首页    期刊浏览 2024年10月06日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:A small open economy DSGE model for Pakistan.
  • 作者:Haider, Adnan ; Khan, Safdar Ullah
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2008
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:Keywords: New-Keynesian Economics, Open Economy DSGE Models, Nominal Rigidities, Monetary Policy, Transmission Mechanism, Bayesian Approach
  • 关键词:Inflation (Economics);Inflation (Finance);Interest rates;Investment analysis;Monetary policy;Open economy;Securities analysis

A small open economy DSGE model for Pakistan.


Haider, Adnan ; Khan, Safdar Ullah


This paper estimates a small open economy Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model for Pakistan using Bayesian simulation approach. Model setup is based on new Keynesian framework, characterised by nominal rigidity in prices with habit formation in household's consumption. The core objective is to study whether an estimated small open economy DSGE model provides a realistic behavior about the structure Pakistan economy with fully articulated description of the monetary policy transmission mechanism vis-a-vis domestic firm's price setting behavior. To do so, we analyse the impulse responses of key macro variables; domestic inflation, imported inflation, output, consumption, interest rate, exchange rate, term of trade to different structural/exogenous shocks. From several interesting results, few are; (a) high inflation in Pakistan do not hit domestic consumption significantly; (b) Central bank of Pakistan responds to high inflation by increasing the policy rate by 100 to 200 bps; (c) exchange rate appreciates in both the cases of high domestic and imported inflation; (d) tight monetary policy stance helps to curb domestic inflation as well as imported inflation but appreciates exchange rate significantly (f) pass through of exchange rate to domestic inflation is very low; finally parameter value of domestic price stickiness shows that around 24 percent domestic firms do not re-optimise their prices which implies averaged price contract is about two quarters.

JEL classifications: E32, E47, E52, F37, F47

Keywords: New-Keynesian Economics, Open Economy DSGE Models, Nominal Rigidities, Monetary Policy, Transmission Mechanism, Bayesian Approach

The complex nature of DSGE models may have also limited their acceptance among policy makers, as notation can get very messy, thus creating a natural barrier for the communication of the results to policy makers, not to mention to the public. Furthermore, understanding the working of these models requires well trained macroeconomists with a modeling culture and strong statistical and computer programming skills. This also implies that central banks may need to invest additional resources to develop such models, something that might not always be considered as priority or simply resources might be scarce.

Camilo E. Tovar (2008)

1. INTRODUCTION

In recent years there has been a growing interest in academics, international policy institutions and central banks (1) in developing small-to-medium, even large-scale, open economy macroeconomic models called Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models based on new-Keynesian framework. (2) The term DSGE was originally used by Kydland and Prescott (1982) in their seminal contribution on Real Business Cycle (RBC) model. The RBC model is based on neoclassical framework with micro-founded optimisation behaviour of economic agents with flexible prices. One of the critical assumptions of this model is that fluctuations of real quantities are caused by real shock only; that is, only stochastic technology or government spending shocks play their role. Later research in DSGE models however included Keynesian short-run macroeconomic features (called nominal rigidities), such as Calvo (1983) type staggered pricing behaviour and Taylor (1980) type wage contracts. Hence this new DSGE modeling framework labeled as new-neoclassical synthesis or new-Keynesian modeling paradigm. (3)

This new approach combines micro-foundations of both households and firms optimisation problems and with a large collection of both nominal and real (price/wage) rigidities that provide plausible short-run dynamic macroeconomic fluctuations with a fully articulated description of the monetary policy transmission mechanism; see, for instance, Christiano, et al. (2005) and Smets and Wouters (2003). The key advantage of modern DSGE models, over traditional reduce form macroeconomic models, is that the structural interpretation of their parameters allows to overcome the famous Lucas critique (1976). (4) Traditional models contained equations linking variables of interest of explanatory factors such as economic policy variables. One of the uses of these models was therefore to examine how a change in economic policy affected these variables of interest, other things being equal.

In using DSGE models for practical purposes and to recommend how central banks and policy institutions should react to the short-run fluctuations, it is necessary to first examine the possible sources, (5) as well as to evaluate the degree of nominal and real rigidities present in the economy. In advanced economies, like US and EURO area, it is easy to determine the degree of nominal and real rigidities as these economies are fully documented. In developing economies like Pakistan, where most of economic activities are un-documented (also labeled as informal economy, black economy, or underground economy), it is very difficult to determine the exact degree of nominal and real rigidities present in the economy. However, one can approximate results using own judgments and through well defined survey based methods. (6)

Broadly, this paper carries two dimensional motivation agenda. First, in emerging market economies with complex structures, one of the enduring research questions is to construct and estimate a valid micro-founded economic model featured with nominal rigidities. This issue is really focusable as such economic model which comprehensively explores the transmission mechanism of economic behaviours in the developing economies is scarcely available. Problems in these dimensions are sometimes quite natural for example due to unavailability of high frequency data or because of a major share of the undocumented economy in the observed economic data. This study comes forward to meet this challenge partially (through formal economy channel) by utilising and constructing (7) the high frequency available data (quarterly basis) in the DSGE micro-founded model for Pakistan economy.

Second, the best of our knowledge, there is no study available that has evaluated and analysed Pakistan economy on the lines of micro-founded new-Keynesian models. Among the available literature on economic modeling for Pakistan economy, nonetheless, one may see four major publications with reference to large macroeconometric modeling: (i) Naqvi, et al. (1983) and its revised version Naqvi and Ahmed (1986); (ii) Chishti, et al. (1992); (iii) Haque, et al. (1994); and (iv) Pasha, et al. (1995). In addition to this three studies on Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling: (i) McCathy and Taylor (1980); (ii) Siddiqui and Iqbal (2001); and (iii) Siddiqui and Kemal (2006). The studies explore general equilibrium policy and welfare tradeoffs especially on fiscal side of the Pakistan economy. Furthermore, they remain insufficient in answering several policy oriented questions. Among the many other questions these models absolutely fail to take care of Lucas critique. This study therefore also endeavors to fill this gap in the Pakistan economic literature.

This study uses a simplified version of small open economy DSGE model consistent with Kolasa (2008), Liu (2006), Gali and Monacelli (2005) and Lubik and Schorfheide (2005). The overall model specification is restricted with few sources of nominal rigidities, a linear production function in labour, and a simple role for the central bank with its two main objectives of price stability and economic growth. Furthermore, foreign sector economy is considered as completely exogenous with its two key variables, output (to capture foreign productivity shock) and real interest rate (foreign monetary policy shock). Using historical data on quarterly basis by applying Bayesian estimation approach vis-a-vis combining with the prior information available in existing literature on Pakistan, this model provide several interesting results, (8) which are discussed in later sections of this paper.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows: section two lay out the structure of the model; section three discusses the estimation methodology; section four carries out empirical results; section five concludes and review literature and model canonical representation are provided in appendix.

2. STRUCTURE OF THE MODEL

In this section, we derive a small-scale open-economy DSGE model for Pakistan. Following mainly Kolasa (2008), Liu (2006), Gali and Monacelli (2005) and Lubik and Schorfheide (2005), the models structure begins with the world-economy as inhabited by a continuum of infinite-lived households, (indexed by i [member of] [0, 1]) who take decisions on consumption and savings, and set wages in a staggered fashion. (9) There is a set of firms that produce differentiated varieties of tradable intermediate goods. They have monopoly power over the varieties they produce and set prices in a staggered way. Another group of firms are importers that distribute domestically different varieties of foreign intermediate goods. These firms have monopoly power over the varieties they distribute, and also set prices in a Calvo-type staggered fashion. Finally, we assume symmetric preferences and technologies and allowing potentially rich exchange rate dynamics under the assumption of complete international asset markets.

