Reminiscing the PIDE.
Khan, A.R.
I first arrived at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics,
then simply the Institute of Development Economics, at the beginning of
October 1960. It was located on the top floor of the Old Sindh Assembly
Building on Bunder Road in Karachi. At the. time the Joint Director, the
resident head of the Institute, was Irving Brecher, a Canadian
economist. The Director of the Institute was Emile Despres, the
ex-officio head of Ford Foundation's Pakistan Project administered
from Williams College, later from Stanford University, who spent only a
few weeks each year at the Institute. The Institute had a number of
foreign research advisers funded by the Ford Foundation Project and a
handful of Pakistani staff members, very few of them at senior levels.
For me the Institute was a refuge. Since my graduation from the
Dhaka University at the end of 1959 I had been teaching in the
Department of Economics. I had also been selected for graduate studies
in England starting the fall of 1960 under an award of the
newly-instituted Commonwealth Scholarship programme. In July 1960 I was
dismissed from my teaching position at the University due to alleged
undesirable political antecedents during my student days. A few weeks
later my scholarship for study abroad was also withdrawn by the
Government of Pakistan whose approval was a prerequisite for the
finalisation of the award. The prospect of alternative employment was
bleak with little private sector demand for economics graduates at the
time.
I had been interviewed by Emile Despres and his colleagues who were
on a recruitment mission the previous winter in Dhaka. The teaching
appointment at the University, coming on the heels of the interview, had
preempted a possible offer from them. A few weeks after I lost my
scholarship, I received a telegram from the Institute offering me the
position of a Research Officer (later named Staff Economist). This
rescued me from what appeared to be virtual banishment from all
possibility of a meaningful career. This was the beginning of the series
of many kind acts by the Institute and its members which over time made
me accustomed to treating it as a home even after my formal employment
in it ended.
When Irving Brecher's term as the Joint Director ended a few
months after my arrival, he was replaced by Henry Bruton. Among other
foreign advisors were Gustav Ranis (who also left soon after my
arrival), John Fei, Richard Porter and John Power. I was assigned to
work with Richard Porter. John Fei used to deliver weekly lectures on
his pet subject of 'linear graph' method of solving
simultaneous systems. Syed Naseem, who had studied at the London School
of Economics and was one of the few senior members of the staff, used to
correct our homework assignments. In 1961 a formal training programme on
development theory and quantitative methods was instituted as
preparatory to graduate study abroad.
In 1962 the Institute selected me, along with Aminul Islam and
Swadesh Bose, for graduate studies in the USA under Ford Foundation
scholarship. I was admitted at a number of places of which I chose the
MIT. We applied for and received US visas. Several weeks later, when I
was on a farewell visit to Dhaka prior to the planned departure for the
USA, news arrived that the US consulate had revoked our visas. Once
again the reason was alleged political antecedents during student days.
Once again I seemed to have reached the dead end as the Institute's
scholarships, funded by the Ford Foundation, had until then been
available only for graduate studies in the United States. By that time
Henry Bruton had returned to Williams College and was replaced by Mark
Leiserson from Yale. He offered to send all three of us to England for
graduate studies, an offer that Bose and I eagerly grabbed. This was yet
another unusual act that made me deeply grateful to the Institute. Mian
Nazir Ahmad, the Secretary of the Institute, helped me cross the
potentially hazardous process of obtaining a passport; the validity of
my previous passport had expired.
I went to Cambridge in 1963 and returned in October 1966 after
completing my PhD I received very rapid promotions before ending up in
the summer of 1969 as a Research Director, the highest professional
grade at the PIDE at the time. In 1968 I was appointed the first
Pakistani editor of The Pakistan Development Review, the journal of the
PIDE. In September 1970 I took leave from the PIDE to accept a position
as research fellow at Nuffield College, Oxford. I have distinct
recollection of the send-off reception given to me by my colleagues. My
own words at the event sounded like a farewell speech. By that time the
political horizon was full of signals of the impending calamity. Within
months of my departure for Oxford Pakistan was engulfed in turmoil from
which both the country and the Institute emerged into two separate
entities. In April 1972 I returned to the Bangladesh Institute of
Development Economics (a few years later given its present name the
Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies) but never quite worked in
it. Almost immediately I began serving in the newly-created Bangladesh
Planning Commission. In September 1973 I resigned from both the Planning
Commission and the Institute to take up a lectureship at the London
School of Economics.
