Financial implications of the 7th NFC Award and the impact on social services.
Sabir, Muhammad
One of the major developments in 2009-10 was a successfully
concluded 7th NFC Award [NFC Award (2009)], which has brought about some
profound changes in the resource distribution formula. Since 1973, it is
the first time when the distribution of resources among provinces is
based not only on the population but also on other criteria such as
backwardness, inverse population density, and revenue
collection/generation. This Award has also helped resolve other issues
such as GDS and Hydroelectricity Profit. This paper analyses the
financial implications of the NFC Award 2009 and its impact on three
major social services, namely, education, health, and water supply and
sanitation. The result shows that as compared to the NFC Award 1997 and
Presidential Distribution Order: Distribution of Revenues and
Grants-in-Aid Order 2006, the changes made in vertical distribution of
resources under the NFC Award 2009 favour the provincial governments
(combined) rather than the federal government. An interesting finding is
that while there is a decline in vertical share of the provinces under
the NFC Award 2009 as compared to the NFC Award 1991, this decline is
not evenly distributed among the provinces. In relative terms, the NFC
Award 2009 benefits the two relatively more backward provinces, Khyber
Pakhtunkhwa and Balochistan, as compared to Sindh and Punjab. Moreover,
the projected values of social sector expenditures indicate that the NFC
Award 2009 has a positive impact on social sector spending. Given that
Pakistan has a comparatively low spending on social services, this award
is a positive move.
JEL classification: H75, H77
Keywords: Intergovernmental Fiscal Relation, Provincial Expenditure
on Social Services
1. INTRODUCTION
The financial status of provincial governments in Pakistan hinges largely on federal transfers to the provinces constituted through
National Finance Commission (NFC) Awards. These awards design the
formula of distribution of resources between federal and provincial
governments, and among the provinces for five years. Historically,
federal and all provincial governments have tried their level best to
get a higher share of the revenues in order to stabilise their own
financial status. As a result, there are very few examples of consensus
based conclusive awards in the past. These consensus based awards have
had different gainers. For instance, in the NFC Award 1991, provincial
governments were the main beneficiaries as they received substantially
higher shares of buoyant taxes such as sales and income taxes. In
contrast, the largest beneficiary of the NFC Award 1997 was the federal
government as it allocated higher shares of all taxes to itself in order
to stabilise its financial status. Given the sensitivity attached to NFC
awards, where an increase or decrease in the share of any tier of the
government affects the share of other tiers with the same magnitude in
the opposite direction, it seems very difficult to develop a consensus
among federal and provincial governments. As a result, since the
separation of East Pakistan, there have been only three conclusive NFC
Awards (1974, 1991, 1997) and one presidential distribution order (2006)
prior to the 7th NFC Award.
In this context, one of the major developments in 2009-10 was a
successfully concluded seventh NFC Award or NFC Award 2009, which
affected the resource distribution formula. Given the past experience of
several inconclusive NFC Awards, a consensus based NFC Award is in
itself a big achievement. It is the first time after the secession of
East Pakistan that the distribution of resources among provinces has
been based not only on population but also on other factors such as
backwardness, inverse population density and revenue
collection/generation. The NFC Award 2009 has also helped to resolve
other issues such as Gas Development Surcharge (GDS) and
Hydroelectricity Profit.
This paper aims to analyse the financial implications of the NFC
Award 2009 and its impact on three major social services namely
education, health, and water supply and sanitation. This analysis would
not only add to relevant research in Pakistan but would also help in
identifying policy implications for future NFC Awards.
2. AN OVERVIEW OF THE NFC AWARDS
The history of intergovernmental fiscal transfers from the federal
government to the provincial governments in the sub-continent dates back
to 1919. Since the independence of Pakistan in 1947, these transfers
have experienced many changes in line with constitutional developments.
However, as in other countries, the purpose of fiscal transfer system in
Pakistan is primarily to correct the vertical fiscal imbalances between
the federal and the provincial governments and horizontal imbalances
between provinces.
According to the constitution of Pakistan, the NFC is set up by the
president of Pakistan every five years. This commission allocates or
awards the total resources or revenues collected during a fiscal year
between the federal government and provincial governments, hence such a
decision is called the NFC Award. The NFC Award decides the method for
allocating the resource transfers for five years based on a formula for
revenue sharing. Table 1 gives the chronology of NFC Awards in Pakistan.
It shows that since the separation of East Pakistan, there have been
only three conclusive NFC Awards (1974, 1991, 1996) in addition to a
Distributional Order 2006--only three NFC Awards during a period of 32
years (1974 to 2006). After the NFC Award 1974, two attempts were made
for the revision in the design of intergovernmental transfers but these
were unsuccessful. The much awaited NFC Award was then materialised in
1990-91. This was followed by the NFC Award 1996 constituted for a
period of five years (1996-97 to 2001-02), but remained in practice till
2005-06. In 2006, a distribution order from the president of Pakistan
replaced the NFC Award 1997.
On the distribution method, all the commissions up to the fourth
NFC (1991) followed the "gap-filling" approach. This approach
assesses the revenue receipts and expenditure based on the actual
numbers and recommends non-plan deficit grants to fill the financing
gaps. This approach encouraged the provincial governments to understate the predicted growth of their own tax revenues, to increase their
commitments on non-plan expenditure, and to run deficit budgets in the
expectation that their financing gaps would be filled by grants from the
Finance Commission. Apart from encouraging inefficiency, this approach
also resulted in qualifying relatively better off provinces for such
grants while disqualifying some of the poor provinces.