2.1. Domestic Households Preferences

The domestic economy is inhabited by a representative household who derives its utility from consumption [C.sub.t], and leisure 1 - [L.sub.t]. Its preferences are described by an intertemporal utility function (10):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)

Where,

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

Where [[beta].sub.t] [member of] (0,1) is the intertemporal discount factor which describe rate of time preferences, [sigma] is the inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption and [phi] is the inverse of wage elasticity of labour supply. We introduce external habit formation for the optimisation household as [H.sub.t] = h[C.sub.t-1] with degree of intensity (11) indexed by h, where [C.sub.t-1] is the aggregate part of consumption index. As usual, it is assumed that, [sigma] > 0 and [phi] > 1.

The variable [C.sub.t] is defined as the composite consumption index of foreign and domestically produced goods:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)

Where [eta] > 0 is the elasticity of intratemporal substitution between a bundle of home goods [C.sub.H,t] and a bundle of foreign goods [C.sub.F,t], while [alpha] [member of] (0, 1) is the trade share also measures the degree of openness. The aggregate consumption indices [C.sub.H,t] and [C.sub.F,t] are defined respectively as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)

Where [C.sub.H,t](i) and [C.sub.F,t](i) are respectively the domestic households consumption levels of home ith good, with i [member of] [0, n] and foreign ith good, with i [member of] [n, 1]. It is also assumed that parameter, [epsilon] > 0 is the elasticity of intratemporal substitution among goods produced to be same in two countries.

Under the supposition of CES, continuous time aggregator from Equation (3) further yields respective demand functions for [C.sub.H,t] and [C.sub.F,t]. These demand functions obtained after optimal allocation for good i over continuous time scale. The demand functions are:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)

Where [P.sub.H,T](i) and [P.sub.F,T](i) are prices of domestic and foreign good i respectively. Under the assumption of symmetry across i household allocate aggregate expenditure based on the following demand functions:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)

Where [P.sub.H,t] and [P.sub.F,t] are domestic and foreign prices indices and [P.sub.t] [equivalent to] [[(1 - [alpha][P.sup.1-[eta].sub.H,t] + [alpha][P.sup.1-[eta].sub.F,t].sup.1/1-[eta]] is the consumer price index (CPI). The household does want to maximise its utility level subject to the following budget constraints at time t:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)

Where [Q.sub.t,t+1] is defined as a stochastic discount factor for assessing consumption streams (12) (or asset price kernel) with the property that the price in period t of any bond portfolio with random values [D.sub.t] (denotes nominal payoffs from a portfolio of assets at time t - 1) in the following period is given by: [B.sub.t] = [E.sub.t][[Q.sub.t,t+1] [D.sub.t+1]] (13) [W.sub.t] is the nominal wage for labour services provided to firms. Since total consumption expenditure for the domestic household is given by [P.sub.H,T][C.sub.H,t] + [P.sub.F,T][C.sub.F,t] = [P.sub.t][C.sub.t]. Hence in the aggregate, household faces the budget constraint as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)

Consider [[XI].sub.t] is the marginal utility of income and labour-leisure choice (14) is followed by the intratemporal optimality condition: [[XI].sub.tt] = [P.sub.t]/[W.sub.t], Therefore, intertemporal consumption choice is obtained after maximising the life time utility function subject to budget constraint (7). So optimisation problem yields the following FOCs are:

[C.sub.t] - h[C.sub.t-1]) - [sigma] [W.sub.t]/[P.sub.t] = [L.sup.[phi].sub.t] (8)

By equating marginal rates of substitution to relative prices, yields the optimal portfolio choice as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)

The Equation (9) can also be translated into [[DELTA].sub.t] form as:

[Q.sub.t, t+1] = [beta][E.sub.t]{([P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t+1])([[XI].sub.tt+1]/[[XI].sub.tt])} (10)

Since monetary authority's main instrument is assumed to be short term nominal interest rates as: [R.sub.t] = [E.sub.t][1/[Q.sub.t,t+1]), so Equation (10)can also be represented as:

[beta][R.sub.t][E.sub.t] {([P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t+1])([[XI].sub.tt+1]/[[XI].sub.tt])} = 1 (11)

Further, Equations (5), (8) and (9) can also be expressed in simple log-linearisation form as:

[c.sub.H,t] = -(1 - [alpha])[[eta]([p.sub.H,t] - [p.sub.t]) + [c.sub.t]] and [c.sub.F,t] = -[alpha][[eta]([p.sub.F,t] - [p.sub.t]) + [c.sub.t]] (12)

[w.sub.t] - [p.sub.t] = [phi][l.sub.t] + [sigma]/1 - h [c.sub.t] (13)

[E.sub.t][c.sub.t+1] -(1 - h/[sigma])([r.sub.t] - [E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1]) = [c.sub.t] (14)

Where, is [[pi].sub.t+1] = [p.sub.t+1] - [p.sub.t] is CPI inflation and [c.sub.t] = 1/1 - h([c.sub.t] - h[c.sub.t-1]) is simple log-form of consumption variable.

2.2. Domestic Producers and Firms

The domestic economy is also inhabited by domestic producers, own identical monopolistically competitive firms, producing differentiated goods. There is also a continuum of firms, indexed by j [member of] (0, 1) where each firm maximises its profits, subject to an isolated demand curve (5) and use only a homogenous type of labour for production.

Consider domestic firms operate the same CRS-technology (i.e., firms have access to a linear production technology) that uses labour as its only input:

[Y.sub.H,t] = [A.sub.t][L.sub.t](j) (15

Where, [A.sub.t] is the country specific labor productivity shock. We define aggregate output as:

[Y.sub.t] = [[[[integral].sup.1.sub.0][Y.sub.t][(j).sup.-(1-[rho])dj].sup.1/-(1-[rho])] (16)

The log-linear aggregate production function can be written as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (17)

Let, ln([A.sub.t]) = [a.sub.t], then (14) can be represented as:

[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.t] + [l.sub.t] (18)

If [TC.sub.t] represents the real total cost, then:

[TC.sub.t] = [W.sub.t]/[P.sub.H,t] [Y.sub.t]/[A.sub.t] (19)

By differentiating w.r.t. [Y.sub.t] (19) gives real marginal cost as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)

This implies that real marginal cost is positively related with real wages and negatively with labor factor productivity.

