Trade liberalisation could improve producers profitability in agriculture: a case of Basmati rice.
Zulfiqar, Muhammad ; Khan, Dilawar ; Chishti, Anwar F. 等
This peace of research has been conducted, as part of PhD research
of the first author, with the objectives to (i) identify various
protection policies and interventions exercised in Basmati rice economy
in Pakistan (ii) estimate welfare effects associated with existing
protection policies and (iii) to estimate implications of WTO's
trade liberalisation in domestic economy and foreign markets. The
quantitative analysis of data reveals that Basmati rice crop hanged
about 'price tax-cum-export tax' regime during the study
period. Welfare analysis of such policy interventions estimated higher
losses to producers (Pak Rs 657.95 million per year) than gains to
consumers (Rs 448.76 million per year) during pre-WTO period. The same
trend continued during post-WTO period but producers' losses were
comparatively smaller i.e., 649.48 million per year. In case of free
trade, simulation results demonstrate greater gains to producers than
losses to consumers. If world market was liberalised, supplementary
gains in the range of Rs 276.65 million to Rs 451.60 million per year
during earlier and Rs 333.45 million to Rs 637.40 million per year
during the later period would have occurred at domestic level. In light
of analytical results, the following recommendations are made. (i)
Government needs to curtail interventions in Basmati rice economy. (ii)
Besides, improving the pace of trade liberalisation at domestic level,
Pakistan should pursue with other members in WTO's negotiations for
early implementation of WTO's trade liberalisation on international
level. (iii) Government of Pakistan should gear up its efforts as
facilitator of trade in accordance with WTO agreements and increase
investment in areas of research, development, and out-reach.
JEL classification: Q17, Q18, Q28
Keywords: Basmati Rice, Government Intervention, Welfare Effect,
Trade Liberalisation, WTO.
1. INTRODUCTION
Rice is one of the most important crops of Pakistan having second
position as staple food after wheat [Akhtar (1999)] while Basmati rice
is an important export commodity [Pakistan (2008)]. Basmati rice is the
third largest crop in terms of occupying area under cultivation
[Zulfiqar (2008)]. Due to the importance of Basmati rice to the economy
of Pakistan, this piece of research has been conducted with the
objectives to; (i) identify various protection policies and
interventions made to Basmati rice economy in Pakistan (ii) estimate
welfare effects associated with existing protection policies and
interventions and (iii) to estimate implications of WTO's trade
liberalisation in domestic economy and abroad.
Production of various crops including Basmati rice has been a
private job. However, marketing and trade of most of the commodities
have mainly been regulated or managed by government in one or the other
way. The major policy intervention of Government of Pakistan has been in
the form of 'support prices', currently abandoned to comply
with World Trade Organisation (WTO) agreements. The announcement of
'support of procurement prices' and size of stocks procured
thereof have affected production and trade of the commodities involved.
Secondly, State Trading Enterprises (STEs) had been playing major role
in trading of some major agricultural commodities including Basmati
rice. Although lately Pakistan has taken certain measures to liberalise
trade but still according to Trading Corporation of Pakistan (2006) it
is, inter alia, involved in inspection of export purpose rice. Thirdly,
import tariffs and export duty has been important interventions.
According to Scott, et al. (1990), imposition of export duties on
Basmati rice has been a common feature. Some clues of such policies in
Basmati rice economy are also found in studies like Cornelisse and
Kuijpers (1987), Ahmad, et al. (1987), Hamid, et al. (1987), Chishti
(1994), Ackerman and Dixit (1999), Ashfaq, Griffith, and Parton (2001)
and Arifullah (2007).