The fifth Finance Commission adopted a new formula for the
allocation of federal transfers. This differed from the previous one on
two grounds: (1) it was based on the new idea of National Resource
Picture; and (2) it included all federal taxes in the divisible pool
with revised shares. In addition, it provided constitutional subvention
for relatively two backward provinces Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (KPK) and
Balochistan. Subsequent NFCs were constituted in 2000 and 2005 but an
award could not be agreed upon. Finally, in the absence of any
recommendation from the sixth Finance Commission, the "Distribution
of Revenues and Grants-in-Aid (Amendment) Order (DRGO) 2006" was
passed by the president of Pakistan. The DRGO 2006 differs with other
NFC Awards in three ways. First, it introduced a variable share of
provincial governments (ranges from 41.50 percent in 2006-07 to 46.25
percent in 2010-11). Second, it introduced two divisible pools: one is
the largest divisible pool which relied on population as a sole
criterion for horizontal distribution and other was used for
distribution of l/6th of the sales tax on new shares of 50, 34.85, 9.93
and 5.22 for Punjab, Sindh, KPK and Balochistan respectively. Third, it
separately awarded grants-in-aid to all provinces based on an unknown
criterion.
2.1. Key Elements of NFC Award 2009
The NFC Award 2009 has brought some profound changes in the
resource distribution formula. It is for the first time since 1973 that
the distribution of resources among provinces is based not only on
population but also on other criteria such as backwardness, inverse
population density and revenue collection/generation. This Award has
also helped in resolving other issues such as GDS and Hydroelectricity
Profit. The financial implications of this Award for the federal and
provincial governments are vast and long-lasting with a substantial
increase in transfers from the federal government to provinces due to
the following five reasons.
(1) The collection charges of the federal government have been
decreased from 5 percent to 1 percent, thereby enlarging the overall
size of the divisible pool.
(2) The federal government and all the four provincial governments
recognised the role of KPK as a frontline province against the war on
terror. One percent of net proceedings of the divisible pool are
therefore earmarked for KPK during the entire award period. For
instance, in 2010-11, KPK will receive an additional amount of Rs 15
billion against the additional costs it is bearing due to the war on
terror.
(3) The remaining proceeds of the provincial share of the divisible
pool have been increased from 46.25 percent to 56 percent in 2010-11 and
then to 57.5 percent for the rest of the award period. This means that
the share of the federal government in the net divisible pool would be
44 percent in 2010-11 and 42.5 percent during the rest of the award
period.
(4) This award ensures that Balochistan will get at least Rs 83
billion under divisible pool transfers. In case the estimated share of
Balochistan is less than Rs 83 billion, the balance funds would be
contributed by federal government.
(5) GST on services collected in the Central Excise (CE) mode is
also transferred to the provincial governments under the straight
transfer mode--implying that revenues collected from a province would be
transferred to that province on the basis of collection. The budget
2010-11, however, did not adhere to this principle.
In addition, the NFC Award 2009 also allows Gas Development
Surcharge (GDS) arrears to be paid retroactively to Balochistan on the
basis of the new formula and for the payment of the long held up hydel
profits to KPK.
2.2. Vertical Distribution of Divisible Pool
Table 2 presents the formula for vertical distribution or the
provincial share in the divisible pool of NFC awards. It indicates that
until the NFC Award 1991, provincial governments had been receiving 80
percent of two major federal taxes "Sales Tax" and
"Income and Corporation Tax", which were the most buoyant
sources of revenues and the focus of tax and tariff reforms initiated in
the early 1990s. Another important point is that the share of provinces
was further increased by including in it the federal excise duty on
tobacco and sugar.
In contrast, the NFC Award 1997 included all federal taxes in the
divisible pool and decreased the provincial share from 80 percent to
37.5 percent, which was less than half of their previous share. This
change was based on optimistic revenue targets of certain macroeconomic projections such as 17 percent growth in nominal GDP, 11 percent
domestic and external inflation rate and higher expectations of revenue
collection from tax and tariff reforms. However, these expectations did
not materialise due to many external and internal shocks that largely
affected the federal tax collection.
2.3. Horizontal Distribution of the Divisible Pool
Table 3 shows the formula for horizontal distribution of the
divisible pool in NFC Awards. It points out that the entire distribution
of divisible pool among provinces in the first three conclusive NFC
Awards and in DRGO was based only on population. However, the NFC Award
2009 framed the distribution of the divisible pool based on four
weighted factors. These include: population (82 percent), poverty and
backwardness (10.3 percent), revenue collection/generation (5 percent)
and inverse population density (2.7 percent).
3. FINANCIAL IMPLICATIONS OF THE NFC AWARD 2009
Table 4 presents the vertical distribution of FBR tax estimates in
Budget 2010-11 as per the NFC Award 2009. The FBR tax revenue target for
2010-11 is Rs 1,647 billion. The federal government will receive money
from these taxes under two heads: (1) divisible pool share, and (2)
others, largely based on collection charges and export duties. According
to this, the total share of the federal government in FBR taxes in
2010-11 would be Rs 683 billion. Similarly, four provincial governments
altogether receive revenues under two heads: (1) divisible pool
transfers, and (2) others, an aggregate of revenue transfer under war on
terror, provincial GST, excise duty on natural gas and grant for
Balochistan to meet the minimum requirement of Rs 83 billion. As a
result, the total share of the four provincial governments would be Rs
964 billion if the FBR achieved its tax collection targets.
