goods and services as a good
producing factory also consume many services including
telecommunication. Furthermore, as highlighted by Ahmed (2010) the
abject performance of FBR and "trust deficit" among provinces
and with the federal government add more complications in the
practicality of GST reforms.
Despite these contradictory arguments, attempts were made to
analyse the scope of sales tax on services by provincial governments to
enhance tax-to-GDP ratio in Pakistan. SPDC (1994) is a systematic
attempt which provides a comprehensive framework for sales taxation of
services by provincial governments. It analysed the constitutional
domain for implementing sales tax on services as per 1973 constitution.
It also looked at the incidence of indirect taxes on services and
concluded that nominal incidence of federal and provincial taxes on
services sector was 2.3 percent of their value added. It also laid down
a criterion for provincial resource mobilisation through effective
implementation of GST on services. The criterion gave higher weight-age
to under taxation, extent of incidence on richer households, case for
integration with national VAT, level of compliance, ease of collection
and so on. It also proposed specific taxation proposals for services
sector including banking and insurance, wholesale and retail,
telecommunication and others. Regardless of such attempts, in 2000, the
provincial governments empowered federal government to implement GST
services. Since then GST services is being collected by the Federal
Board of Revenue (FBR).
At present, in Pakistan financial status of provincial governments
largely hinges on federal transfers to the provinces constituted through
NFC award rather than on a rational tax assignment. There is an
overriding centralisation of revenue collection as over 90 percent of
the revenues are collected at the federal level consequently leaving the
provinces with very narrow tax bases. From the perspective of
sustainable public service provision, the provincial governments require
enough "own" revenues rather than heavily relying on federal
transfers and grants. GST on services is an ideal option for
decentralisation ensured by the 18th Constitutional Amendment and 7th
NFC Award.
In this context, this paper is an attempt to analyse the devolution of GST services and vertical imbalance in Pakistan. It determines the
scope of GST services in minimising vertical imbalances, if implemented
practically. Since, GST services has been initiated in 2000-01, the
paper cover the period 2000-01 to 2009-10.
The paper is organised as follows: Section 2 underlines the
constitutional provision of revenue assignment; Section 3 presents the
pattern of resource mobilisation in Pakistan; Section 4 reveals the
extent of vertical imbalance in Pakistan; Section 5 analyses the
devolution of GST services and its impact on vertical imbalance; Section
6 discusses the implementation challenges in collecting GST services;
and Section 7 concludes the paper.
2. REVENUE ASSIGNMENT AS PER CONSTITUTION
In Pakistan, the constitution and certain statutes designate the
revenue assignments between the federal and provincial governments.
After the abolishment of concurrent lists in the 18th Amendment, the
revenue source assigned to the federal and provincial governments is
through an express provision in an article of the constitution or
through classification in the federal lists of subjects. In the latter
case if the revenue source is mentioned in the Federal List it belongs
to the federation only. However, if a revenue source is not mentioned in
the Federal List it then belongs to the provinces only.
Federal taxes under the Fourth Schedule, Article 70(4), of the
Constitution of Pakistan are given Table 1. It states that among the
indirect taxes the federal government has a constitutional right to
collect taxes only on the sales and purchases of goods (imported,
exported, produced, manufactured or consumed) but not on sales of
services. This provides autonomy to the provincial governments to levy
sales tax on services.
The revenue assignment of provincial governments according to the
constitutional scheme is given in Table 2. It is to be mentioned that
property tax, capital gains, excise duty, sales tax on services, tax on
professions, motor vehicle tax are shared revenues under the NFC clauses
of the constitution. The base and rate are set by the federation.
Thus, according to the constitution of Pakistan, federal government
is empowered to levy GST only on the sales, purchase and consumption of
goods; however GST on services exclusively falls under the domain of
provincial governments.
It was for this very reason that provinces levied sales tax on
services on 15th July 2000. Later on, in 2000-01, the provincial
governments empowered the federal government to collect GST services on
their behalf. Since then federal government has been collecting GST
services by breaking it into two modes: GST CE mode and GST provincial.
The latter has been transferred to provinces (after deducting the
collection charges) on the basis of population rather than collection.
CE mode was being treated similar to GST goods before the implementation
of 7th NFC Award (July 2010).
Though. collection of sales tax on services already remains a
constitutional right of provinces, the 7th NFC Award and the 18th
Constitutional Amendment further strengthened this. The document of the
18th Amendment states, in fourth schedule of the constitution, in the
federal legislative list, entry 49 after the word "consumed"
the comma and words "except sales tax on services" shall be
added. As a result, GST services CE mode is transferred to provincial
governments.
3. RESOURCE MOBILISATION IN PAKISTAN
Before analysing the impact of tax decentralisation on provincial
finances, this section presents the pattern of resource mobilisation
(generating the required resources to carry out expenditures for public
service delivery) in Pakistan by major revenue source both at the
federal and provincial levels.