2.2.1. Calvo-Type Price Setting Behaviour

For our model, Calvo (1983) type staggered-price setting is assumed. This means that domestic differentiating goods are defined subject to Calvo-type price-setting. Consider, at each period, only 1 - [[theta].sub.t] fraction of randomly selected domestic firms set prices optimally, while [[theta].sub.t] [member of] [0,1] firms keep their prices unchanged. (15) As a result the average duration of a price is given by 1/1 - [[theta].sub.t]. This implies that 0t firms are assumed to reset their prices, [P.sup.l.sub.t](j) by indexing it to last period inflation. Therefore, [[theta].sub.t] becomes a natural index of price stickiness. The index of domestic prices (16) is defined as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)

Where [P.sub.H,t](J) = [P.sub.H,t](k) for all continuum of firms j, k. Let each home firm j sets a new price [P.sup.*.sub.H,t](J) in order to maximise the present market value of its stream of expected future profits. Therefore domestic price level can be defined as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (22)

In aggregate, firms re-optimise their prices and maximise their profits after setting the new price [P.sup.*.sub.H,t](j) at time t as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (23)

With respect to [P.sup.*.sub.H,t](j) Subject to the following demand function:

[Y.sub.H,t+k] [less than or equal to] ([C.sub.H,t+k] + [C.sup.*.sub.H,t+k])[[[P.sup.*.sub.H,t]/[P.sub.H,t+k]].sup.- [epsilon]]

Where [NMC.sub.H,t+k] is the nominal marginal cost and demand of firm's product drives both from domestic consumption, [C.sub.H,t] as well as foreign consumption, [C.sub.F,t]. The first order condition with (23) takes the form:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (24)

Where [epsilon]/[epsilon] - 1 is considered as desired or frictionless markup. (17) The above condition (24) is linearised around zero-inflation steady-state. So optimal condition (24) can be rewrite after dividing by [P.sub.H,t-1] as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (25)

Letting, [[pi].sub.H,t+k] = [P.sub.H,t+k]/[P.sub.H,t-1] and [MCH.sub.H,t+k] = [NMC.sub.H,t+k]/[P.sub.H,t+k] which is a real marginal cost in period t + k. Hence, Equation (25) can be written as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (26)

From (8) we can incorporate the value of [Q.sub.t,t+k] = [[beta].sup.k] [E.sub.t]{([P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t+k])([C.sub.t+k]/[C.sub.t]).sup.-[sigma]]} in Equation (26) as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (27)

Since [P.sub.t]/[C.sup.-[sigma].sub.t] is independent of summation and its values are known at time t, so (27) yields:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (28)

In the zero inflation steady-state, [P.sup.*.sub.H,t]/[P.sub.H,t-1] = 1 and [[pi].sub.H,t+1] = 1. So log-linear form of (28) at zero inflation steady-state is:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (29)

Where [mc.sub.t+k] denotes log deviation of marginal cost from its steady state value. The first order Taylor expansion of (29) yields:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (30)

Combining the log-linear of Equation (30) with the result (22) yields the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC):

[[pi].sub.H,t] = [beta](1 - [[theta].sub.H])[E.sub.t]{[[pi].sub.H,t+1]} + [[theta].sub.H][[pi].sub.H,t-1] + [[lambda].sub.H][mc.sub.t] (31)

Where, [[lambda].sub.H] = (1 - [[theta].sub.H])(1 - [beta][[theta].sub.H])/[[theta].sub.H]. The NKPC Equation (31) implies that home country's inflation dynamics drives from both forward looking and backward looking components. The above NKPC representation also called a hybrid version of NKPC with forward looking and backward looking behaviour. It further shows that real marginal cost is also a main determinant of domestic inflation.

2.3. Import Goods Retailers

Following Gali and Monacelli (2005) and Monacelli (2005), we assume that the law-of-one price (LOP) holds at the wholesale level for imports. But, endogenous fluctuations from purchasing power parity (PPP) in the short run arise due to the existence of monopolistically competitive importers. Since, they keep domestic import prices over and above the marginal cost. As a result, the LOP fails to hold at the retail level for domestic imports. Importers purchase foreign goods at world-market prices [P.sup.*.sub.F,t](j) so that the law of one price holds at the border. These purchased foreign goods are then sell to domestic consumers and a mark-up is charged over their cost, which creates a wedge between domestic and import prices of foreign goods when measured in the same currency.

Therefore, law of one price (l.o.p.) gap can be defined as: (18)

[[psi].sub.F,t] = [P.sup.*.sub.t]/[e.sub.t][P.sub.F,t] (32)

Where [e.sub.t] is the nominal exchange rate. Following a similar staggered-pricing argument (29) as defined in the case of domestic producer, the optimal price setting behaviour for the domestic monopolistically competitive importer could be defined as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (33)

Where, [[theta].sub.F] [member of] [0, 1] is the stickiness parameter of importer retailers that cannot re-optimise their prices every period. However, in order to maximise profits, domestic retailers set domestic currency price of imported goods as a markup over [[psi].sub.F,t], as they are concerned with the law of one gap and future path of imported inflation. Therefore, endogenous fluctuations from PPP occurred which provides a mechanism for incomplete pass-through in the short-run. This mechanism finally results in a new Keynesian Phillips curve relationship. Hence, Equation (31) can be defined in term of [[pi].sub.F,t] as:

[[pi].sub.F,t] = [beta](1 - [[theta].sub.F])[E.sub.t]{[[pi].sub.F,t+1]) + [[theta].sub.F][[pi].sub.F,t-1] + [[lambda].sub.F][[psi].sub.F,t] (34)

Where [[lambda].sub.F] = (1 - [[theta].sub.F])(1 - [beta][[theta].sub.F])/[[theta].sub.F]. Since consumer price index (CPI) is defined as: [P.sub.t] [equivalent to] [[(1 - [alpha])[P.sup.1-[eta].sub.H,t] + [alpha][P.sup.1-[eta].sub.F,t]].sup.1/1-[eta]], therefore using (31) and (34) the log-linear form of overall inflation is defined as:

[[pi].sub.t] [equivalent to] [(1 - [alpha])[[pi].sub.H,t] + [alpha][[pi].sub.F,t]] (35)

The above functional form of overall inflation with specifications (31) and (34) completes inflation dynamics for a small open economy like Pakistan.

2.4. Foreign Sector Economy

In this section we drive the open economy dynamics between inflation; terms of trade; real exchange rate; international risk sharing and un-covered interest parity. Since e, is nominal exchange rate. We defined home country real exchange rate as:

[RER.sub.t] [equivalent to] [e.sub.t]P.sub.t/[P.sup.*.sub.t] (36)

Similarly, counterpart of home country, foreign country real exchange rate is the inverse of (36). Due to law of one price gap, term of trade between home and foreign countries may differ. Therefore, domestic term of trade (TOT) [S.sub.t] and foreign TOT [S.sup.*.sub.t] can be defined as:

[S.sub.t] [equivalent to] [P.sub.F,t]/[P.sub.H,t] and [S.sup.*.sub.t] [equivalent to] [P.sup.*.sub.H,t]/[P.sup.*.sub.F,t] (37)

The domestic TOT is thus the price of foreign goods (imports) per unit of domestic goods (exports) and foreign TOT is domestic goods per unit the price of foreign goods. Both Terms of trade coincide inversely only if pass-through is perfect. But in case of imperfect pass-through, the relationship between law of one price gaps and terms of trade can be defined as:

[[psi].sub.F,t]/[S.sub.t] [equivalent to] [[psi].sup.*.sub.H,t]/[S.sup.*.sub.t] (38)

As log-linearising of CPI formula around the steady-state yields the following relationship: [p.sub.t] [equivalent to] [(1 - [alpha])[p.sub.H,t] + [alpha][p.sub.F,t]] and log-linear form of TOT [S.sub.t] as:

[S.sub.t] [equivalent to] [p.sub.F,t] - [p.sub.H,t]. Solving both simultaneously as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (39)

Equation (39) in first difference form can be represented in inflation notation as:

[[??].sub.t] [equivalent to] [[[??].sub.H,t] + [alpha][DELTA][S.sub.t]] (40)

Solving (35) and (40) we have;

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (41)

This shows that domestic TOT is positively related with foreign inflation and its own lag and negatively with domestic inflation.