Table 5 presents the horizontal distribution of FBR taxes estimates
in Budget 2010-11 as per the NFC Award 2009. Of the total Rs 844 billion
in divisible pool, Punjab would accrue Rs 437 billion (51.7 percent),
Sindh Rs 207 billion (24.6 percent), KPK Rs 123 billion (14.6 percent)
and Balochistan Rs 77 billion (9.1 percent). Of the total 118 billion
transfers in the "others" category, KPK would receive Rs 15.2
billion under the head of war on terror. In order to meet the
requirement of a minimum transfer of Rs 83 billion for Balochistan, the
federal government would give an additional Rs 6.3 billion to
Balochistan. Table 5 also shows the excise duty on natural gas
separately because this is a provincial tax and the federal government
transfers this tax separately to provinces after deducting collection
charges.
An interesting implication of the NFC Award 2009 is the acceptance
of provincial rights over GST services. As per the constitution, GST
services is a provincial tax, however, FBR collects it under two heads:
(1) GST services (CE Mode) and (2) GST services (provincial). While GST
services (provincial) is directly transferred to provincial governments
after deducting collection charges, GST services (CE Mode) is treated as
GST on goods which is distributed among the federal and provincial
governments similar to other divisible pool taxes. The NFC Award 2009
treats both GST services (CE Mode) and GST services (provincial) as GST
services (provincial) and transfers the amount collected under this tax
to provincial governments after deducting collection charges. Thus while
the anomaly in vertical distribution of GST services has been resolved
in the NFC Award 2009, the horizontal distribution of this tax is still
an unsettled impediment. The distribution of GST services shown in Table
5 is as reported in federal budget documents, which is based on
population share of provinces. The distribution of GST on services on
the basis of population, though beneficial for Punjab and KPK, is not in
line with the spirit of the NFC constitution. Nevertheless, the
disagreement over the distribution of GST on services is reflected in
the revised federal budget documents as it is stated "The
indicative share of GST on services (provincial) are strictly
provisional at this stage since a decision on levying a reformed GST has
been deferred to 1st October, 2010. These shares would be revised in the
light of a decision taken after discussion with the provinces. The final
share so determined would take effect from 1st July, 2010."
3.1. Comparison of NFC Award 2009 with DRGO 2006
Table 6 shows the comparison of NFC Award 2009 with DRGO 2006. It
indicates that the federal government would receive almost Rs920 billion
revenues in 2010-11 if the DRGO 2006 would continue. However, due to
revision in resources distribution formula in 2010, the federal
government would get revenues amounting to Rs 685 billion. As a result
of the NFC Award 2009, the federal revenues would decline by Rs 235
billion in 2010-11 compared to revenues under DRGO 2006.
Table 7 shows province-wise financial implications of the NFC
Awards 2010 in comparison with DRGO 2006. It indicates that in absolute
terms, Punjab is the biggest beneficiary of the NFC Award 2009, as it is
likely to receive Rs 83 billion additional revenues in 2010-11 as per
NFC 2010 compared to DRGO 2006. This is on two counts: one,
Punjab's share of higher than 50 percent in the divisible pool
allows it to benefit the most from the huge increase in vertical
transfers; two, the distribution of GST on services on the basis of
population rather than on collection adds to this increase. In
percentage terms, however, Balochistan is the major beneficiary, with an
increase of more than 100 percent, followed by KPK. The relative picture
shows that in percentage terms, the NFC Award 2009 is more beneficial
for relatively backward provinces. Gain from NFC Award 2009 to Sindh may
increase if GST services (provincial) is not distributed on the basis of
population.
3.2. Comparison of the NFC Award 2009 with the NFC Award 1997
Table 8 presents a comparison of federal revenues under the NFC
Award 2009 with the NFC Award 1997. It indicates that the federal
government would receive almost Rs1055 billion in 2010-11 if the 1997
NFC Award would continue. However, due to revision in resource
distribution formula in 2010 the federal government would get Rs685
billion. As a result of the NFC Award 2009 federal revenues would
decline by Rs370 billion in 2010-11 compared to revenues under NFC Award
1997.
Table 9 highlights the province-wise financial implications of the
NFC Awards 2010 in comparison with the NFC Award 1997. The province-wise
federal transfers show that in absolute terms, Punjab is likely to
receive Rs152 billion additional revenues in 2010-11 as per the NFC
Award 2009 compared to the 1997 NFC Award. The comparative picture of
other provinces show that Sindh, KPK and Balochistan are likely to
receive Rs 90 billion, Rs 70 billion and Rs 57 billion additional
revenues in 2010-11 as per the NFC 2010 compared to the NFC Award 1997.
3.3. Comparison of NFC Award 2009 with NFC Award 1991
Table 10 displays a comparison of federal revenues under the NFC
Award 2009 with the NFC Award 1991. While the previous two comparisons
show that the NFC Award 2009 caused a declined in federal revenues,
comparison with NFC Award 1991 gives an opposite picture. It indicates
that federal government would receive almost Rs 607 billion in 2010-11
if the 1991 NFC Award would continue. However, due to revision in
resources distribution formula in 2010 it would get Rs 685 billion.