3.1. Resource Mobilisation at Federal Level
Table 3 gives the magnitude and growth in different components of
FBR tax revenue in Pakistan. In 2009-10, total tax revenue in Pakistan
was Rs 1,380 billion. Of this, 39 percent were the direct taxes and 61
percent were indirect taxes. 16 percent of the indirect taxes were
originated via excise duties and 20 percent via import duties while the
remaining from GST on goods and services.
The trend in growth indicates that tax revenue increased at an
average rate of 11 percent per annum during 2001-05 and 18 percent
during 2006-10; indicating higher growth in federal taxes in the second
half on 2000s. In the first half of 2000s, highest growth was observed
in GST services while in second half it was in direct taxes. During the
entire period, GST services depicted highest growth that could be due to
the fact that it started from a zero base.
Table 4 presents the trend in tax to GDP ratio in Pakistan. It
shows that total tax revenue remained on average 9.2 percent per annum
of GDP during 2001-05 and increased slightly to 9.5 percent during
2006-10. Direct taxes that on average constituted 3 percent per annum of
GDP during 2001-05 increased on average by 0.5 percentage points during
2006-10. Alternatively, indirect taxes declined from an average of 6.2
percent per annum of GDP to 5.9 percent of GDP during these two
sub-periods. It is noticeable that contribution of GST on goods in GDP
remained on average over 3 percent per annum during these sub-periods
while that of GST on services stayed at less than 0.5 percent. (1)
3.2. Resource Mobilisation at Provincial Level
Table 5 gives the resource mobilisation efforts at provincial
level. Compared to Rs 1,380 billion tax collected by the federal
government in 2009-10, provincial governments altogether collected only
Rs 70 billion. It further indicates that provincial tax revenues
increased from a meagre Rs 19.1 billion in 2000-01 to Rs 70 billion in
2009-10. On the other hand, non-tax revenues increased from Rs 19.9
billion to Rs 95 billion during same period.
Relative to taxes, higher growth in non-tax revenues indicates that
provincial revenues are tilted towards non-tax revenue. Further, over
the entire period, provincial taxes grew at a pace similar to federal
taxes suggesting that capacity of provincial governments in collecting
taxes is not as bad as it usually argued.
4. VERTICAL FISCAL IMBALANCE IN PAKISTAN
Vertical fiscal imbalance means the disparity between the revenues
of a government and its expenditure responsibilities. An adequate
provision of social services is a concurrent function of federal and
provincial governments. However, the combination of decentralised spending with centralised financing through grants and tax revenue
sharing leads to vertical fiscal imbalance. This situation prevails in
Pakistan where the financing and delivery of social services largely lie
in the hands of provinces and major sources of revenues in the hand of
federal government creating vertical imbalances.
Table 6 shows the total tax and non-tax revenue collected by the
federal and provincial governments. Noticeably, the table reveals that
the federal government collects 92 percent to 94 percent of the revenue
in Pakistan. Only 6 percent to 8 percent of the revenues are collected
by the provincial governments. This suggests that provincial governments
have a very narrow base of revenue collection.
Table 7 gives only the total tax collection of federal and
provincial governments. It further strengthens the point that provinces
have limited control in collection of taxes in Pakistan. In most of the
years since 2000-01, provincial governments collected only 4 percent of
the total taxes in the country.
On the other hand, the current expenditures of the federal and
provincial government given in Table 8 indicate that the share of
provinces in total current expenditure is tar high. Provinces spend 23
percent to 29 percent of the total current expenditure in Pakistan. It
needs to mention that the share of provinces would go up if these
expenditures include the amount of development expenditures.
Thus, while provincial share in tax revenue on average is less than
5 percent during the 2000s their share in expenditure is over 25 percent
indicating the extent of vertical imbalance in Pakistan. This builds the
argument that provinces to a large extent depend on the resources or
transfers from the federal government to meet their expenditures demand.
Accordingly, in Pakistan, 88 percent of the provincial government's
resources depend on intergovernmental transfers. In contrast, in other
developing countries, like India and Malaysia, 35 percent of the
provincial government's resources come from intergovernmental
transfers.
5. DEVOLUTION OF GST SERVICES AND VERTICAL IMBALANCE
Having developed that there are significant vertical imbalances in
Pakistan, it is important to analyse whether or not devolution of GST
services will make any sizeable impact As Khan (2009) highlights that
services sector constitutes more than half of the value added of the
economy, but it is fetching only 34 percent of the federal tax receipts.