For the instant article, types of interventions that Government of
Pakistan has adopted to regulate its Basmati rice economy from 1985 to
2005, our study period, have been determined through reviewing
Pakistan's Basmati rice domestic wholesale price, export price and
-world trade price. An examination of the data on prices (Table 1)
reflects that Pakistan's domestic wholesale price ([P.sub.d]) has
remained, on average, at US$374.89 (Pak Rs 13777.29) per M. ton while
average world trade price ([P.sub.w]) remained US$332.97 (Rs 12236.59)
per M. ton. However, Pakistan's average export price ([P.sub.e])
was US$514.23 (Rs 18897.74), signifying export tax amounting US$139.34
(Rs 5120.71) per M. ton during the 1985-2005 study period. Basmati is
especial quality rice and its export can not be evaluated on the basis
of world average rice price given in Table 1. Therefore free trade
export price has been estimated using domestic price of Basmati rice and
establish whether Pakistan has supported its Basmati rice in the
domestic market. For this purpose export supply ([E.sub.s]) and export
demand ([E.sub.d]) functions adopted from Zulfiqar (2008) and solved for
Basmati rice free trade export price ([P.sub.ef]). So realised free
trade export price along with Pakistan's domestic Basmati rice
price is reflected in Table 2. A comparison of the two prices ([P.sub.d]
& [P.sub.ef]) indicates Basmati Rice remained under 'price
tax-cum-export tax' regime.
2. METHODOLOGICAL/ANALYTIC FRAMEWORK
The objective set for this research required to engage three
methodologies, namely: (a) analysis of prices using time series data
from 1985 to 2005 and identification of government interventions which
was done through calculating mean values of prices for the study period.
(b) computation of associated welfare effects in terms of changes in
producer and consumer surpluses (APS & ACS) using following
approach.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
or
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and (c) analysing implications of implementation of WTO's
Agreements particularly agreement on Agriculture from the difference of
domestic and world prices. As WTO in general aims at introducing and
implementing free trade. For estimating welfare effects of existing
policy regimes, we compared those with free trade situation. In case no
government interventions were existed, free trade price [P.sub.df] would
have prevailed instead of existing domestic price [P.sub.d]. Hence, the
effects of implementation of free trade at domestic level have been
estimated using free trade scenario. However, at international level,
these estimates have been developed using an increase in the prices at
international market, based on empirical results of a number of studies
such as FAO (2005), Anderson, Martin, and Mensbrugghe (2006) and Akhtar
(1999). The functional detail of these methodologies are given in their
respective sections in succeeding sections.
Identification of Government Interventions
To achieve our objectives, the study period (1985-2005) was divided
into two subperiods: pre-WTO (1985-1995) and post-WTO (1995-2005). The
mean values of prices for the two sub-periods were computed, as follows,
using Tables 1 and 2.
Average [P.sub.d] lingered at US$368.18 per M. ton against average
[P.sub.e] at US$551.94 and average [P.sub.ef] at US$398.63 during the
pre-WTO period, reflecting 'price tax-cum-export tax' regime
(Figure 1). Post-WTO study period witnessed average [P.sub.d]
(US$381.61), [P.sub.e] (US$476.52) and [P.sub.ef] (US$387.79), again
reflecting 'price tax-cum-export tax' regime (Figure 2).
Computation of Welfare Effects
Welfare effects of (pre- and post-WTO) scenarios, were estimated
using simple welfare analysis. To conduct welfare analysis, producer and
consumer surpluses ([DELTA]PS and [DELTA]CS) were determined along with
computed export tax (ET) based on demand, supply and price linkage
equations. To estimate producer and consumer surplus and to estimate
these equations, time series data from 1985 to 2005 was used.
Pre-WTO Situation: The welfare effects of 'price
tax-cum-export tax' regime of pre-WTO period are represented in
Figure 1, as follows.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The associated welfare effects were captured using the following
model.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
ET = (ghij) = ([P.sub.e] - [P.sub.d])
[E.sub.s] (export supplies) ... ... ... ... (3)
NWG/C (net welfare gain or cost) =
[DELTA]PS + [DELTA]CS + ET ... ... (4)
The model adopted following Basmati rice supply and demand
functions from Zulfiqar (2008).