Thus, as a result of the NFC Award 2009, the federal government is
likely to receive an addition of Rs 78 billion in comparison with the
NFC Award 1991. It is important to note that while revenues from
customs, capital value tax and part of federal excise are not shared
with provincial governments, the high share of provinces in two buoyant
sources of revenues income and sales tax causes a substantial reduction
in federal revenues.
Table 11 brings to light a very important aspect of the NFC Award
2009 in comparison with the NFC Award 1991. It indicates that while
there is a decline in vertical share of provinces under the NFC Award
2009 compared to the 1991 NFC Award, this decline is not evenly
distributed among the provinces. For instance, if the NFC Award 1991 had
continued, Punjab and Sindh would have been likely to receive an
additional amount of Rs 105 billion and Rs 17 billion respectively
compared to the NFC Award 2009. In contrast, KPK and Balochistan would
have been likely to receive Rs 8 billion and Rs 35 billion less in
2010-11 respectively compared to transfers as per the NFC Award 2009.
This indicates that the NFC Award 2009 benefits the two relatively more
backward provinces, KPK and Balochistan.
4. IMPACT ON SOCIAL SERVICES
Public expenditure on social services such as education and health
is generally considered as a source of poverty reduction as it
contributes to human capital formation. Moreover, public spending on
social services would likely cause a positive impact on achieving the
Millennium Development Goals. However, Pakistan falls among the
countries that spend a very low share of their GDP on the social sector.
Table 12 shows a comparison of Pakistan with other East and South
Asian countries. It is interesting to note that public spending on
education in Bangladesh is higher than the public spending on three
social services in Pakistan namely education, health, and water supply
and sanitation. Even public spending on education in India is more than
double what it is in Pakistan. Similarly, governments in Thailand,
Malaysia, Iran and Vietnam spend a much higher share of their GDP on
education as compared to Pakistan. Several plans have been made to
increase the share on public spending on social services in Pakistan. At
policy planning level almost all policy documents including five year
plans, MTDF, MTBF, PRSPs gave greater importance to social sector
spending. Similarly, the 1997 NFC Award and the Fiscal Responsibility
and Debt Limitation Act, 2005 included social sector spending in the
list of priority expenditures. However social sector spending has
remained very low, particularly after the 1997 NFC award. The allocation
of higher share of taxes to provinces under the seventh NFC Award
provides a hope that these expenditures as a percentage of GDP may rise
during the current five year period.
In this context, this section analyses the estimated impact of
financial implications of the NFC Award 2009 in comparison with the DRGO
2006, the NFC Award 1997 and the NFC Award 1991 on provincial social
services. The analysis is based on a hypothesis that a change in design
of federal transfers in favour of provincial government would be likely
to cause an increase in social sector expenditures. This may occur
because provincial governments are primarily responsible for the
financing and delivery of social services and any increase in their
resources may allow them to allocate and spend more money on social
services.
4.1. Empirical Strategy
A search of publically available research did not indicate
sufficient empirical studies that tested the response of change in
intergovernmental transfers on social services expenditures. There is a
substantial descriptive literature addressing many aspects of
intergovernmental transfers with respect to fiscal competition among the
sub-national governments [Musgrave (1997)], market incentives of
federalism [Qian and Weingast (1997)], intergovernmental transfers and
deadweight losses in tax system [Smart (1996)], coordination failure [De
Mello Jr. (2000)], survey of approaches in designing intergovernmental
fiscal transfers [Bird and Smart (2002)], principles and practices of
intergovernmental transfer [Boadway and Shah (2007)] and finally social
policy and state revenues [Hinojosa, Bebbington, Barrientos, and Addison
(2010)]. However, this body of work really did not shed much light on
the normative question of consequences of any change in the designed
mechanism of intergovernmental transfers on provincial expenditures.
In Pakistan Ghaus and Pasha (1996) and Sabir (2001) developed and
tested an econometric model for Pakistan to evaluate the consequences of
the NFC Awards 1991 and 1997. The current study has benefitted with the
methodological framework developed in Sabir (2002) which developed two
separate equations to estimate the impact of the NFC Award 1997 on the
social sector and other service related expenditures (see Appendix). In
line with its scope this paper is restricted to the estimation of the
following equation derived for social services expenditures.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
For estimation purposes the above equation can be re-written as
SE = [c.sub.0] + [c.sub.1] [[p.sub.1]Y/[p.sub.2]] - [c.sub.2]
[[p.sub.1]/[p.sub.2]] + [c.sub.3] [(T + [G.sub.0] + B*D92)/[p.sub.2]] +
[c.sub.4] [[B*D91/[p.sub.2]]
Where
SE = real per capita social sector expenditures (both recurring and
development)
Y = real per capita income
[p.sub.1] = General Price Level (CPI)
[p.sub.2] = price index of public expenditure
T = per capita total intergovernmental transfers
B = per capita borrowing by the provincial government
m = proportion of the provincial revenue deficit financed by
deficit grants
[G.sub.0] = lump sum grants
D91 = capturing the impact of deficit grants and having value 1
prior to implementation 1991 NFC Award afterwards zero
D92 = having value zero prior to 1991 NFC Award afterwards 1
Estimated Results
Due to limitation on the availability of the basic data (for
example, the data on provincial gross domestic products and inflation
are not available), province wise analysis was not possible. Therefore,
the above model was estimated for the four provincial governments
combined. Annual budget statements of the individual provinces have been
used to generate the aggregate database for key provincial budgetary
magnitudes. The above equation is estimated for the period 1972-73 to
2007-08. Results of estimation are given in Table 13.