While mentioning the difficulties in taxing services, he points out that
many services are rendered at the distribution process or at the stage
of production, which sometime have informal characteristics, hence
making it difficult to collect taxes from them. Given the narrow base of
services and difficulties attached to collecting taxes from them, this
section first highlights the contribution of GST in overall FBR taxes
and then looks whether GST services has sizeable tax base. As per scope
of the study, it excludes other taxation on services sector such as
Federal Excise Duty (FED), income tax and the like. It also compares
effective tax rate of GST services with other taxes to highlight the tax
potential in GST services. Afterwards, it compares the vertical
imbalances in revenue transfer to the provincial governments with or
without GST services.
5.1. Contribution of GST Services in FBR Taxes
Table 9 gives the contribution of GST on services in comparison
with GST on goods under different tax heads. For instance, in total GST,
services contributed on average only 7.4 percent per annum during
2001-05, which increases to 12.6 percent during 2005-10. GST services
contributed on average 4.5 percent per annum in total indirect taxes and
3 percent per annum in total tax revenue during 2001-05. These shares
increased to 7.7 percent and 4.8 percent respectively during 2006-10.
While in comparison with GST goods these shares are still very low, they
showed relatively higher growth.
5.2. Tax Base of GST Services
Table 10 shows the ratios of GST goods and GST services base to
GDP. While base-to-GDP ratio of GST goods substantially increased,
base-to-GST ratio of services hovered around over 20 percent during the
two sub-periods. This happened because FBR focused only on the
efficiency of GST services collection till 2008-09, without broadening
its tax base. However in 2009-10, new services like banking insurances
and other were also added to broaden its base.
5.3. Effective Tax Rates
Table 11 portrays the effective tax rate of different components of
tax revenues in Pakistan. It indicates that effective tax rate of GST
services hanged on average only about 1.4 percent and 2 percent per
annum respectively during the two sub-periods. GST on goods though
declined from an average of 12 percent per annum during 2001-05 to
nearly 9 percent during 2006-10 but remained far above than that of GST
on services. GST services have lowest rates because of lower efficiency
of tax collection and tax exemptions. This lowest effective tax rate
indicates greater potential of GST in services sector.
Though, it is apparent there exist potential of taxation in the
services sector but the idea here is to observe how far the vertical
imbalance be reduced once the provinces are empowered to collect GST
services.
5.4. Share of Provincial Revenues with or without GST Services
Table 12 displays the share of provincial tax revenues in total
taxes with and without GST services. It indicates that had the GST
services been devolved in 2000-01 and had it acquired the same
efficiency then provincial share of taxes would have increased from 4.3
percent to 6.3 percent in 2000-01. And, with the passage of time this
share would have further increased to 8.6 percent in 2009-10. Thus, with
full provincial share of GST services, provincial share in taxes would
have more than doubled during 2006-10.
5.5. Role of GST Services in Minimising Vertical Imbalances
Table 13 shows vertical imbalances in Pakistan with or without
devolving GST services during 2006-07 to 2009-10. It indicates that if
GST services were successfully devolved then vertical imbalance would
have been reduced. For instance, in 2006-07 vertical imbalance would
have been reduced from 27.2 percent to 23.9 percent due to
decentralisation of GST services. Similarly in 2009-10, vertical
imbalance would have been reduced from 24.3 percent to 21.2 percent due
to decentralisation of GST services.
6. IMPLEMENTATION CHALLENGES
Despite the fact that devolving GST service has constitutional
provision and it also reduces the vertical imbalances, this has not yet
been put into practice. There are certain challenges that often come in
its implementation debate. These can be sum-up in following three
arguments.
* Provincial governments do not have the capacity to collect GST on
services.
* Under VAT regime, collection of goods and services cannot be
separated.
* Bulk of the taxes in Pakistan are paid at the headquarters of the
firm that may lead to an unfair allocation of revenues after
decentralisation.
This section systematically discusses the validity of these
arguments by analysing the structure of GST services. Table 14 presents
the GST collected on services by sectors in 2009-I0. The statistics
reveal that GST on services is largely collected from telecommunication
sector, which contributed more than 70 percent of total GST on services.
Historically, the share of telecommunication in GST services was more
than 90 percent. The other major tax spinners are banking and insurance
(tax collected under federal excise duty), community and social
services, and transport and communication services.
6.1. Devolution of GST on Telecommunications
There are several apprehensions regarding the devolution of GST on
telecommunication services. For example, does it require lots of
capacity that provincial government do not have at present? Will it lead
to an unfair allocation among provinces? Is it impossible under VAT
regime?
As per our understanding, the answer to all these questions is in
negative. Firstly, there are fewer telecommunication companies to deal
with. They have computerised record and have complete information about
usage of their services, charging of bills and payment of taxes. As a
result, devolution of telecommunication taxes does not require much
capacity and provincial governments can easily collect tax with these
fewer computerised telecommunication companies. Their computerised
records also help minimising the scope of unfair allocation among the
provinces. However, devolution of GST on telecommunication under VAT
mode is relatively a difficult task. Attempts have been made at the
federal and provincial (Sindh) government level to resolve this issue.