The real exchange rate of (36) in log-linear form [q.sub.t] can be presented after solving (32), (36) and (37) as:

[q.sub.t] = -[[??].sub.t] - (1 - [alpha])[s.sub.t] (42)

Where [[psi].sub.t] [equivalent to] ln([[PSI].sub.t]) = [p.sup.*.sub.t] - [p.sub.F,t] - [e.sub.t] is LOP gap. If this is equal to one then import price index is equal to foreign price index divided by nominal exchange rate.

The Equation (42) shows that real exchange rate negatively related with both law of one price gap as well as terms of trade.

The log-linear transformation of (36) yields nominal exchange rate relationship as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (43)

Since, under the assumption of complete international financial markets implies perfect risk-sharing between households in both countries. This means that the expected nominal return from risk-free bounds in home currency terms must be same as the expected domestic currency returns from foreign bonds. So,

[E.sub.t][Q.sub.t,t+1] = ([E.sub.t][Q.sup.*.sub.t,t+1] [e.sub.t+1]/[e.sub.t]) ... ... ... (44)

Using this notion (44), we can extent (9) as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (45)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (46)

The log-linear form of (46) gives a relationship between marginal utilities across countries adjust for purchasing power as:

[[XI].sub.t] = [[XI].sup.*.sub.t] - [q.sub.t] ... ... ... (47)

The assumption of complete international asset market also holds another relationship called un-covered interest parity condition (UIP).

[E.sub.t] {[Q.sub.t,t+1]([R.sub.t] - [R.sup.*.sub.t] [e.sup.t]/[e.sub.t+1])} = ... ... ... (48)

The log-linear representation of (48) around steady-state yields the following relationship:

[r.sub.t] - [r.sup.8.sub.t] = [E.sub.t][DELTA][[??].sub.t+1] ... ... ... (49)

This equation implies that the interest rate differential is related with expected future exchange rate depreciation, which defined as un-covered interest parity. Similarly, expression (49) can also be written as:

-([r.sub.t] - [[pi].sub.t+1]) - ([r.sup.*.sub.t] - [[pi].sup.*.sub.t+1]) = [E.sub.t][DELTA][q.sub.t+1] (50)

This equation implies that expected changes in real exchange rate determine by current real interest rate differentials with negative sings.

2.5. Monetary Policy Reaction Function

It is assumed that domestic vis-a-vis foreign central banks follow Taylor-type reaction functions. Since the basic objective of the central bank is to stabilise both output and inflation. So to specify this reaction function it needs to adjusts nominal interest rate in response to deviations of inflation, a measure of output and exchange rate depreciation from their targets. Following Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (2001), simple reaction function can be defined as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (51)

Where [[rho].sub.r] is the degree of interest rate smoothing and [[phi].sub.1], [[phi].sub.2] are relative weights on inflation and output growth respectively. It should be note that this model is estimated using a speed limit policy rather than the traditional Taylor-rule based output and inflation. A recent study Malik and Ahmed (2007) argues that State Bank of Pakistan do not follow a simple Taylor-type-rule, as SBP also considers various other macroeconomic factors, like exchange rate smoothing, etc., while conducting its monetary policy. Following this approach, we initially included these factors into (51), but due to identification issues we again restricted with the simple version, as describes above.

2.6. General Equilibrium

Using the above model setup, we can drive general equilibrium dynamics around their steady-state level. The general equilibrium is achieved from goods market equilibrium and labour market equilibrium. The goods market equilibrium derived from aggregate demand side forces and labour market equilibrium dynamics emerge from aggregate supply side forces. So, the general equilibrium of the whole model is achieved from these market equilibriums.

2.6.1. Aggregate Demand Side: Goods Market Equilibrium and IS-Curve

To find goods market equilibrium, output is equating with domestic consumption, government investment and foreign consumption of domestic produced goods. Hence, market clearing condition is;

[Y.sub.H,t] = [C.sub.H,t] + [Y.sup.*.sub.H,t] ... ... ... (52)

Since, [C.sub.H,t] = (1 - [alpha]) [([P.sub.H,t]/[P.sub.t]).sup.-[eta]] and [C.sup.*.sub.H,t] - (1 - [alpha])[([e.sub.t] [P.sub.H,t]/[P.sup.*.sub.t]).sup.[eta]] [C.sup.*.sub.t], the log-linear

form of this setup is given as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (53)

Final representation after solving (53) simultaneously as:

[[??].sub.H,T] = [alpha][eta][[psi].sub.t] + (1 - [alpha]) {[c.sub.t] + [alpha][eta][s.sub.t]} + [alpha]{[eta]([s.sub.t] + [psi].sub.t]) + [c.sup.*.sub.t]} ... ... ... (54)

or

[y.sub.t] = (2 - [alpha])[alpha][eta][s.sub.t] + (1 - [alpha])[c.sub.t] + [alpha][eta] [[psi].sub.t] + [alpha][y.sup.*.sub.t] ... ... ... (55)

It should also be note that if we plug value of ct is equal to zero then this model converges to closed economy.

2.6.2. Aggregate Supply Side: Marginal Cost and Inflation Dynamics Since we already derived domestic firm's price setting behaviour in terms of NKPC in (29) as:

[[pi].sub.H,t] = [beta](1 - [[theta].sub.H]) [E.sub.t] {[[pi].sub.H,t+1]} + [[theta].sub.H] [[[pi].sub.H,t-1] [[lambda].sub.H] [mc.sub.t]

Where [[lambda].sub.H] = (1 - [[theta].sub.H])(1 - [beta][[theta].sub.H]) and real marginal cost is [m.sub.ct] = [W.sub.t] - [P.sub.H,t] - [[alpha].sub.t].

Assuming symmetrical equilibrium, real marginal cost can also be rewrite as:

[m.sub.ct] = ([v.sub.t] - [p.sub.t]) + ([P.sub.t] - [P.sub.H,t]) - [a.sub.t] ... ... ... (56)

Using (13) and (39) the above expression can also be written as:

[m.sub.ct] = [phi][n.sub.t] [alpha][s.sub.t] + [sigma]/1 - h ([c.sub.t] - [hc.sub.t-1]) - [a.sub.t] ... ... ... (57)

Since, simple log-linear representation of Cob-Douglas production function with one input (labour) is:

[Y.sub.t] = [n.sub.t] + [a.sub.t] ... ... ... (58)

Hence, the final representation of (57) is given as:

[mc.sub.t] = [[phi][y.sub.t] + [alpha][s.sub.t] + [sigma]/1 - h ([c.sub.t] - [hc.sub.t-1]) - (1 + [phi] [a.sub.t] ... ... ... (59)

This model is finally solved using the general methodology provided in Klein (2000). This methodology also considered the autoregressive shocks as exogenous processes. The detail list of endogenous variables and exogenous processes are described in Appendix Table B 1 of Appendix-B.

3. THE EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

This section briefly outlines the empirical setup by illustrating data, choice of priors and estimation methodology used in this paper.

3.1. Data

To estimate the model parameters, data over the quarterly frequencies from 1984:Q1 to 2007:Q4 (post floating period) is used on eight macroeconomic variables: domestic output ([y.sub.t]); foreign output ([y.sup.*.sub.t]); domestic overall inflation ([[pi].su.t]); imported inflation ([[pi].sub.F,t]);domestic interest rate ([r.sub.t]); foreign real interest rate ([r.sup.*.sub.t]); real exchange rate ([q.sub.t]); and term of trade ([s.sub.t]). Since the model has implications for the log-deviations from the steady-state of all these variables, so we pre-process the data before the estimation stage. Details on the construction and the sources of the data set are provided in Appendix-A. Pair wise correlation matrix of above mentioned variables is also available in Table A2 of Appendix-A. These correlations are consistent with the standard theory.