The signs of all the estimated coefficients are theoretically
consistent. Each coefficient is significantly different from zero at a 5
percent significance level as apparent from the t-statistics. The value
of adjusted [R.sup.2] indicates that the first model explains almost 98
percent variation in provincial social sector expenditures. According to
the estimated equation an increase or decrease of Rs 100 in either the
real federal transfers or lump sum grants or borrowing can affect the
social sector expenditures by Rs 19.40 in real terms.
Based on the above estimated equation and projected values of all
explanatory variables for 2010-11, social sector expenditures are
forecasted for transfers under the NFC Award 2009, the DRGO 2006, the
NFC Award 1997 and the NFC Award 1997. Table 14 provides these
forecasted values. It indicates that after the NFC Award 1991 transfers
under the NFC Award 2009 are likely to cause a higher increase in social
sector expenditure. In the absence of a conclusive NFC Award in 2010,
DRGO 2006 would have been continued in 2010-11. Therefore, a comparison
of social sector expenditure is made with DRGO 2006. As indicated by the
last column of Table 14, due to a conclusive NFC Award in 2010, it is
expected that spending on social sectors would increase by more than Rs
45 billion.
5. CONCLUSION
NFC Awards are regularly set up after every five years under
article 160 of the constitution. However, there are fewer examples of
conclusive NFC Awards due to lack of consensus among federating units.
In this regard, the NFC Award 2009 is a big success of the present
democratic regime. This Award successfully made substantial changes in
the design of the resource distribution mechanism. It explicitly
introduced multiple indicators for horizontal distribution for the first
time, allocated higher share of resources to provincial governments and
correspondingly lower share to federal government. Given that provincial
governments are largely responsible for financing and delivery of social
services, this paper makes an attempt to simulate the impact of this
increase on social services expenditures. The projected values of social
sector expenditures indicate that the NFC Award 2009 has a potentially
positive impact on social sector spending. Given that Pakistan has a
comparative low spending on social services, this award is a positive
move. Hence, it also helps increasing the pace of achieving MDGs
targets.
APPENDIX
Methodology Brief
The estimated equation is based on the methodological framework
developed in Sabir (2002). A brief description of the major assumptions
used in developing microtheoretic framework is reproduced below.
The methodological framework is based on the assumption that
politicians/ officials want to maximise the utility of a typical
consumer (median consumer) in their jurisdiction subject to budget
constraint. For the sake of simplicity, the consumption basket of a
typical citizen (median consumer) can be divided into two broad groups;
publicly provided goods and services (A), and privately provided goods
and services (B). Utility was assumed to depend positively on the
quantity of goods and services provided by the provincial government (A)
and on the level of consumption of private goods (B).
U = U ([Q.sub.A], [Q.sub.B])
The goods and services provided by provincial government can be
divided into social services and, other goods and services
U = U ([Q.sub.S], [Q.sub.O], [Q.sub.B])
The quantity of demand of each good and services depends upon the
expenditure (public/private) on it. In the case of private goods and
services, expenditure would be equal to real per capita disposable
income of the consumer or (y - R), where y is the real per capita income
and R is the real per capita revenue received by the government.
Similarly, in case of publicly provided goods and services, expenditure
would be equal to provincial government expenditure on social services
(SE) and other services (OE). Therefore, the utility function can be
rewritten as
U = U(SE, OE, Y - R) (1)
R includes both tax and non-tax revenues, while SE and OE consist
of both recurring, and development expenditures on publically provided
social services and other services. The payments for servicing of debt
are excluded as these do not benefit citizens directly through provision
of services.
The sources of revenues for provincial government except its own
revenues are federal transfers from the divisible pool, development and
non-development grants and borrowings. Therefore, the budget constraint
of the provincial government (at current prices) can be expressed as:
[p.sub.2](SE + OE) = [p.sub.1]R + T + B + G (2)
Where
Y = real per capita income
R = real per capita provincial revenue (include both tax and
non-tax revenues)
SE = real per capita social sector expenditures (both recurring and
development)
OE = real per capita other expenditures (both recurring and
development)
[p.sub.1] = General Price Level (CPI)
[p.sub.2] = price index of public expenditure
T = per capita total intergovernmental transfers
B = per capita borrowing by the provincial government
G consisted of two types of grants from federal government to
provincial governments. These are lump sum grants (heavily consists of
development grants) and deficit grant (heavily consists of
non-development and non-obligatory grants). Therefore, by definition,
the total flow of grants is given as:
G = [G.sub.0] + m[[p.sub.2](SE + OE) - [p.sub.1]R - [bar.T] -
[G.sub.0]], 0 < m < 1 (3)
Where m = proportion of the revenue deficit financed by deficit
grants.
Deficit grant has played a very significant role in the provincial
finances before 1991 but this option was curtailed in the 1991 NFC
Award. However, lump sum grants are still provided to the provinces for
their development projects.