Their technical teams concluded, "while VAT regime requires
'input-output adjustment' to be centralised, collection can be
decentralised." For instance, as per 2009-10 estimate provinces can
collect Rs 45 billion in GST from telecommunications services. Since
bulk of this tax is collected from end users with limited scope for
input output adjustment, however, companies seeking refunds submit
consolidated (goods and services) account/claim to FBR. As per FBR
estimates these refunds hardly reached to Rs 3.5 billion. After
receiving and verifying these refund claims FBR can provide refunds (Rs
3.5 billion) to companies and provinces can reimburse FBR the amount
equivalent to refund claims i.e. Rs 3.5 billion.
6.2. Devolution of GST on Banking and Insurance
Banking and insurance sector is the second biggest contributor in
services tax. At present, the services of this sector are taxed under
FED mode and not under GST. Nevertheless, after the 7th NFC Award, it is
likely that this collection can be treated as GST. This sector also has
smaller number of banking and insurance companies, mostly in formal
sector, having computerised records. Given this, the provincial
governments do not require much capacity and can easily deal with them.
Moreover, complete computerised transaction details also minimise the
scope of unfair allocations of GST among the provinces. Similar to
telecommunication sector, the input output adjustment can be dealt by
federal government; however, the collection can be devolved.
6.3. Devolution of GST on Other Sectors
In contrast to telecommunication and banking and insurance, other
sectors have large number of tax payers. The provincial governments need
to build capacity in order to collect GST from them. In this regard,
recently an attempt has been made by the government of Sindh where it
established a board named Sindh Revenue Services (SRS). It has an
independent board of directors and separate collection mechanism.
Currently, the progress of SRS working is slow as the decision to
devolved GST services is in pending.
Certain confusions also prevail regarding the collection of GST
services. For example, there is confusion that if more than one person
was involved in consuming a service like telecommunication then who will
pay the tax. And if they live in different provinces then which province
would receive the revenue from GST services. Theoretically, this
argument seems very difficult but in reality this can be addressed very
easily. For example, every telecommunication company charges a fee on
its services. While two persons are consuming same service the bill is
generally paid by one person. Since GST service is a proportional tax on
billing amount, it would be collected by the province whose consumer
bears the charges of bill and hence that province will receive the
revenue. The same logic can be followed if more than one consumer pays
the billing amount and taxes, whether in a pre- or post-paid manner.
Another confusion is whether or nor GST service is a part of
divisible pool. Prior to the 7th NFC Award, GST on services CE mode was
part of the divisible pool and GST provincial tax was treated as
straight transfers. After the 7th NFC Award, both GST provincial and CE
mode would be treated as straight transfers and hence GST services would
no more be part of divisible pool.
7. CONCLUSION
In Pakistan, confinement of major sources of revenues with the
federal government and a sizeable expenditures assignment at provincial
level creates vertical fiscal imbalances. While these vertical
imbalances are generally addressees through intergovernmental transfers,
there is still a need to devolve taxes at provincial levels. The 7th NFC
Award and 18th Constitutional Amendment ensure that a GST services is a
provincial tax. In this context, this paper analyses the scope of GST
services in minimising the vertical fiscal imbalances in Pakistan. The
analysis indicates that devolution of GST services will help doubling
the share of provincial tax revenues in total taxes thus facilitate
reducing vertical imbalances in Pakistan. Moreover, the
telecommunication sector, which pays bulk of the GST services, requires
limited provincial capacities for collection of GST as there are fewer
telecommunication companies in Pakistan and all have computerised
database.
Though, the devolution of GST services will reduce the vertical
imbalance but it will not eliminate it completely. Future NFCs would
therefore be needed to address the issues of reaming vertical and
horizontal imbalances.
REFERENCES
Ahmed, Ehtisham (2010) Why is it so Difficult to Implement a GST in
Pakistan? The Lahore Journal of Economics 15-SE.
Bahl, Roy (1999) Implementation Rules for Fiscal Decentralisation.
International Studies Programme, School of Policy Studies, Georgia State
University, USA.
Bahl, Roy, Sally Wallace, and Musharraf Cyan (2008) Pakistan:
Provincial Government Taxation, International Studies Programme, Georgia
State University. (Working Paper 08-07).
Khan, Mir Ahmad (2009) Vying for Raising Tax GDP Ratio: Taxation of
Services Sector in Pakistan. FBR Quarterly Review 8:3.
Martinez-Vanquez (2006) Pakistan: An Overview of Tax System in
Pakistan. International Studies Programme, Andrew Young School of Policy
Studies, Georgia State University, USA.
Pakistan, Government of (n.d.) The Constitution of Pakistan.
<www.pakistani. org/pakistan/constitution/>
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Pakistan Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues), Federal Board of Revenue
Yearbook. Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.