3.2. Choice of Priors

According to the Schorfiede (2000), priors can be gleaned from personal introspection to reflect strongly held beliefs about the validity of economic theories. Priors also reflect researcher confidence about the likely location of structural parameter of the model. In practice, priors are chosen based on observation, facts and from existing empirical literature.

For our study, two parameters [alpha] and [beta] fixed (19) at 0.35 and 0.95. For parameter [alpha] (degree of openness) which is consistent with the average trade to GDP ratio during the sample period. This parameter value can also be depict from Figure A3 of Appendix-A. The parameter value of discount factor ([beta]) is set in order to obtain historical mean of the nominal interest rate in the steady state. The degree of habit persistence (h) in consumption is set as 0.5 with standard deviation equal to 0.2. As usual in the literature, the inverse elasticity of intermporal substitution in consumption ([sigma]) assumed to follow normal distribution with prior means 1.0 and standard deviations equal to 0.4. The elasticity of intratemporal substitution between a bundle of home goods ([eta]) and the inverse of wage elasticity of labour supply ([phi]) are assumed to follow gamma distributions with prior means 1.0 and standard deviations equal to 0.4. See for instance, Smets and Wouters (2003).

Following Ireland (2004) and Lubik and Schorfiede (2005) the parameters measuring the degree of Clavo price stickiness ([[theta].sub.H] ) and ([[theta].sub.F] ) are assumed to have the same mean value equal to 0.50 with standard deviation equal to 0.25. (20) In the case of Pakistan, the average frequency of price change of various commodities and average prices (CPI) fall within the interval from 0.45 to 0.55 as shown in the Figures Al and A2 of Appendix-A. So the prior value of ([[theta].sub.H] ) is also consistent with the Pakistan's data. The priors on the coefficients in the monetary policy reaction functions are standard: a relatively high prior mean on the inflation coefficient ([[phi].sub.1]) with mean 1.5 and standard deviation equal to 0.25 and slightly low output growth coefficient ([[theta].sub.2]) with mean 025 and standard deviation equal to 0.10. The persistence coefficient domestic and foreign monetary policy reaction function is set to 0.5 with standard deviation equal to 0.20.

Finally all other priors mean values with their standard deviations are available in first column of Table B3 in Appendix-B.

3.3. Bayesian Estimation Approach

In empirical literature, there are numerous strategies used to determine the parameters of new-Keynesian DSGE models. These ranging from pure calibration, e.g., Kydland and Prescott (1982), Monacelli (2005); over generalised method of moments (GMM) for estimation of general equilibrium relationships, e.g., Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992); to full-information based maximum likelihood estimation as in Altug(1989), Mcgrattan (1994), Leeper and Sims (1994), Kim (2000) and Irland (2000). Other studies also proposed mixed strategies like limited-information based methods to explore a key question whether a DSGE model matches the data with some certain dimensions. For example, Canova (2002) and Christiano, et al. (2005) used minimum distance based criterion to estimate VAR and DSGE model impulse response functions. Further methodological debate can be referred using the following studies by Diebold (1998), Ruge-Murcia (2003) and Tovar (2008).

Other than these proposed estimation and calibration strategies, this study uses another estimation approach called Bayesian estimation approach. This alternative approach is a combination of calibration and estimation of selected model parameters. The fundamental advantage of this approach is a batter adaption of the model to the conditions in the given economy, see e.g., Smets and Wouters (2003).

In any empirical modeling exercise, there are three possible sources of uncertainty; the model itself; the parameterisation condition of the model and the data. The debate on the issue of uncertainty is the most important as it provide a difference between frequentist (classical) and Bayesian approach. In classical approach the probability of the occurrence of an event, i.e., the measurement of uncertainty is associated with its frequency. However, in Bayesian approach, the probability of an event is determined by two components; the subjective believe (prior) and the frequency of that event. For further detail on this notion, see for instance Gelman (2006) and Koopman, et al. (2007).

The seminal work on DSGE modeling used this approach started with the study by Landon-Lane (1998), DeJong, et al. (2000), Schorfheide (2000) and Otrok (2001). This approach has been generalised by Lubik and Schorfheide (2005) who estimate a DSGE model without providing restrictions to the determinacy region of the parameter space. Almost all recent studies on DSGE model has been used this approach, e.g., Smets and Wouters (2003), Laforte (2004), Onatski and Williams (2004), Ratto, et al. (2008), Adolfson, et al. (2008) and Kolasa (2008).

In practical sense, we try to fit out referenced model, which consists in placing a prior distribution [rho]([GAMMA]) on structural parameters F, the estimate of which are then updated using the data [Y.sup.T] according to the Bayes rule:

p([GAMMA]/[Y.sub.T]) = p([Y.sub.T]/[GAMMA])/p([Y.sub.T])[varies] L([GAMMA]/[Y.sup.T])p([GAMMA]) ... ... ... (60)

Where p([Y.sup.T]/[GAMMA]) = L([GAMMA]/[Y.sup.T]) is the likelihood function p ([GAMMA]/[Y.sup.T]) is the posterior distribution of parameters and p([Y.sup.T]) is the marginal likelihood defined as:

p([GAMMA]/[Y.sub.T]) = [integral] p ([Y.sub.T]/[GAMMA])p([GAMMA])d[GAMMA] ... ... ... (61)

Any DSGE model forms a linear system with rational expectations, the solution to which is of the form:

[R.sub.t] = [B.sub.1]([GAMMA])[R.sub.t-1] + [B.sub.2]([GAMMA]) [[mu].sub.t] ... ... ... (62)

[[mu].sub.t] = [B.sub.3]([GAMMA])[[mu].sub.t-1] + [B.sub.4]([GAMMA]) [[epsilon].sub.t ... ... ... (63)

Where [R.sub.t] is a vector of endogenous variables, [[mu].sub.t] is a vector of stochastic disturbances and a, is a vector of innovations to stochastic shocks and coefficient matrices Ai depending on the parameters of the model. The measurement Equations (62) and (63) linking observable variables used in the estimation with endogenous variables can be written as:

[Y.sub.T] = [CR.sub.t] ... ... ... (64)

Where, C is the deterministic matrix. The Equations (62), (63) and (64) form the state-space representation of the model. The likelihood of which can be evaluated using Kalman filter. The analytical solution of the whole system may not be obtain in general, however the sequence of posterior draws can be obtain using Markov-Chain-Monte-Carlo (MCMC) simulation methodology. This methodology is briefly discussed in Lubik and Schorfheide (2005), Gelman, et al. (2006) and Koopman, et al. (2007). For our open economy DSGE model the random walk Metropolis-Hastings algorithm is used to generate Morkov-Chains (MC) for the model parameters.

3.4. Fitness and Stability of Model Structural Parameter

Following Global Sensitivity Analysis (GSA) toolkit, (21) we assess the fitness and stability of model structural parameters and structural shocks. This toolkit consists of MATLAB programme routines, which used Smirnov-test for stability analysis. Ratto (2008) provided detail discussion on using this toolkit with various applied examples.