The subject of these pages is personal reminiscence of my days at
the PIDE during the early years of its development. And yet it does not
seem right to completely avoid a discussion of the work at the
Institute. In a paper titled PIDE's Contribution to Development
Thinking: The Earlier Phase, published on the occasion of the golden
jubilee of the PIDE, I outlined the principal components of what I
consider to have been an outstanding achievement for a research
institution anywhere in the developing world. Starting from the scratch,
with no national staff to speak of at the beginning of the 1960s, how
did it succeed in achieving this height with a vibrant journal; a strong
national staff producing the large majority of its research output; a
forum where development thinkers from abroad collaborated with the
indigenous staff in making major contributions in international
development; and a producer of thought that significantly influenced
development policy? I shall highlight a few factors that seem to me to
have been critical. No doubt others have different and more extensive
lists.
There was an entrepreneurial coalition consisting of some members
of the bureaucracy and civil society; an international group of
economists and advisors committed to the creation of research capability
within Pakistan; and an initial donor--the Ford Foundation--willing to
commit resources. The sequence of events and the relative importance of
the roles of the components in the coalition differ in different
narratives about how the Institute emerged.
There was an early recognition by the PIDE leadership that the
necessary senior staff--its technical humanpower--will have to be
created by internal investment by itself. The country did not have a
pool of trained economists and demographers who might be attracted to
the Institute to build up its staff. There was an acute shortage of
highly trained personnel in these, as in most other, fields and the PIDE
was in no position to compete with the government and others in bidding
for the services of those who were there. It therefore decided to train
its future senior staff. It instituted a programme of graduate studies
abroad which served as an inducement for the best graduates in economics
from domestic universities to join the Institute. Recognising that
domestic graduates were often not adequately prepared for graduate
studies at best foreign universities, it instituted a training programme
focusing on basic development theory and quantitative methods. Right
from the beginning the Institute's training activities provided
substantial externality: the in-house training programmes were open to
economists already working with the government and semi-government
agencies; Ford Foundation's scholarship programme for higher
studies abroad was expanded and opened up to candidates from outside the
Institute which continued to administer it.
The retention rate of the staff trained abroad was high. They were
required to serve the Institute for three years on their return, but the
high retention rate was not due to the enforcement of this contract.
Good performance was rewarded by quick promotion and a work environment
that guaranteed autonomy and opportunity for exciting research. I do not
think that the Institute could have prevented a member of its staff from
leaving. merely by enforcing the contractual obligation if the
Government wanted his/her services. I myself am a case in point: two
years after my return from Cambridge I was offered a high position in
the Planning Commission. The Institute countered this by promoting me
yet again to the position of Research Director which made me turn down
the offer from the Planning Commission.
Within the Institute the 'rule of law' and the avoidance
of arbitrary interference were practiced to a very high degree.
Publications in the Journal were subject to anonymous peer review to
which all, including the Director and the members of the international
advisory board, submitted. Non-arbitrary rule of law was undoubtedly a
strong factor in improving the commitment of the independent-minded
researchers to the Institute.
The broader environment of incentives at the time helped the
implementation of all the above. The pull of international brain drain
was much weaker than now. The assault of international and national
agencies bidding for the consultancy services of the skilled economists
was almost non-existent. During the entire period that I was a member of
the PIDE staff I never once received a consultancy assignment.
Pakistan had an authoritarian government during the entire period
that I have reviewed. And yet the government tolerated independent
research whose findings were at times inconsistent with the policies and
objectives pursued by the government. The quid pro quo of the implicit
contract was that the Institute avoided involvement in public
controversies and direct conflict with the government. The two sides
understood the rules: the government accepted that a degree of autonomy
and independence had to be guaranteed to enable the finest domestic
centre of applied research to produce output that the country could not
afford to do without while the Institute understood that the price of
this autonomy was self-imposed distance from politically sensitive
controversies. This is of course my personal understanding of the
implicit rules of the game. Others may have different views.
By the end of the 1960s the core national staff had taken over the
leadership of the Institute, producing much of its research and running
most of its training programme, relegating the foreign advisors to a
supporting role. It had become internationally recognised as the
principal centre of applied economic research in Pakistan. The PDR had
internationally established itself as a major journal of development.
With the passage of time many of the conditions described above
changed. As a result the PIDE must also have developed coping mechanisms
which enabled it to maintain its preeminent position as a centre of
research and attain its new role of a university for graduate-level
studies in social sciences. That is a story that must be told by those
who have lived through it.