SPDC (1994) Sales Taxation of Services by Provincial Governments.
Reported presented to Canadian High Commission as part of the Integrated
Social Sector Planning Project, Social Policy and Development Centre.
Thirk, Wyne (2008) Tax Policy in Pakistan: An Assessment of Major
Taxes and Options for Reforms. International Studies Programme, Andrew
Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, USA.
Comments
The paper delve into the critical issue faced by the over all
revenue management in Pakistan. In the ambit of over all fiscal
decentralisation milieus where a land mark achievement in the form of
7th NFC and 18th amendment has been achieved, still there remain issues
which are critical both in terms of catering to the needs of the
federating units and to the revenue efficiency.
The paper picks a potential topic for research, the
decentralisation of revenues; and there the authors discuss in a
holistic manner the issues pertaining to the decentralisation of GST on
services. The 18th amendment exclusively holds the provision of revenue
collection in this head to be the sole responsibility of the provinces
as per the 1973 constitution and the paper focus on this issue.
The proponents of decentralisation argue the case of potential
growth promoting effects on the basis of possible preference-matching,
efficiency through competition and increased accountability. But the
real question is that the assumptions behind this logic e.g. the local
tax administration being more efficient and people responding to
enhanced services in a reciprocal manner by paying more and others like
the assumptions for a tie-bout model where people vote by migrating to
the preferred constituencies require the perfect mobility of factors of
production and wealth sources, which is next to impossible considering
the term of government being on average 3-4 years and high economic and
social cost of migration.
Even though the authors have very excellently prepared the case for
reduction in vertical imbalance, which is very high as compared to other
countries such as India (Expenditure share 50 and Revenue 37) but also
mentioned the opposite Malaysia (8, 35). So it may not be the most
common best practice (see Table below)
Over all Pakistan has the lowest C-efficiency (0.27, Sri Lanka 0.45), if devolved this may further reduce. In Pakistan the case for
services decentralisation is propagated, as also mentioned by the author
that most of GST on services is collected from telecommunication sector
only (around 80 percent) and other large business head quarters. Mostly
these are concentrated in Karachi, some would be in Lahore or in bigger
cities, but I have doubt if there are many in whole of the Balochistan.
Further with these services related GST, again the issue of calling
party arrangements matter, e.g. if a person is calling from Karachi and
being received in Lahore, then both the Karachi and Lahore based network
is being utilised, so how will they share the revenues, who will charge
and how much it will retain. Although else where e.g. India sub national
governments collects GST on goods as they are more tangible and leaves
the value added based taxes to the centre as they are complex, but here
the arrangements are the other way.
In the paper the authors have mentioned that if whole of the GST on
services revenue is being devolved to the provinces and they collect the
same as it is now then the vertical imbalances will reduce, let me ask
here what is then the objective of NFC?, because essentially the GST is
part of the divisible pool.
So the difference it will make, what I feel is that there will be
less change in the vertical imbalance (the author may like to see the
contribution of GST on services revenues towards the NFC) rather it will
create a horizontal imbalance as provinces with lesser corporate office
will loose.
So the decentralisation in GST on services may only bring about
required results if the provinces start applying the different marginal
rates (in a sense competing with other constituencies and considering
the structural differences in bases and their buoyancies regarding the
services base assigned to them) and improve the over all tax
administration system.
The effective tax rate calculation needs to be adjusted for
services sectors by adjusting it for the exemptions and inclusion of CED on telecommunication as identified by the authors themselves to be the
hidden GST on telecommunication services.
In the end I would still congratulate the author to bring upon a
good topic for discussion, but also encourage them to improve it in the
light of above comments.
Mahmood Khalid
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
A Comparison of Selected Fiscal Systems
Selected Indicators
The Character Range of Local Local
Countries of Fiscal Government Fiscal
Federalism Responsibilities Autonomy
Australia 2-tier Centralised Limited Fair
Brazil 3-tier Decentralised Extensive Fair
Canada 2-tier Decentralised Extensive Strong
Germany 2-tier Centralised
Integrated Limited Fair
India 3-tier Centralised Limited Weak
Malaysia 2-tier Centralised Limited Weak
Nigeria 3-tier Centralised Limited Weak
Russia 2-tier Centralised Limited Fair
Spain 2-tier Centralised Limited Fair
South Africa 3-tier Centralised Limited Fair
Switzerland 2-tier Decentralised Extensive Strong
United States 2-tier Decentralised Extensive Strong
Source: Shah Anwar, 'Comparative Conclusions on Fiscal Federalism'.
Published in Edited Book: A Global Dialogue on Federalism.
Volume 4, 2007.
(1) See Martinez-Vanquez (2006) and Thirk (2008) for analysis of
taxation and policies in Pakistan.