[S.sub.d] = 676.9517 + 0.052582
[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (5)
[D.sub.d] = 840.7971 - 0.008451
[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (6)
[E.sub.s] = -163.845 + 0.061033
[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (7)
[E.sub.d] = 468.7365 - 0.23247
[P.sub.e] ... ... ... ... ... (8)
= 1.360216 + 1.1063
[P.sub.w] ... ... ... ... (9)
For arriving at free market price ([P.sub.ef]), export supply
([E.sub.s]) and export demand ([E.sub.d]) were equalised, as follows.
[E.sub.s] =
[E.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... ... .... .... (10a)
Since [P.sub.d]/EXR = [P.sub.e] or [P.sub.d] = [P.sup.*.sub.e] EXR,
replacing [P.sub.d] in above equation we obtained:
[P.sub.ef] = US$398.63 per M.
ton ... ... ... ... ... (10b)
Putting values of [P.sub.ef] = 398.63 given in (10b) in [E.sub.d]
in Equation (8)
[E.sub.df] = 468.7365 - 0.23247
([P.sub.e] = 398.63) ... ... ... ... ... (11a)
[E.sub.df] = 575.85 M. tons ... ... ... ... ... (11b)
Equating [E.sub.df] = [E.sub.st] ... ... ... ... ... (12a)
[P.sub.df] = Pak Rs 8846.24
per M. ton ... ... ... ... ... (12b)
After computing [P.sub.ef] and [P.sub.df] in Equations (10b) and
(12b), the pre- WTO scenario's welfare effects specified in model
(1) to (4) were estimated, as follows.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] ... ... ... (13a)
= - Rs 657953 thousand
= - Rs 657.95 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (13b)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] ... ... (14a)
= Rs 448759.20 thousand
= Rs 448.76 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (14b)
ET = (ghij) = ([P.sub.e] -
[P.sub.d])[E.sub.s] ... ... ... ... ... ... (15a)
= US$ 62555.42
= Rs 1403792 thousand
= Rs 1403.79 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (15b)
NWG/C = [DELTA]PS +
[DELTA]CS + ET ... ... ... ... ... ... (16a)
= Rs 1194598.00 thousand
= Rs 1194.60 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (16b)
Post-WTO Situation: Figure 2 given below best reflects the
interventions made in Basmati rice economy during second part of the
study period.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The following supply and demand functions adopted from Zulfiqar
(2008) was used for the post-WTO period (1995-2005).
[S.sub.d] = 898.4736 + 0.052582
[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (17)
[D.sub.d] = 1437.392 - 0.008451
[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (18)
[E.sub.s] = -538.919 + 0.061033
[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (19)
[E.sub.d] = 749.3228 - 0.23247
[P.sub.e] ... ... ... ... ... (20)
= 298.5887 + 1.1063
[P.sub.w] ... ... ... ... ... (21)
For estimation of free market price ([P.sub.ef])
[E.sub.s] =
[E.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (22a)
Since [P.sub.d]/EXR = [P.sub.e] or [P.sub.d] = [P.sub.e.sup.*] EXR,
replacing [P.sub.d] in above equation we get:
[P.sub.ef] = US$387.79
per M. ton ... ... ... ... ... (22b)
Putting values of [P.sub.ef] = 387.79 given in (22b) in [E.sub.d]
(20)
[E.sub.df] = 749.3228 - 0.23247
([P.sub.ej] = 387.79) ... ... ... ... (23a)
[E.sub.df] = 659.17 M.