After formal severance from the Institute, my relations with both
the organisations succeeding the original PIDE were gradually
reestablished. My first visit to the PIDE after 1970 took place in May
1978. By that time I was working for the ILO in Geneva and the PIDE had
shifted to Islamabad. The purpose of my visit to Islamabad was to
participate at a Conference held at the Institute on Basic Needs, then a
recently-emerged focus of development. I have vivid recollection of the
visit. It was like returning to an exuberantly-welcoming home that had
acquired many new members during my long absence. There was a large
reception at the Islamabad Club on the day I arrived; and lunches and
dinners every day at the home of or hosted by a former colleague,
inevitably starting with Syed Naseem. Besides participating at the
Conference, I separately gave seminars at the PIDE and at the
Quaid-i-Azam University. Dr Sultan Hashmi was the Joint Director at the
time, the Director, Mr. M. L. Qureshi being away. I was deeply touched
by the affection shown me during the visit: several retired former
colleagues, including Mian Nazir Ahmad, came to see me. I visited the
PIDE again in September 1982 when Syed Naqvi was the Director and I was
heading the Asian Employment Programme of the ILO. It was then that Dr
Naqvi invited me to serve as a member of the Board of Editors of the
PDR, a position that I held for decades. My most recent visit to the
PIDE was in December 1997 when Sarfraz Qureshi, then Director, invited
me to attend the PSDE Conference on the occasion of the 50th anniversary
of Pakistan. It was a grand celebration where I met many old friends. I
was again invited in 2008 by Rashid Amjad, then and now the
Vice-Chancellor, to attend PIDE's golden jubilee celebrations.
Although I completed and submitted the paper that I was asked to
prepare, I had to cancel my visit literally on the eve of my departure
due to the back injury that my wife accidentally sustained on that day.
Now that the PSDE is holding a special session to remember me at its
Annual Conference in 2010, I am once again unable to accept the
invitation to attend due to prior travel commitments tied to important
family obligations.
I am profoundly grateful to the organisers of the Conference for
the extraordinary kindness in holding a special session to remember me.
I know I do not deserve this honour. I view this as a reflection of what
the friends at the PIDE and PSDE wanted me to achieve rather than what I
have actually achieved. The gap between the two is very large, but that
could never quite succeed in blocking the flow of PIDE's affection
for me.
New York, December 2010
A. R. Khan is Professor Emeritus of Economics, at the University of
California, Riverside. He is a former Research Director of the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics and the first Pakistani to have
edited The Pakistan Development Review.
Reflection on A. R. Khan
S.M. NASEEM
Mr Chairman, Vice-Chancellor Rashid Amjad, Professor Hafeez Pasha,
distinguished and more importantly, useful members of the audience.
It is a pleasure for me to participate in this Special Session to
pay tribute to one of the most illustrious alumnae of PIDE, the parent
institute of its surviving twins, PIDE and BIDS, Dr A. R. Khan whose
presence on this occasion is being sorely missed. I wish PIDE had
persuaded him to be here and share our feelings and allow us to share
his wisdom during half a century's scholarship in development
economics. The PIDE is doing yeoman's service in development
economics by highlighting the life and works of eminent professionals in
the field, especially those closely associated with it. It is hoped that
it will continue to do this in a systematic way and by ensuring their
presence on the occasion. I have known A. R. Khan longer than perhaps
anyone in the audience, largely because there are very few as old as me
still around. I well remember the day Aziz along with (the late) Swadesh
Bose landed at lunch time in the large open corridor of the top floor of
Old Sindh Assembly building Karachi whose entrance led to a lounge with
a ping pong table where the Institute's staff and its foreign
advisors played Table Tennis at lunch time. The Institute's
reigning champion, John Fei, interrupted his game to welcome the two new
staff members of the Institute who had just arrived from Dhaka.
Aziz was one of the most productive staff economists in the
Institute and produced a paper within six months on the financing of
Pakistan's first Five Year Plan which he presented at a seminar on
Pakistan economy in Islamabad inaugurated by President Ayub Khan. Aziz
represented the PIDE along with John Fei and myself who presented a
joint paper on Planning Methodology in Pakistan. All three of us
travelled together from Lahore to Islamabad by car with Prof. Fei
entertaining both of us with his boundless curiosity and his
American-Chinese accent. Professor Fei was a remarkably perceptive human
being besides being a first-rate economist. In the interest of public
disclosure, I may add that Professor Fei was my mentor and has been a
great help in building my career.
My second significant encounter with Aziz was after I had returned
from Yale on completing my PhD and spending a year in Turkey and later
joined Islamabad University, now Quaid-i-Azam University, while Aziz
returned after completing his PhD from Cambridge and continued to
research at PIDE, Karachi. Aziz and I were both working on the
development planning models and both of us did our PhD dissertations
using optimisation technique. He included one of my articles based on my
thesis in the Readings on Development Planning Techniques edited by him.
He also taught as a visiting faculty, part of my course in development
planning at Islamabad University on the Department's invitation.