4. ESTIMATION RESULTS

In this section the estimation results from the small open economy DSGE model are discussed. First we shell analyse the parameter estimates and then we shell discuss model impulse response functions with all their possible dynamics.

4.1. Parameter Estimates

In line with Bayesian estimation approach by combining the suitable priors with the likelihood leads to an analytically-intractable posterior density. In order to sample from the posterior, random walk Metropolis-Hastings algorithm is used to generate 150,000 draws from the posteriors. We reported the posterior results (parameter estimates) in the second column of Table B3 of Appendix-B. Furthermore, Figure B 1 of Appendix-B displays kernel estimates of the priors and the posteriors of each parameter. These results show that prior and posterior means are in most the cases considerably away from each other.

The parameter (h) is equal to 0.36 which is a bit lower than its prior mean of 0.5. This parameter value implies that degree of habit persistence in consumption is quite low as compared with advance economies; see for instance, Lubik and Schorfeide (2005). The parameter estimates of inverse elasticity of intermporal substitution in consumption ([sigma]), the elasticity of intratemporal substitution between a bundle of home goods ([eta]) and the inverse of wage elasticity of labour supply ([phi]) are 0.84, 1.01, 0.98 respectively. It should also be noted that high value of ([sigma]) show that household are more willingness to accept deviation from a uniformed pattern of consumption over time. This high value of inverse elasticity of intermporal substitution in consumption is also consistent with the low value of habit persistence as noted above. These parameter values are not apart from their prior means.

The posterior estimates of Calvo price stickiness provide reasonable notion about frequencies of price change which is the probability of not changing price in a given quarters. The estimated values of ([[theta].sub.H]) and ([[theta].sub.F]) are 0.24 and 0.76 respectively, which shows the proportion of firms that do not re-optimise their prices in a given quarters. Furthermore, comparatively lower value of ([[theta].sub.H] ) shows domestic firms re-optimise their prices in a given quarters frequently. These staggered price coefficients imply that the average duration of price contracts is around two quarters for domestic firms and three to four quarters for import retailers. This duration is calculated as: 1/(1-[theta]). These results are also consistent with da Silveira (2006) in the case of Brazil (emerging market economy) and Smets and Wouters (2003) in the case of US.

The posterior estimates of Central Bank reaction function provide a reasonable description of monetary policy design in Pakistan during the sample period. The posterior estimate of inflation coefficient ([[phi].sub.1]) is 1.17 which is slightly low from its prior mean and output growth coefficient ([[phi].sub.2]) is 0.72 which is above from its prior mean. This also shows that policy-maker in Pakistan put more weight on growth objectives as compared with other developing economies. A recent empirical study by Malik and Ahmed (2007) argued that coefficient values (weights) as suggested by Taylor (1993) are not suitable for Pakistan's monetary policy reaction function. However, our estimated values of monetary policy reaction function are approximately closed to Taylor rule. Finally, the posterior mean for the degree of interest rate smoothing is estimated to be 0.94 which is quite high degree of smoothness as compare with its prior mean. The overall results of reaction function show the effectiveness of monetary policy design in Pakistan with price stability as its primary objective consistent with the economic growth objectives. Finally all posterior estimates with their 95 percent confidence interval are available in second column of Table B3 in Appendix-B.

4.2. Parameter Fitness and Stability Results

Parameter's stability and fitness results are provided in Figure-B2 of Appendix-B. The d-stat of Smirnov-test is also provided for each parameter, which shows the significance of for individual parameter into the whole model. Furthermore, cumulative plots for stability and instability behaviour provide us useful information for the fitness of each structural parameter. Figure B2 shows that all model parameters are stable and properly fitter with respect to the data.

Similar to structural parameters we also assessed the fitness of structural shocks. The d-stat results vis-a-vis cumulative plots show that all structural shocks are fitted but with some degree of instability. This might be due to some degree of seasonality which still exists in the quarterly constructed data.

4.3. Impulse Response Analysis

Figure B3 of Appendix-B shows the impulse response functions for model endogenous variables in response to the various structural shocks. (22) These impulse response functions provide several interesting results.

First figure plots the impulse response to positive domestic labour productivity shock. Following this shock, domestic output initially increases up to two quarters and decrease slightly before staying above trend until eight quarters later. The later decrease in output shows that agent's substitution between working and leisure dominates the lower cost of production that arises from the increase in productivity. Secondly consumption falls initially up to one quarter then increases but increment is steady and almost around its steady path. Inflation on the other hand falls initially as the higher labour productivity supports to minimise the cost of production before returning close to steady state eight quarters later. (23) All other variables fall initially and returning close to zero up to four to six quarters later.

Second figure plots the impulse response to a positive domestic inflation shock. (24) Following this shock, domestic output initially fall, up to two quarters and then returning close to its steady state four to six quarters later. Secondly consumption also falls initially up to one quarter but its decline magnitude is relatively less as compared with domestic output. This also shows that high inflation in Pakistan do not hit domestic consumption significantly. Thirdly, positive shock in domestic inflation decreases the degree of domestic competitiveness. Furthermore, the central bank of Pakistan responds to the higher rate of inflation by increasing the interest rate by 100 to 200 basis points. In response to this monetary tightening domestic output decreasing up to one to two quarters but this decline impact is very nominal. Exchange rate on the other hand appreciates in response to positive domestic supply shock.

Third figure plots the impulse response to a positive imported inflation shock. The impact of this shock on the model endogenous variables is quite different as compared with domestic inflation or supply shock. In response to this shock domestic inflation increases, as higher import prices pushing up the cost of production causes as a surge in domestic inflation. Term of trade increases as foreign prices increases relative to domestic prices. The economic interpretation of this surge in the degree of competiveness is that domestic agents substitute out of foreign produced goods into home produced goods in response to import inflation shock which causes expenditure switching effect and hence leads to a surge in domestic terms of trade. The central bank of Pakistan responds to the higher rate of imported inflation by increasing the interest rate by 150 to 250 basis points as compared with domestic inflation case. This also leads an exchange rate appreciation but this appreciation is higher than in the case of domestic inflation.

Forth figure plots the impulse response to a positive interest rate shock which also considered as a domestic monetary policy shock. Following the increase in the interest rate, domestic inflation, imported inflation, degree of international competitiveness and domestic output decreases; exchange rate appreciates before returning to equilibrium.

Consumption on the other hand increases by one percent and returning close to its steady state up to four to six quarters. These results reasonably capture the effectiveness of monetary policy as it shows to achieve its basic objectives, with some nominal tradeoffs, in terms of output decline and exchange rate appreciation. Furthermore, due to continuous domestic supply and foreign price shocks there needs to further tightening of monetary is order to curb these frights.

Fifth figure plots the impulse response to a positive exchange rate shock. This shock transmits from uncovered interest parity condition (25) to rest of the model. In response to this shock domestic inflation, output, interest rate decreases but the decrement impact in all the variables is very nominal. For monetary policy perspective, interest rates decline by 50 basis points. This also indicates a monetary expansion in the case of surge in UIP condition. (26) Lastly, this shock decreases the degree of international competitiveness and increases consumption up to six and two percent respectively.

Sixth figure plots the impulse response to a positive term of trade shock. Following this shock, all variables show a minor surge except imported inflation which shows a decline behaviour and return to zero up to four quarters later. This shock also causes an exchange rate appreciation. Lastly for monetary policy perspective, interest rate shows a positive response to this shock up to 10 basis points and then returns to its equilibrium path up to two quarters later. This small monetary tightening helps to offset the adverse impact in term of domestic inflation and exchange rate appreciation.