Iffat Ara <iffatara@spdc.org.pk> is Principal Economist,
Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC). Muhammad Sabir
<muhammadsabir@spdc.org.pk> is Principal Economist, Social Policy
and Development Centre (SPDC), Karachi.
Table 1
Federal Revenue Assignment as per Constitutional Provision
Federal
Federal Taxes Legislative List
Direct Taxes
Personal Income Tax (excl. Agricultural Income) subject 47
Corporate Income Tax subject 48
Capital Value Tax (excl. Immovable Property) subject 50
Indirect Taxes
Duties of Customs (Including Export Duties) subject 43
Excise Duty (Except on Alcohol, Narcotics) subject 44
Taxes on the Sales and Purchases of Goods
(Except Sales Tax on Services) subject 49
Mineral Oil, Minerals, Natural Gas subject 51
Tax on Production Capacity subject 52
Terminal Taxes on Goods Transport and Passengers subject 53
Table 2
Provincial Revenue Assignment as per Constitutional Provision
Provincial Taxes Constitutional Scheme
Direct Taxes
Property Tax Residuary but there is bar in the
Federal List (subject 51)
Capital Gains Assigned through bar on the federation
in the Federal List (subject 50)
Agriculture Income Tax Through bar on the federation in the
Federal List (subject 47)
Indirect Taxes
Excise Duty on Assigned to province by bar on the
federation in the
Alcohol/Liquor/Narcotics Federal List (subject 44)
Sales Tax on Services Residuary assignment
Tax on Professions Article 163 of the constitution
Motor Vehicle Tax Residuary assignment
Stamp Duty Residuary assignment
Registration Fee Residuary assignment
Mutation Fee Residuary assignment
Natural Gas Excise Duty Article 161 of the constitution
Net Hydro Profits Article 161 of the constitution
Electricity Duty Article 157(2) (b)of the constitution
Table 3
Components of Federal Tax Revenue
(Rs Million)
Total
Tax Direct
Year Revenues Taxes
2000-01 392,277 124,585
2001-02 404,070 142,505
2002-03 460,627 151,898
2003-04 520,843 165,079
2004-05 590,387 183,372
2005-06 713,442 224,988
2006-07 847,236 333,737
2007-08 1,008,091 387,861
2008-09 1,161,150 443,548
2009-10 1,380,000 540,400
Average Annual Growth Rate (%)
2001-05 11.29 10.21
2006-10 17.94 25.19
2001-10 14.91 17.45
Indirect Taxes
GST
Excise Import
Year Total Duties Duties Total Goods Services
2000-01 267,692 49,080 65,047 153,565 144,981 8,584
2001-02 261,565 47,186 47,818 166,561 154,787 11,774
2002-03 308,729 44,754 68,836 195,139 180,991 14,148
2003-04 355,764 45,552 91,045 219,167 203,713 15,454
2004-05 407,015 53,104 115,374 238,537 214,519 24,018
2005-06 488,454 55,272 138,384 294,798 263,767 31,031
2006-07 513,499 71,804 132,299 309,396 267,531 41,865
2007-08 620,230 92,137 150,663 377,430 325,752 51,678
2008-09 717,602 117,455 148,403 451,744 395,154 56,590
2009-10 839,600 134,400 164,900 540,300 473,474 66,826
Average Annual Growth Rate (%)
2001-05 11.94 -0.53 16.39 15.67 10.39 30.49
2006-10 14.65 25.03 4.77 16.56 16.08 21.49
2001-10 13.83 10.15 12.10 16.82 14.31 26.35
Source: Federal Board of Revenue, Yearbook (Various Issues).
Table 4
Trend in Tax-to-GDP Ratio
(Percent)
Total
Tax Direct
Year Revenues Taxes
2000-01 9.32 2.96
2001-02 9.07 3.20
2002-03 9.45 3.12
2003-04 9.23 2.93
2004-05 9.08 2.82
2005-06 9.36 2.95
2006-07 9.77 3.85
2007-08 9.84 3:79
2008-09 9.11 3.48
2009-10 9.41 3.68
Average Annual Ratios
2001-05 9.23 3.00
2006-10 9.50 3.55
2001-10 9.36 3.28
Indirect Taxes
GST
Excise Import
Year Total Duties Duties Total Goods Services
2000-01 6.36 1.17 1.55 3.65 3.44 0.20
2001-02 5.87 1.06 1.07 3.74 3.48 0.26
2002-03 6.33 0.92 1.41 4.00 3.71 0.29
2003-04 6.31 0.81 1.61 3.89 3.61 0.27
2004-05 6.26 0.82 1.78 3.67 3.30 0.37
2005-06 6.41 0.73 1.82 3.87 3.46 0.41
2006-07 5.92 0.83 1.53 3.57 3.08 0.48
2007-08 6.06 0.90 1.47 3.68 3.18 0.50
2008-09 5.63 0.92 1.16 3.55 3.10 0.44
2009-10 5.72 0.92 1.12 3.68 3.23 0.46
Average Annual Ratios
2001-05 6.23 0.95 1.48 3.79 3.51 0.28
2006-10 5.95 0.86 1.42 3.67 3.21 0.46
2001-10 6.09 0.91 1.45 3.73 3.36 0.37
Source: Federal Board of Revenue, Yearbook (Various Issues).