1966 to 1970 was Aziz's most productive period at PIDE. The
seminal critique of Pakistan's ISI development strategy (Import
Substituting Industrialisation) was undertaken in a PDR article by John
Power entitled "Pakistan's Industrialisation Strategy--A Case
of Frustrated Take-off'. It was based partly on the empirical
findings of a study done by Aziz which showed that the source of
increased demand for industries promoted was principally an expansion of
domestic consumption far in excess of normal consumption preferences and
income growth. Aziz's work was also influenced by that of another
Ford Foundation Advisor who later became his mentor and colleague at ILO
and at UC, Riverside, Professor Keith Griffin. Griffin's critique
of the Pakistani ISI model had a different focus than that of Power. He
critiqued Pakistan's ISI strategy for deliberately redistributing
income in favour of the treasury and capitalist classes in the hope of
promoting higher rates of saving and investment, a strategy that also
failed. Griffin's Hypothesis lent support to the grievance of East
Pakistanis that resources were being exploited and deployed for the
development of West Pakistan.
A. R. Khan along with other prominent econgmists of East Pakistan
notably Muhammad Anis-ur-Rahman who founded Islamabad University's
Economics Department, Rahman Subhan and Nurul Islam, who were his
admired teachers in Dhaka University actively participated in supporting
the demand for an independent Bangladesh. A significant contribution
based on his research at PIDE Karachi was an investigation in to the
behaviour of real wages in Pakistan which led him to his more abiding
and wider interest in the income distribution and poverty. This latter
interest brought me in touch with Aziz once again when we both worked at
ILO, first in Geneva and later on in Bangkok. Aziz published my revised
study on poverty in Pakistan in the collection of studies on
Landlessness and Poverty in Asia. Later we worked together for a year at
ARTEP in Bangkok after he succeeded Prof. K. N. Raj who had recruited me
left for Kerala to rejoin his Institute (Centre for Development Studies)
in Trivandrum. Aziz succeeded him and after Aziz, Rashid succeeded at
ARTEP.
A. R. Khan's career as a development economist which started
modestly in Karachi took him to various positions of eminence not only
in Bangladesh where he became a member of the Planning Commission but
also in many academic and research institutions and agencies abroad,
including Oxford, LSE, ILO, World Bank and University of California at
Riverside. His contributions of research on income distribution and
poverty in China have rightly earned him the status of a recognised
authority in that field. He has been an outstanding researcher and
prolific author of articles and books on various issues in development
economics. His quantitative and analytical skill have always enriched
his contributions and brought new insights on the subject matter. His
stratospheric rise in his career as a development economist is a matter
of pride for his friends, colleagues, peers and admirers.
S. M. Naseem is former Head, Department of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam
University, Islamabad.
Reflection on A. R. Khan
HAFIZ A. PASHA
Dr Naqvi, Dr Naseem, Dr Rashid Amjad,
My reflections on Aziz ur Rahman's work are not based on any
personal relationship. I did not have the privilege of knowing him
because he is kind of which represents even more senior generations than
somebody like me these days are considered quite senior. I want to focus
on his material contributions and his contributions as a development
economist. His earlier work on Pakistan in the Sixties is really for
students who are interested in the economic history of Pakistan, a very
useful guide, particularly in terms of the experience in the process of
industrialisation which has already been referred to. My own
understanding of Aziz ur Rahman's work is that he was somewhat more
neutral in his stance with respect to this very strong view of
exploitation that had emerged from many of the East Pakistani economists
at that time particularly about the trade mechanism being used for the
purposes of the transfer of resources from one wing to the other wing of
Pakistan. His contribution I feel can be classified broadly speaking now
in terms of two or three critical areas. First, I think Aziz made a
major contribution to the development of the earlier paradigm of basic
needs which was really in some sense an ILO invention and in a sense
also was a pre concept of a broader notion of development which
subsequently became which was the human development view, of course,
also propounded by South Asian economists. More recently I think his
contribution has been broadly speaking in different aspects of what we
now-a-days refer to as inclusive growth. A lot of his recent work, for
example, particularly in China and in Bangladesh and elsewhere in Asia
predominantly has focused on issue of growth and inequality, poverty,
employment and of course, on implications of globalisation on what is
happening to various parts of Asia. So his contributions are really
extremely useful for students of development economics today who have
time to look at the experience of Asian countries, particularly, major
countries like China, Pakistan, Bangladesh and so on. I would suggest
very strongly that there is a Bibliography of Aziz ur Rahman's work
which is available here today and please have a look at it and I am sure
you will find extremely useful articles for your work, particularly on
the economic history of the region. So I as an economist feel that my
dedication is essentially to the contributions to the knowledge base of
development economics that economist of the stature of Aziz ur Rahman
has given to us and we are grateful to him for that. Thank you.
Hafiz A. Pasha <hafiz.pasha@gmail.com> is Dean, Beaconhouse
National University (BNU). Lahore.