Final two figures show impulse responses to a positive foreign output shock and foreign monetary policy shock. Due to these positive shocks, all domestic endogenous variables behave according to the theory. This also represents the effectiveness of model, which is quite useful for policy decision making.

5. CONCLUSION

In this paper, we estimate a small open economy DSGE model for Pakistan. The model setup is based on new Keynesian framework characterised by nominal rigidity in prices with habit formation in household's consumption. This framework allows us to include microeconomic foundations of optimum behaviour of the economic agents; domestic households, domestic firms, monetary authority and foreign sector economy, into the system. It is also considered that the foreign sector is completely exogenous to the system. In our empirical section, some parameters has been calibrated, e.g., degree of openness, discount factor, inverse elasticity of intertemporal substitution; the remaining parameters has been estimated using the Bayesian simulation approach, which combines prior information from preliminary estimates and from historical data covering period 1984:Q1 to 2007:Q4. The model ability to describe the dynamic structure of Pakistan economy has been analysed by means of impulse-response functions.

The estimation results of structural parameters and model impulse response functions yield useful quantitative vis-a-vis qualitative information. The exogenous shocks impact on endogenous system variables in the right direction, so that the model seems to be helpful as a complementary tool for monetary policy analysis in the Pakistan economy.

From several interesting results, few are; (a) high inflation in Pakistan do not hit domestic consumption significantly; (b) Central bank of Pakistan responds to" high inflation by increasing the policy rate by 100 to 200 bps; (c) exchange rate appreciates in both the cases of high domestic and imported inflation; (d) tight monetary policy stance helps to curb domestic inflation as well as imported inflation but appreciates exchange rate significantly (f) pass through of exchange rate to domestic inflation is very low; finally parameter value of domestic price stickiness shows that around 24 percent domestic firms do not re-optimise their prices which implies averaged price contract is about two quarters.

Finally, this model is still in progress. After relaxing some key assumptions and incorporating fiscal-side dynamics, this model will be more robust for policy decision making and future forecasting of key macroeconomic variables.

APPENDIX-A

[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE A3 OMITTED]

[FIGURE A4 OMITTED]
Table A1
Description of Variables

S.
No Variable * Description / Source

1 [y.sub.t] Quarterly real GDP per capita as a proxy of
 domestic output. We follow Kemal and Arby
 (2004) to construct this series. We initially
 convert original series into new base (Year
 2000=100). Since it is an interpolated series
 from annual frequency data, so we also perform
 necessary seasonal adjustments using moving
 average methodology. Finally, for stationarity
 purpose we detrend this series from its linear
 trend. **

2 [[pi].sub.t] Overall domestic inflation. This series is the
 annual growth rates in consumer price index
 (CPI) for Pakistan. Data source of this
 variable is FBS, Islamabad, Pakistan.

3 [[pi].sub.F,t] Imported Inflation as a proxy of foreign
 inflation. This series is the annual growth
 rates in unit value of import index (UVIM).
 This series is taken from IFS-CD June 2008
 version.

4 [q.sub.t] Real exchange rate. This series is calculated
 by multiplying nominal exchange rate with Pak-
 US price ratios where CPI of both countries is
 a suitable proxy of respected prices. Data
 source of this variable is IFS-CD June 2008
 version.

5 [r.sub.t] Nominal interest rate. Short term money market
 rate is taken as the proxy of nominal interest
 rate. Data source of this variable is
 Statistical Bulletins of the State Bank of
 Pakistan.

6 [s.sub.t] Term of Trade (ToT). This series is calculated
 by taking the ratio of the unit value of import
 index (UVIM) and unit value of export index
 (UVEX). Data source of this series is IFS-CD
 June 2008 version.

7 [y.sup. *.sub.t] Foreign Output. The series is taken as annual
 growth rate in U.S. real GDP per capita. This
 is obtained from IFS-CD June 2008 version.

8 [r.sup. *.sub.t] Foreign real interest rates. This series is
 calculated by subtracting nominal US money
 market rates from expected inflation. Data
 source of this variable is IFS-CD June 2008
 version.

* For stationary purpose, all series are converted into detrended
form. This is done by subtracting each series from its linear
trend.

** Detrended output is also considered as a proxy of output gap,
see for instance, Bukhari and khan (2008).

Table A2
Pairwise Correlation Matrix

 [y.sub.t] [y.sup.*.sub.t] [[pi].sub.t]

[y.sub.t] 1.00
[y.sup.*.sub.t] 0.23 1.00
[[pi].sub.t] -0.05 0.18 1.00
[[pi].sub.F,t] -0.05 0.28 0.08
[r.sub.t] -0.28 -0.12 0.11
[r.sup.*.sub.t] -0.16 0.06 0.05
[q.sub.t] -0.21 -0.31 -0.75
[s.sub.t] -0.06 0.02 -0.24

 [[pi].sub.F,t] [r.sub.t] [r.sup.*.sub.t]

[y.sub.t]
[y.sup.*.sub.t]
[[pi].sub.t]
[[pi].sub.F,t] 1.00
[r.sub.t] -0.13 1.00
[r.sup.*.sub.t] 0.08 0.58 1.00
[q.sub.t] -0.07 -0.17 -0.10
[s.sub.t] -0.28 0.46 0.49

 [q.sub.t] [s.sub.t]

[y.sub.t]
[y.sup.*.sub.t]
[[pi].sub.t]
[[pi].sub.F,t]
[r.sub.t]
[r.sup.*.sub.t]
[q.sub.t] 1.00
[s.sub.t] 0.21 1.00


APPENDIX-B

B1. Log-Linearisation and canonical representation of the model

This section proceeds by a model solution methodology with the log-linearisation and canonical representation of the model along with its foreign sector economy, (27) In order to solve the model, we first state the first order nonlinear dynamic system that characterises the competitive equilibrium. In order to calculate the steady state we transform the system equations into their deterministic steady state representation and solve using numerical methods. Then we log-linearise around the deterministic steady state where [[??].sub.t] =log([x.sub.t]) - log([bar.x]). At this stage the system is expressed in terms of relative deviations from the steady state. After solving the model using the method of Klein (2000) (28) we obtain matrices M and H which generate the dynamic solution by iterating on the following two equations:

[Y.sub.t] = H[x.sub.t] ... ... ... (b1)

[x.sub.t+1] = M[x.sub.t] + R[[eta].sub.t+1 ... ... ... (b2)

Where Y is a vector composed by control, co-state and flow variables, x is a vector of endogenous and exogenous states, H characterises the policy function and M the state transition matrix, [[eta].sub.t+1] is an innovation vector and R is a matrix composed of zeros, ones or a parameter instead of a one. This matrix determines which variables are hit by the shock and in what magnitude. Given a set of values of the parameters of the model, this state space representation will help us to compute the relevant statistics of the model such as the spectrum of the data, the likelihood function, among others.

The small open economy model consists of eleven equations for endogenous variables and three equations for the exogenous processes.

The canonical representation of the whole model in log-linearised form is available in Table B2.