tons ... ... ... ... ... ... (23b)
Equating [E.sub.df] =
[E.sub.sf] ... ... ... ... ... ... (24a)
[P.sub.df] = Rs 19630.23
per M. ton ... ... ... ... ... (24b)
For estimation of NSWG/C specified in model (1) to (4), we estimate
various components of NWG/C, as follows.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (25a)
= - Rs 649480.00 thousand
= - Rs 649.48 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (25b)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (26a)
= Rs 430193.50 thousand
= Rs 430.19 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (26b)
ET = (ghij) = ([P.sub.e] -
[P.sub.d])[E.sub.s] ... ... ... ... ... ... (27a)
= US$60604.84
= Rs 3063899.00 thousand
= Rs 3063.90 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (27b)
NWG/C = [DELTA]PS +
[DELTA]CS + T ... ... ... ... ... ... (28a)
= Rs 2844612 thousand
= Rs 2844.61 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (28b)
Implications of WTO's Trade Liberalisation in Domestic
Economy: WTO's Agreements particularly agreement on Agriculture
aims at steadily reducing 'domestic support', 'import
tariffs' and 'export subsidies' and eliminate/abolish all
such protection/support policies over a specified period (www.wto.org).
This means that WTO in general aims at introducing and implementing free
trade. So, if no government interventions were existed, free trade price
[P.sub.df] = Rs 8846.24 would have prevailed instead of existing
domestic price [P.sub.d] = Rs 8262.30 per metric ton during the pre- WTO
period (Figure 1). The effects of implementation of free trade would
have been as follows.
[DELTA]PS = Rs 657.95 million ... ... ... ... ... (29)
[DELTA]CS = - Rs 448.76 million ... ... ... ... ... (30)
ET (export tax) = - Rs 1403.79
million ... ... ... ... ... (31)
NWG/C= - Rs 1194.60 million ... ... ... ... ... (32)
Similarly, welfare effects of free-trade scenario for post-WTO
period would have been, as follows.
[DELTA]PS = Rs 649.48 million ... ... ... ... ... (33)
[DELTA]CS = - Rs 430.19 million ... ... ... ... ... (34)
ET = - Rs 3063.90 million ... ... ... ... ... (35)
NSWG/C = -Rs 2844.61 million ... ... ... ... ... (36)
Implementation of WTO Trade Liberalisation in International
Markets: Certain empirical studies have suggested that implementation of
Agreement on Agriculture and other WTO agreements would raise world
prices. FAO (2005) and Akhtar (1999) have found that impacts of trade
liberalisation on world commodity prices would be positive. Another
study by Anderson, Martin and Mensbrugghe (2006) found that a move to
free trade would increase farm employment, the real value of
agricultural output and exports, real returns to farm land and unskilled
labour, and real net farm incomes in developing countries. In want of
exact estimates, an assumption a 5 percent rise in world prices
([P.sub.w]) was made and examined its effects on Pakistan's
domestic economy.
Pre-WTO Scenario
Using Equation (9) and putting 5 percent-enhanced value
of [P.sub.w], that is, 1.05 [P.sub.w].
[E.sub.d] = 1.360216 + 1.1063
([P.sub.w]= 355.6407) ... ... ... ... (37a)
= 394.805 thousand M. tons ... ... ... ... ... (37b)
Equating [E.sub.d] = 394.805 with [E.sub.s] given in (7) and
solving for [P.sub.d]
[E.sub.d] = [E.sub.s] ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (38a)
394.81 = -163.845 + 0.061033[P.sub.d]
Pa = 9153.253 Rs per M. ton ... ... ... ... ... (38b)
Substituting [P.sub.d] = 9153.253 in (5 and
6) and solving for Sa and [D.sub.d]
[S.sub.d] = 676.9517 + 0.052582[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (39a)
= 1158.25 thousand M. tons ... ... ... ... ... (39b)
[D.sub.d] = 840.7971 - 0.008451[P.sub.d] ... ... ... ... ... (40a)
= 763.44 thousand M. tons ... ... ... ... ... (40b)
Welfare Effects
Welfare effects of the changes in Pakistan's Basmati rice
domestic price from the existing level of [P.sub.d0] = Rs 8262.30 due to
new level of [P.sub.df]= Rs 9153.252 are measured in terms of changes in
producers and consumers surpluses ([DELTA]PS and [DELTA]CS), using the
following model.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (41a)
= Rs 1011.08 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (41b)
[DELTA]CS=- [[integral].sup.Pdf =9153.253.sub.Pdo=8262.30]
(840.7971 - 0.008451) dp ... ... ... (42a)