Substituting (3) into (2) we obtain,
[p.sub.2](SE + OE) = [p.sub.1]R + [bar.T] + [[bar.G].sub.0] +
[G.sub.D] + [bar.B] (4)
After addition of [p.sub.1]y on both sides of the equation (4) the
budget constraint can be written as:
[p.sub.1](Y - R) + [p.sub.2]SSE + [p.sub.2]OSE + = [p.sub.1]Y +
[bar.T] + [[bar.G].sub.0] + [G.sub.D] + B (5)
Based on the above set of equations, a utility maximisation problem
can be set up as follows:
l(R, SE, OE, [lambda]) = U(Y - R, SE, OE) + [lambda][I =
[p.sub.1](Y - R) - [p.sub.2](SE + OE)] (6)
Where I = [P.sub.1]Y + T + [G.sub.0] + [G.sub.D] + B
The first order conditions are as follows:
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative]R = [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative](Y - R) + [lambda][p.sub.1] = 0 (7)
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative]SE = [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative]SE + [lambda][p.sub.2] = 0 (8)
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative]OE = [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative]OE + [lambda][p.sub.2] = 0 (9)
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative][lambda] = I -
[p.sub.1](Y - R) - [p.sub.2](SE + OE) = 0 (10)
The above derivation based on a micro-theoretic approach provides
the information on the signs of partial derivatives of the function, but
it needs an explicit utility function for estimation purposes. In the
analysis of consumer behaviour, many utility functions were used and
among them, we chose the analogous Stone-Geary utility function for the
estimation of the model.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
0 < [[alpha].sub.1] < 1,
0 < [[alpha].sub.2] < 1,
0 < [[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2] < 1,
The Stone-Geary utility function has particular advantages over
other functions. The most important advantage of the Stone-Geary utility
function is the inclusion of [y.sub.0], [SE.sub.0], and [OE.sub.0].
which are "minimum survival bundles" and ensure the
subsistence level of consumer demand for public and private goods and
services. Substituting the derivatives of utility function into (7), (8)
and (9) respectively, yields
[P.sub.1](Y - R) = (1 - [[alpha].sub.1] -
[[alpha].sub.2])U/[lambda] + [P.sub.1][Y.sub.0] (12)
[P.sub.2]SE = [[alpha].sub.1]U/[lambda] + [P.sub.2][SE.sub.0] (13)
[P.sub.2]OE = [[alpha].sub.2]U/[lambda] + [P.sub.2][OE.sub.0] (14)
Substituting the value of [p.sub.2]SE, [p.sub.2]E and
[p.sub.1](Y-R) from (12), (13) and (14) into (5) we obtained
U/[lambda] = [p.sub.1](Y - [Y.sub.0]) + T + [G.sub.0] + B/1 - m -
[p.sub.2]([SE.sub.0] + [OE.sub.0]) (15)
Minimum bundle of income Y0 was assumed to be partly constant and
partly rises with income y.
[y.sub.0] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1]y
Therefore, Equation 15 can be written as:
U/[lambda] = (1 - [[alpha].sub.1])[p.sub.1]Y -
[[alpha].sub.0][p.sub.1] + T + [G.sub.0] + B/1 - m -
[p.sub.2]([SE.sub.0] + [OE.sub.0]) (16)
After substituting the value from Equation 16 into 12, 13 and 14,
we finally have the following system of equation for estimation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (17)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
Equations (17) and (18) are the desired expenditure equations.
Divided both equations by [p.sub.2] we have the following functional
form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
After 1991 NFC Award value of m became zero
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (22)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (23)
The value of D91 is 1 prior to 1991 NFC Award otherwise zero and
the value of D92 is 1 after the 1991 NFC Award, otherwise zero.
REFERENCES
Bird, R. and M. Smart (2002) Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers:
International Lessons for Developing Countries. World Development 30:6,
899-912.
Boadway, R. and A. Shah (2007) Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers:
Principles and Practice. The World Bank. (Public Sector Governance and
Accountability Series).
De Mello Jr. Luiz R. (2000) Fiscal Decentralisation and
Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations: A Cross-country Analysis. World
Development 28:2, 365-380.
Ghous, A. F. Aisha (1996) Intergovernmental Revenue Sharing in
Pakistan. Social Policy and Development Centre. (Research Report No. 8.)
Ghous, A. F. Aisha and Hafiz A. Pasha (1994) Dynamic Budgetary
Consequences of the 1991 NFC Award. The Pakistan Development Review
33:4, 627-645.
Henderson, James M. (1968) Local Government Expenditures: A Social
Welfare Analysis. The Review of Economics and Statistics 50, 156-163.
Hinojosa, L., A. Bebbington, A. Barrientos, and T. Addison (2010)
Social Policy and State Revenues in Mineral-Rich Contexts. United
Nations Research Institute for Social Development. (Social Policy and
Development Programme Paper Number 44).
Ma, Jun (1997) Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfer: A Comparison of
Nine Countries. Prepared for Macroeconomic Management and Policy
Division, Economic Development Institutes, The World Bank.
Musgrave, Richard A. (1997) Devolution, Grants, and Fiscal
Competition. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:4, 65-72.
Oates, Walles E. (1999) An Essay on Fiscal Federalism. Journal of
Economic literature 37, 1120-1149.
Pakistan, Government of (1996) Report of the National Finance
Commission. National Finance Commission Secretariat, Islamabad.