Table 5
Provincial Revenues
(Rs Million)
Year Tax Non-Tax Total
2000-01 19,100 19,900 39,000
2001-02 18,800 21,300 40,100
2002-03 21,800 25,400 47,200
2003-04 28,000 25,000 53,000
2004-05 34,710 22,404 57,114
2005-06 36,800 47,600 84,400
2006-07 36,819 45,408 82,227
2007-08 40,794 77,987 118,781
2008-09 46,084 83,789 129,873
2009-10 70,000 95,000 165,000
Average Annual Growth Rates (%)
2001-05 13.68 7.59 10.46
2006-10 16.35 40.08 25.21
2000-10 15.01 23.84 17.84
Source: GoP, Economic Survey.
Table 6
Revenue Collection of Federal and Provincial Governments
Total Revenues (Rs Million) Share in Revenues (%)
Year Federal Provincial Total Federal Provincial
2000-01 514,000 39,000 553,000 92.9 7.1
2001-02 584,000 40,100 624,100 93.6 6.4
2002-03 673,600 47,200 720,800 93.5 6.5
2003-04 741,000 53,000 794,000 93.3 6.7
2004-05 842,900 57,114 900,014 93.7 6.3
2005-06 992,200 84,400 1,076,600 92.2 7.8
2006-07 1,215,730 82,227 1,297,957 93.7 6.3
2007-08 1,380,599 118,781 1,499,380 92.1 7.9
2008-09 1,721,028 129,873 1,850,901 93.0 7.0
2009-10 1,990,387 165,000 2,155,387 92.3 7.7
Source: GoP, Economic Survey (Various Issues).
Table 7
Tax Collection of Federal and Provincial Governments
Total Taxes (Rs Million) Share in Taxes (%)
Year Federal Provincial Total Federal Provincial
1999-00 386,800 18,800 405,600 95.4 4.6
2000-01 422,500 19,100 441,600 95.7 4.3
2001-02 459,300 18,800 478,100 96.1 3.9
2002-03 534,000 21,800 555,800 96.1 3.9
2003-04 583,000 28,000 611,000 95.4 4.6
2004-05 624,700 34,710 659,410 94.7 5.3
2005-06 766,900 36,800 803,700 95.4 4.6
2006-07 852,866 36,819 889,685 95.9 4.1
2007-08 1,009,902 40,794 1,050,696 96.1 3.9
2008-09 1,158,586 46,084 1,204,670 96.2 3.8
2009-10 1,523,497 70,000 1,593,497 95.6 4.4
Source: GoP, Economic Survey (Various Issues).
Table 8
Current Expenditures of Federal and Provincial Governments
Total Current Expenditure Share (%)
(Rs Million)
Year Federal Provincial Total Federal Provincial
1999-00 477,900 148,500 626,400 76.3 23.7
2000-01 479,000 166,700 645,700 74.2 25.8
2001-02 524,600 175,600 700,200 74.9 25.1
2002-03 599,800 191,900 791,700 75.8 24.2
2003-04 557,000 218,000 775,000 71.9 28.1
2004-05 664,200 200,300 864,500 76.8 23.2
2005-06 789,100 245,600 1,034,700 76.3 23.7
2006-07 973,130 402,215 1,375,345 70.8 29.2
2007-08 1,416,015 437,132 1,853,147 76.4 23.6
2008-09 1,495,873 545,697 2,041,570 73.3 26.7
2009-10 1,670,963 590,000 2,260,963 73.9 26.1
Source: GoP, Economic Survey (Various Issues).
Table 9
Contribution of GST on Goods and Services
(Percent)
GST on Goods as GST on Services as
Proportion of Total Proportion of Total
Indirect Tax Indirect Tax
Year GST Tax Revenue GST Tax Revenue
2000-01 94.41 54.16 36.96 5.59 3.21 2.19
2001-02 92.93 59.18 38.31 7.07 4.50 2.91
2002-03 92.75 58.62 39.29 7.25 4.58 3.07
2003-04 92.95 57.26 39.11 7.05 4.34 2.97
2004-05 89.93 52.71 36.34 10.07 5.90 4.07
2005-06 89.47 54.00 36.97 10.53 6.35 4.35
2006-07 86.47 52.10 31.58 13.53 8.15 4.94
2007-08 86.31 52.52 32.31 13.69 8.33 5.13
2008-09 87.47 55.07 34.03 12.53 7.89 4.87
2009-10 87.63 56.39 34.31 12.37 7.96 4.84
Average Annual Shares
2001-05 92.59 56.39 38.00 7.41 4.51 3.04
2006-10 87.47 54.02 33.84 12.53 7.74 4.83
Source: Federal Board of Revenue, Yearbook (Various Issues).