= - Rs 683.55 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (42b)
NWG/C = APS + APS ... ... ... ... ... ... (43a)
= 1011.08 - 683.55
= Rs 327.53 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (43b)
Post-WTO Scenario: In the foregoing fashion, 5 percent-enhanced
world price [P.sub.w] would cause domestic price to rise from the
existing level of [P.sub.d0] = Rs 19292.28 to new level of [P.sub.DF] =
Rs 19950.35 and the associated welfare effects would be measured as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (44a)
= [[integral].sup.Pdf = 19950.35.sub. Pdo=19292.28]
((898.4736 + O.052582Pd)dp
= Rs.1270.216 million ... ... ... (44b)
[DELTA]CS=[[integral].sub.Pdf=19950.35.sub.Pdo=19292.28]
(1437.392- 0.00845 IPd) dp ... ... ... (45a)
= - Rs 836.7886 million ... ... ... ... ... ... (45b)
NWG/C = [DELTA]PS + [DELTA]PS ... ... ... ... ... ... (46a)
= 1270.216 - 736.7886
= Rs 433.4274 million ... ... ... ... (46b)
3. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
The domestic Basmati rice price (US$368.18 per M.ton) was kept
lower than the Pakistan average export price (US$551.94 per M.ton). Thus
producers suffered losses in their producer surpluses by Rs 657.95
million per year. The government collected Rs 1403.79 million per year
as export tax during pre-WTO period. Although, consumers benefited by Rs
448.76 million per year in their consumer surpluses but losses to
producers were greater than benefits to consumers. However, due to
export tax earnings, overall benefit of Rs 1194.60 million per year was
estimated for the society. There has been an increase in domestic prices
during post-WTO period (1995- 2005) to (US$381.61 per M.ton). But
average export prices were (US$476.52 per M.ton), that again resulted in
losses to producers of Rs 649.48 million per year. The consumers'
surplus stood at Rs 430.19 million per year while export tax collected
was Rs 3063.90 million. Losses in Producers' surplus were larger
than benefit to consumers' surplus but net welfare benefit was Rs
2844.61 million per year mainly due to export tax.
The interventions in Basmati rice economy resulted in net welfare
gain in both, pre- and post-WTO periods due to export tax collection.
Such a scenario obscured real welfare of producers and consumers. As
export tax would minimise/abolish in free trade situation and producers
and consumers' surpluses would remain for a comparative evaluation
of welfare effects. Therefore, from trade liberalisation perspective,
the study reveals that losses to producers surplus had been greater than
benefits in consumers' surplus due to government interventions and
it trade liberalisation was introduced in the domestic economy, it would
have incurred greater gains to Basmati rice producers than losses to
consumers. The results show similar trend for international market i.e.
trade liberalisation in world Basmati rice markets would have been
benefited Pakistan's economy by Rs 327.53 million and Rs 433.43
million per annum during pre- and post- WTO periods respectively.
4. CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS
The foregoing results and discussions are concluded and
recommendations thereof are as under.
(1) It seems that government policy interventions in price regime
have lowered during post-WTO period as compared to pre-WTO period. This
is evident from relatively narrowing gaps between Pakistan's
domestic price and export price of former period than that of pre-WTO
period. The positive trend of narrowing gap between domestic and export
(international) prices needs to be continued till international prices
prevail at domestic level that will improve the profitability of
producers.
(2) The estimated welfare effects in terms of producers and
consumers' surpluses revealed heavier losses than gains during both
the periods but relatively lesser losses during post-WTO period. Trade
liberalisation simulations for domestic economy revealed larger
producers' gains relative to losses to consumers if trade was
liberalised. Thus, Pakistan should continue implementing trade
liberalisation in line with WTO regime.
(3) Trade liberalisation simulations for world market also
reflected higher gains to the domestic economy of Pakistan. Therefore
efforts should be geared up for trade liberalisation on global basis.