Pakistan, Government of (n.d.) 7th National Finance Commission
Report and Explanatory Memorandum. Finance Division, Islamabad.
Pasha, Hafiz A. (n.d.) Fiscal Decentralisation: Lessons from the
Asian Experience. Social Policy and Development Centre. (Research Report
No. 19).
Qian, Yingy, and Barry R. Weingast (1997) Federalism as a
Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11:4, 83-92.
Quigley, John R. and Daniel L. Rubinfeld (1996) Federalism and
Reductions in the Federal Budget. National Tax Journal 49:2, 289-302.
Sabir, Muhammad (2001) Dynamic Consequences of the 1997 NFC Award:
Provincial Social Sector Expenditures. The Pakistan Development Review
40:4, 967-984.
Shah, Anwar (n.d.) Fiscal Federalism and Macroeconomic Governance:
For Better or For Worse? Public Sector Management (Institutional Reform)
Coordinator, Operations Evaluation Department, World Bank.
Shah, Anwar and Zia Qureshi (n.d.) Intergovernmental Fiscal
Relations in Indonesia: Issues and Options. World Bank. (World Bank
Discussion Paper 239).
Slack, Enid (1980) Local Fiscal Response to Intergovernmental
Transfers. The Review of Economics and Statistics 62:3, 364-370.
Smart, M. (1996) Taxation Incentives and Deadweight Loss in a
System of Intergovernmental Transfers. Department of Economics and
Institute for Policy Analysis, University of Toronto. (Working Paper
Number ut-ecipa-msmart-96-03 July 22, 1996).
(1) Since the model is based on ratios, non stationary issues did
not exist in estimation. This is further investigated by using Augmented
Dickey Fuller unit root test in E-views, which confirmed the stationary
nature of the variables used in estimation. These results are available
on request from the author.
Muhammad Sabir <muhammadsabir@spdc.org.pk> is Principal
Economist, Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC), Karachi.
Table 1
Chronology of NFC Awards
S. No. Name Status
First NFC Award 1974 Conclusive
Second NFC Award 1979 Inconclusive
Third NFC Award 1985 Inconclusive
Fourth NFC Award 1991 Conclusive
Fifth NFC Award 1995 Inconclusive
NFC Award 1997 Conclusive
Sixth NFC Award 2002 Inconclusive
Distribution Order 2006 --
Seventh NFC Award 2009 Conclusive
Table 2
Provincial Share in Divisible Pool Taxes
(%)
Divisible Pool Taxes NFC 1974 NFC 1991 NFC 1997
Income Tax and Corporation Tax * 80 80 37.5
--Other Direct Taxes -- -- 37.5
Sales Tax 80 80 37.5
Central Excise Duty ** --
--Tobacco -- 80 37.5
--Sugar -- 80
Import Duties -- -- 37.5
Export Duties
--Cotton 80 80 --
Divisible Pool Taxes DRGO 2006 NFC 2010
Income Tax and Corporation Tax * 41.50-46.25 56.0-57.5
--Other Direct Taxes 41.50-46.25 56.0-57.5
Sales Tax 41.50-46.25 56.0-57.5
Central Excise Duty **
--Tobacco 41.50-46.25 56.0-57.5
--Sugar
Import Duties 41.50-46.25 56.0-57.5
Export Duties
--Cotton -- --
* Excluding taxes on income consisting of remuneration paid out of
federal consolidated fund.
** Excluding Central Excise Duty on Natural Gas.
Table 3
Factors Used in Horizontal Distribution of Divisible Pool Taxes
Factors NFC 1974 NFC 1991 NFC 1997
Population 100.0 100.0 100.0
Poverty/Backwardness -- -- --
Revenue Collection/Generation -- -- --
Inverse Population Density -- -- --
Factors DRGO 2006 * NFC 2010
Population 100.0 82.0
Poverty/Backwardness -- 10.3
Revenue Collection/Generation -- 5.0
Inverse Population Density -- 2.7
* Other than 1/6th of sales tax collected and distributed in
lieu of Octroi/Zila Tax.
Table 4
Vertical Distribution of FBR Taxes as per the 7th NFC Award
(Rs Million)
Federal Revenues
Budget Divisible Others Total
Estimates Pool
2010-11
Income Tax 633,000 270,220 10,113 280,333
Capital Value Tax 4,700 2,027 28 2,055
Customs 180,800 76,231 5,079 81,310
Sales Tax 674,900 251,802 3,465 255,267
Federal Excise 153,600 63,095 868 63,964
Total 1,647,000 663,375 19,553 682,929
Provincial Revenues
Divisible Others Total
Pool
Income Tax 343,916 8,751 352,667
Capital Value Tax 2,580 66 2,645
Customs 97,021 2,469 99,490
Sales Tax 320,475 99,157 419,633
Federal Excise 80,303 9,333 89,636
Total 844,296 119,776 964,071
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts 2010-11.