Table 10
GST Base-to-GDP Ratio
(Percent)
Year Total GST GST Goods GST Services
2000-01 48.41 27.81 20.60
2001-02 47.56 26.47 21.08
2002-03 48.27 26.96 21.31
2003-04 50.95 30.58 20.37
2004-05 54.35 34.18 20.17
2005-06 57.78 37.29 20.49
2006-07 56.84 36.41 20.44
2007-08 59.53 39.12 20.41
2008-09 56.03 33.59 22.44
2009-10 54.45 31.56 22.89
Average Annual Ratio
2001-05 49.9 29.2 20.7
2006-10 56.9 35.6 21.3
Table 11
Effective Tax Rate
(Percent)
Indirect Taxes
GST
Direct Excise Imports
Year Taxes Duty Duty Goods Services
2000-01 4.18 4.72 17.77 12.38 0.99
2001-02 4.48 4.25 11.95 13.13 1.25
2002-03 4.37 3.62 14.83 13.77 1.36
2003-04 4.04 3.11 14.25 11.81 1.35
2004-05 3.81 2.93 13.30 9.65 1.83
2005-06 3.95 2.43 12.05 9.28 1.99
2006-07 5.10 2.75 10.49 8.47 2.36
2007-08 4.91 2.90 9.92 8.13 2.47
2008-09 4.68 3.13 8.89 9.23 1.98
2009-10 4.99 3.15 9.57 10.23 1.99
Average Annual Rate
2001-05 4.18 3.73 14.42 12.15 1.36
2006-10 4.72 2.87 10.19 9.07 2.16
Table 12
Provincial Revenues With or Without GST Services
(Percent)
Provincial Share in Revenues
Without GST With GST Difference
Year Services Services
2000-01 7.1 8.6 1.6
2001-02 6.4 8.3 1.9
2002-03 6.5 8.5 2.0
2003-04 6.7 8.6 1.9
2004-05 6.3 9.0 2.7
2005-06 7.8 10.7 2.9
2006-07 6.3 9.6 3.2
2007-08 7.9 11.4 3.4
2008-09 7.0 10.1 3.1
2009-10 7.7 10.8 3.1
Average Annual Shares
2001-05 6.6 8.6 2.0
2006-10 7.3 10.5 3.1
Provincial Share in Taxes
Without GST With GST Difference
Year Services Services
2000-01 4.3 6.3 1.9
2001-02 3.9 6.4 2.5
2002-03 3.9 6.5 2.5
2003-04 4.6 7.1 2.5
2004-05 5.3 8.9 3.6
2005-06 4.6 8.4 3.9
2006-07 4.1 8.8 4.7
2007-08 3.9 8.8 4.9
2008-09 3.8 8.5 4.7
2009-10 4.4 8.6 4.2
Average Annual Shares
2001-05 4.4 7.0 2.6
2006-10 4.2 8.6 4.5
Source: Authors' estimates based on FBR Yearbook.
Table 13
Vertical Imbalances in Pakistan
(Percent)
Year Without GST Services
Revenue Expenditure Surplus/
Share Share Deficit
2006-07
Federal 93.7 66.5 27.2
Provincial 6.3 33.5 -27.2
2007-08
Federal 92.1 73.6 18.4
Provincial 7.9 26.4 -18.4
2008-09
Federal 93.0 70.4 22.6
Provincial 7.0 29.6 -22.6
2009-10
Federal 92.3 68.0 24.3
Provincial 7.7 32.0 -24.3
Year With GST Services
Revenue Expenditure Surplus/
Share Share Deficit
2006-07
Federal 90.4 66.5 23.9
Provincial 9.6 33.5 -23.9
2007-08
Federal 88.6 73.6 15.0
Provincial 11.4 26.4 -15.0
2008-09
Federal 89.9 70.4 19.6
Provincial 10.1 29.6 -19.6
2009-10
Federal 89.2 68.0 21.2
Provincial 10.8 32.0 -21.2
Source: Authors' estimates based on FBR Yearbook.
Table 14
General Sales Tax on Services--2009-10
Tax Collection Share
Sector (Rs Million) (%)
Telecommunications 44,852.5 70.4
Banking and Insurance 5,969.8 9.4
Community and Social Services 5,368.9 8.4
Transport and Communication 4,453.2 7.0
Hotels, Recreation and Entertainment 2,347.7 3.7
Wholesale and Retail Trade 468.8 0.7
Other 222.6 0.3
Total 63,683.5 100.0
Source: Federal Board of Revenue.
Note: Banking and Insurance largely includes federal excise duty.