(4) Instead of coddling in State Trading Enterprises (STEs), the
government should act as facilitator of trade as envisaged in the
'Green Box' of Agreement on Agriculture and other WTO
agreements. It should concentrate on research, development and out-reach
related investments for improvement in productivity and quality of
Basmati rice.
Annex Table 1
Pakistan's Bastnati Rice Prices for 1985-05
(Prices per Million Ton)
Year Pakistan's Domestic
Wholesale Price
World Price Pakistan's Export
Pak Rs US$ (US$) Price (US$)
1985-86 6300.75 390.40 268.23 655.87
1986-87 6625.75 385.68 280.56 697.68
1987-88 6843.75 388.86 347.59 713.10
1988-89 6625.25 344.79 351.99 677.51
1989-90 7326.00 341.61 356.24 671.57
1990-91 8314.50 370.81 368.93 466.23
1991-92 9338.25 375.87 358.03 407.07
1992-93 10323.00 397.65 332.35 424.34
1993-94 10650.50 353.09 374.17 405.56
1994-95 10275.25 333.05 348.97 400.45
1995-96 14316.75 426.49 403.33 406.71
1996-97 14729.25 377.74 390.74 440.67
1997-98 17683.25 409.37 351.67 452.41
1998-99 20570.75 439.64 329.25 508.14
1999-00 15902.00 307.16 295.98 501.71
2000-01 18140.25 310.42 268.52 463.95
2001-02 21000.50 341.88 252.40 461.93
2002-03 23327.75 398.77 276.89 494.78
2003-04 22636.25 393.16 325.24 508.54
2004-05 24616.00 411.43 378.35 526.34
Average 13777.29 374.89 332.97 514.23
Source: FAO (www.fao.org; Statistical databases).
Agricultural Statistic of Pakistan (Various Issues).
Annex Table 2
Pakistan's Bastnati Rice Domestic and Estimated Free Trade Prices
for 1985-05 (Prices per Million Ton)
Year Pakistan's Domestic Basmati Rice Estimated Free
Wholesale Price (US$) Export Trade Price (US$)
1985-86 390.40 441.09
1986-87 385.68 442.30
1987-88 388.86 446.55
1988-89 344.79 399.83
1989-90 341.61 391.38
1990-91 370.81 384.66
1991-92 375.87 380.02
1992-93 397.65 401.07
1993-94 353.09 358.97
1994-95 333.05 340.46
1995-96 426.49 424.48
1996-97 377.74 383.34
1997-98 409.37 412.86
1998-99 439.64 444.79
1999-00 307.16 320.49
2000-01 310.42 319.81
2001-02 341.88 348.89
2002-03 398.77 404.64
2003-04 393.16 400.32
2004-05 411.43 418.31
Average 374.89 393.21
Source: Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan (Various Issues).
REFERENCES
Ackerman, K. Z. and P. M. Dixit (1999) An Introduction to State
Trading in Agriculture. Market and Trade Economics Division, Economic
Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture. (Agricultural Economic
Report No. 783).
Ackerman, K. Z. and P. M. Dixit (1999) An Introduction to State
Trading in Agriculture. Market and Trade Economics Division, Economic
Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture. (Agricultural Economic
Report No. 783).
Ahmad, B. and A. M. Chaudary (1987) Profitability of
Pakistan's Agriculture. In B.A. Azhar (ed.) (1996) Pakistan
Agricultural Economics--A Book of Readings. Islamabad: National Book
Foundation.
Ahmad, B. and A. M. Chaudhry (1987) Profitability of
Pakistan's Agriculture. In B. A. Azhar (ed.) (1996) Pakistan
Agricultural Economics--A Book of Readings. Islamabad: National Book
Foundation.
Akhtar, M. R. (1999) Effects of Trade Liberalisation on Agriculture
in Pakistan: Commodity Aspects. The Regional Coordination Centre for
Research and Development of Coarse Grains, Pulses, Roots and Tuber Crops
in the Humid Tropics of Asia and the Pacific (CGPRT Centre), Bogor
Indonesia. (Working Paper 44).