Table 5
Horizontal Distribution of FBR Taxes as per the 7th NFC Award
(Rs Millions)
Punjab Sindh KPK
Divisible Pool Taxes
Taxes on Income 177,942 84,431 50,281
Capital Value Tax 1,335 633 377
Sales Tax (Goods) 50,199 23,819 14,185
Federal Excise (Net of Gas) 165,814 78,677 46,853
Customs Duties 41,549 19,714 11,740
Total: Divisible Taxes (A) 436,839 207,275 123,436
Others
War on Terror/Other Transfers -- -- 15,229
Excise Duty on Natural Gas 407 5,025 209
G.S.T (Provincial) 51,155 21,145 12,325
Total: Other Transfers (B) 51,563 26,170 27,763
Total Transfers (A+B) 488,401 233,445 151,199
Balochistan Total
Divisible Pool Taxes
Taxes on Income 31,262 343,916
Capital Value Tax 234 2,580
Sales Tax (Goods) 8,819 97,021
Federal Excise (Net of Gas) 29,131 320,475
Customs Duties 7,300 80,303
Total: Divisible Taxes (A) 76,746 844,296
Others
War on Terror/Other Transfers 6,254 21,483
Excise Duty on Natural Gas 1,503 7,144
G.S.T (Provincial) 4,557 89,183
Total: Other Transfers (B) 12,314 117,810
Total Transfers (A+B) 89,060 962,106
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts 2010-11.
Table 6
Comparative Impact on Federal Revenues NFC Award 2009 and DRGO 2006
(Rs Million)
NFC Award 2009 DRGO 2006 Difference
Income Tax 280,333 357,803 -77,470
Capital Value Tax 2,055 2,635 -580
Customs 81,310 103,132 -21,822
Sales Tax 257,087 374,142 -117,054
Federal Excise 64,109 82,171 -18,061
Total 684,894 919,882 -234,988
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts 2010-11.
Table 7
Comparative Impact on Provincial Revenues NFC Award 2009 and DRGO
2006
(Rs Million)
NFC Award 2009 DRGO 2006 Difference
Punjab 488,401 405,607 82,794
Sindh 233,445 187,502 45,943
Khyber Pakhtunkhwa 151,199 95,599 55,600
Balochistan 89,060 38,410 50,650
Total 962,106 727,118 234,988
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts.
Table 8
Comparative Impact on Federal Revenues NFC Award 2009 and NFC Award
1997
(Rs Million)
NFC Award 2009 NFC Award 1997 Difference
Income Tax 280,333 409,868 -129,535
Capital Value Tax 2,055 3,026 -971
Customs 81,310 117,826 -36,516
Sales Tax 257,087 429,616 -172,529
Federal Excise 64,109 94,333 -30,223
Total 684,894 1,054,668 -369,773
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11
published in Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts.
Table 9
Comparative Impact on Provincial Revenues NFC Award 2009 and NFC
Award 1997
(Rs Million)
NFC Award 2009 NFC Award 1997 Difference
Punjab 488,401 336,071 152,330
Sindh 233,445 143,773 89,672
Khyber Pakhtunkhwa 151,199 81,082 70,117
Balochistan 89,060 31,406 57,654
Total 962,106 592,332 369,773
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts.
Table 10
Comparative Impact on Federal Revenues NFC Award 2009 and NFC Award
1991
(Rs Million)
NFC Award 2009 NFC Award 1991 Difference
Income Tax 280,333 156,984 123,349
Capital Value Tax 2,055 4,700 -2,645
Customs 81,310 180,800 -99,490
Sales Tax 257,087 160,168 96,920
Federal Excise 64,109 104,050 -39,941
Total 684,894 606,702 78,193
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-11,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts 2010-11.
Table 11
Comparative Impact on Provincial Revenues NFC Award 2009
and NFCAward 1991
(Rs Million)
NFC Award 2009 NFC Award 1991 Difference
Punjab 488,401 593,025 -104,623
Sindh 233,445 249,986 -16,541
Khyber Pakhtunkhwa 151,199 142,991 8,208
Balochistan 89,060 54,297 34,763
Total 962,106 1,040,298 -78,193
Source: Author's estimates based on Budget Estimates of 2010-1,
Explanatory Memorandum on Federal Receipts 2010-11.
Table 12
Public Sector Spending on Education: A Comparison
with Selected Asian Countries
(As Percentage of GDP)
Country Public Sector Spending
Vietnam 5.3
Iran 5.2
Malaysia 4.7
Thailand 4.5
Indonesia 3.5
India 3.3
Nepal 3.2
Bangladesh 2.6
Pakistan
Education 1.5
Health 0.7
Water Supply and Sanitation 0.2
Total 2.4
Source: Pakistan Economic Survey 2009-10 for other countries and
Authors estimate for Pakistan.
Table 13
Results of Estimation-1973-74 to 2009-101
Dependent Variable-Real Per Capita Social Sector Expenditures
Independent Variable Constant [P.sub.1]Y/ [p.sub.1]/
[p.sub.2] [p.sub.2]
Coefficient -0.058 +0.018 -1.381
t-Statistic (-0.071) (4.991) (-2.257)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.978
Independent Variable (T+[G.sub.0]+B+D92)/ [B.sup.*]D91 DUM
[p.sub.2]
Coefficient +0.194 +0.301 0.908
t-Statistic (4.369) (4.194) (10.230)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] Durbin-Watson stat 1.798
Table 14
Impact of NFC Awards on Social Sector Expenditures
(Rs Billion)
Forecast Difference
DRGO 2006 409.7 0.0
7th NFC Award 455.3 45.6
1997 NFC Award 383.5 -26.2
1991 NFC Award 470.5 60.8