Anderson, K., W. Martin, and D. V. D. Mensbrugghe (2006) Incidence
of Trade and Subsidies Policies on Developing Countries Welfare, Export
and Debt Sustainability. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
Arifullah, S. (2007) Pakistan's Crop Sector: Ah Economic
Analysis. PhD Thesis, Department of Agricultural Economics, NWFP
Agricultural University Peshawar, Pakistan.
Ashfaq, M., G. Griffith, and K. Parton (2001) Welfare Effects of
Government Interventions in the Wheat Economy of Pakistan. Agricultural
Prices Commission Pakistan Journal of Agricultural Economics 4:1, 25-33.
Chishti, A. F. (1994) An Evaluation of Pakistan's Rice Trade
Policy: A Case Study of Basmati Rice. PhD Thesis, University of Illinois
at Urbana-Champaign, USA.
Cornelisse, P. and B. Kuijpers (1987) A Policy Model of the Wheat
and Rice Economy of Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 25:4,
365-399.
FAO (2005) The State of Food and Agriculture: Agricultural Trade
and Poverty. Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations,
Rome. (FAO Agriculture Series No. 36).
Hamid, et al. (1987) The Wheat Economy of Pakistan: Setting and
Prospects. USAID/International Food Policy Research Institute,
Washington, DC. (Mimeographed).
Hamid, et al. (1987) The Wheat Economy of Pakistan: Setting and
Prospects (Mimgiraphed). USAID/International Food Policy Research
Institute, Washington, DC.
Pakistan, Government of (2008) Economic Survey of Pakistan.
Islamabad: Ministry of Finance, Economic Adviser's Wing, Finance
Division.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Agricultural Statistics of
Pakistan. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Livestock.
Scott, W. E., A. K. Siddiqi, S, A. William, and M. I. Muhammad
(1990) Export Restrictions--A Study of Restrictions on Agricultural
Exports in Pakistan. Ministry
of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, and United States Agency for
International Development. Islamabad. (Special Report No. 17).
Trading Corporation of Pakistan (2006) 38th Annual Report 2004-05.
Available at: www.pakistan.gov.pk.
Zulfiqar, M. (2008) WTO's Trade Liberalisation: Implications
for Pakistan's Crop Sector. PhD Thesis submitted to Department of
Agricultural Economics, NWFP Agricultural University Peshawar.
Muhammad Zulfiqar <zulfi64@yahoo.com> is Director Planning,
Kohat University of Science and Technology, Kohat. Dilawar Khan
<dilawarmkd@yahoo.com> is Assistant Professor, Kohat University of
Science and Technology, Kohat. Anwar F. Chishti <chishti
anwar@yahoo.com> is Incharge Graduate Programme, Muhammad Ali Jinnah
University, Islamabad. Munir Khan <munirkhan4@hotmail.com> is
Professor, NWFP Agricultural University, Peshawar. Wasiullah
<wasiullahmalik_63@yahoo.com> is Project Director, Kohat
University of Science and Technology, Kohat. Ajmal Waheed
<awkhan2@yahoo.com> is Assistant Professor, Quaid-i-Azam
University, Islamabad. Muhammad Zakir <mzakirs@yahoo.com> is
Director QEC, Kohat University of Science and Technology, Kohat. Robina
Karim <robikarim@yahoo.com> is PhD Fellow, NWFP Agricultural
University, Peshawar.
Table 1
Pre-WTO Period Post-WTO Period
(1985-1995) (1995-2005)
Pakistan's US$368.18 (Rs 8262.30) US$381.61(Rs 19292.28)
Wholesale Price
([P.sub.d])
Estimated Free US$398.63 (Rs 8945.57) US$387.79 (Rs 19604.86)
Trade Price
([P.sub.e])
Pakistan's Trade US$551.94 (Rs 12385.92) US$476.52 (Rs 24090.51)
Price ([P.sub.d])