[FIGURE B1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B3 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B4 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B5 OMITTED]
Table B1
Description of Model Endogenous and Exogenous Variables

1. List of endogenous variables: {[y.sub.t]; [y.sup.*.sub.t];
 [[pi].sub.t];
 [[pi].sub.F,t]; [r.sub.t];
 [r.sup.*.sub.t]; [q.sub.t]}

2. List of endogenous state variables: {[psi].sub.t]; [c.sub.t];
 [mc.sub.t]; [[pi].sub.H,t];
 [s.sub.t]}

3. List of model endogenous innovations [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
 REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

4. List of model exogenous shocks: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
 REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Table B2
Canonical Representation of the Model

S. No. Description Model Log-Linearised Equation(s)

1. Goods Market [y.sub.t] = (2 - [alpha])
 Clearing [alpha][eta][s.sub.t]
 Condition

2. Firm Marginal [mc.sub.t] = [phi][y.sub.t] + [alpha]
 Cost [s.sub.t] + [sigma]/1-h ([c.sub.t] -
 [hc.sub.t-a]) - (1 + [phi])
 [[alpha].sub.t]

3. Domestic Inflation [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
 REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

4. Imported Inflation [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
 REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

5. Overall Inflation [[pi].sub.t] = [(1 - [alpha])
 [[pi].sub.H,t] + [alpha][[pi].sub.F,t]]

6. Monetary Policy [r.sub.t] = [[rho].sub.r][r.sub.t-1] +
 Reaction Function (1 - [[rho].sub.r]) ([[phi].sub.l]
 [[??].sub.t] + [[phi].sub.2][DELTA]
 [[??].sub.t]) + [[rho].sup.r.sub.t]

7. Uncovered [E.sub.t][DELTA][q.sub.t+1] = -
 Interest Parity ([r.sub.t] - [[pi].sub.t+1]) -
 Condition ([r.sup.*.sub.t] - [[pi].sup.*.sub.t+1])
 + [[rho].sup.q.sub.t]

8. Term of Trade [s.sub.t]=[s.sub.t-1] + [[??].sub.F,t] -
 with Measurement [[??].sub.H,t] + [[rho].sup.s.sub.t]
 Error

9. Law of One Price [[??].sub.t] = -[q.sub.t] -
 Gap (1 - [alpha]) [s.sub.t])

10. Consumption [E.sub.t] ([c.sub.t+1] - [hc.sub.t]) -
 Euler Equation (1-h/[sigma]) ([r.sub.t] -
 [E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1]) = [c.sub.t] -
 [hc.sub.t-1]

11. International Risk [y.sup.*.sub.t] - [hy.sup.*.sub.t-1] -
 Sharing Condition (1-h/[sigma]) [q.sub.t] = [c.sub.t] -
 [hc.sub.t-1]

12. Exogenous [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
 Processes REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

* Table Key: All exogenous processes follow recursive equilibrium
law of motion.

Table B3
Model Prior and Posterior Distribution Results

Prior Distributions

Parameters Distribution Mean Std_Dev

alpha beta 0.35 0.20
H beta 0.50 0.20
sigma normal 1.00 0.40
eta gamma 1.00 0.40
phi gamma 1.00 0.40
thetah beta 0.50 0.25
thetaf beta 0.50 0.25
phi1 gamma 1.50 0.25
phi2 gamma 0.25 0.10
rhor beta 0.50 0.20
rhorst beta 0.50 0.20
rhoa beta 0.50 0.20
laml beta 0.50 0.20
sig_a normal 2.00 0.50
sig_s normal 2.00 0.50
sig_q normal 2.00 0.50
sig_pi normal 2.00 0.25
sig_pif normal 1.00 0.20
sig_r normal 1.00 0.20
sig_rst normal 0.50 0.20
sig_yst normal 1.00 0.20

Posterior Distribution

Distribution Mean 5% Percentile 95% Percentile

beta 0.23 0.19 0.24
beta 0.36 0.33 0.37
normal 0.84 0.80 0.86
gamma 1.01 1.00 1.08
gamma 0.98 0.91 1.04
beta 0.24 0.21 0.36
beta 0.76 0.68 0.82
gamma 1.17 1.10 1.23
gamma 0.72 0.65 0.78
beta 0.94 0.87 1.00
beta 0.43 0.36 0.49
beta 0.51 0.44 0.57
beta 0.36 0.29 0.42
normal 2.04 1.98 2.11
normal 1.92 1.86 1.99
normal 2.04 1.98 2.11
normal 2.02 1.96 2.09
normal 1.62 1.56 1.69
normal 1.28 1.22 1.35
normal 0.50 0.44 0.57
normal 1.63 1.57 1.70

Table Key:

(a/) The posterior mean of all the estimation parameters are
delivered by a 150,000 runs of Metropolis-Hastings algorithm.

(b/) We use two MATLAB toolboxes; Dynare 4.0 and Uhlig toolkit
version 4.1 to estimate our model. Both toolkits 19 are freely
available on internet. (29)

(c/) The parameter beta which is discount factor is fixed at
0.95.


APPENDIX-C
Table C1
A Quick View of Empirical Evidence on DSGE Model

Country Authors Authors Model Description

Canada Dib. This study develops
 Gammoudi on the basis of New
 and Moran Keynesian model for
 (2008) Canada. This model
 in particular computes
 out of sample
 forecasts and
 compares its forecasts
 with those arising
 from VAR models. It
 shows that the
 forecasts are
 favorably valid with
 that of the benchmark,
 particularly as the
 forecasting horizon
 increases. Thus the
 study deduces that the
 model could become
 a useful forecasting
 tool for Canadian
 economy.

Central Europe Sadeq, T. This paper uses a
Transition (2008) small open economy
Economies DSGE model for
 central Europe
 Transition economies,
 EU-15: Czech
 Republic, Hungary,
 Poland, Slovakia and
 Slovenia. The
 objective is to analyse
 the general model
 convergence issues.

Poland Kolasa, M. This paper presents a
 (2008) two-country model
 linking Poland and
 the euro area

Australia Buncic and This paper provides an
 Melecky open economy New
 (2008) Keynesian policy
 model for Australian
 economy. It focuses to
 observe the importance
 of external shocks on
 macroeconomic
 fluctuations as
 compared to the impact
 of domestic shocks.

United Kingdom DiCecio and This study replicates
 Nelson the DSGE model of
 (2007) Christiano, Eichenbaum
 and Evans (2005), in
 which both the nominal
 frictions and dynamics
 in preferences and
 productions are
 incorporated.

Low-Income Peiries and This paper presents
Countries Saxegard DSGE model to
 (2007) evaluate monetary
 policy tradeoffs in low-
 income countries under
 certain assumptions.
 The model is estimated
 on data for
 Mozambique in sub-
 Sahara Africa except
 South Africa.

New Zealand Liu (2006) This study designs
 DSGE based New
 Keynesian framework
 to describe the key
 features of a small open
 economy. Particularly
 the model focuses on
 the transmission
 mechanism of monetary
 policy to provide a tool
 for basic policy
 simulations. This
 model, however, shows
 the capacity to simulate
 the monetary paths and
 to analyse the policy
 outcome in uncertainty.

Brazil da Silveria, This paper presents a
 M.A.C. small open economy
 (2006) DSGE model for
 Barazilian economy
 with special reference
 to monetary policy
 analysis. A distinctive
 feature of the model is
 that the terms of trade
 enters directly into the
 new Keynesian Phillips
 curve as a new pushing
 cost variable feeding
 theinflation, so that
 there is no more the
 direct relationship
 between marginal cost
 and output gapthat
 characterises the closed
 economies.

Chile Medina and This study presents
 Soto (2006) DSGE model for policy
 analysis and
 simulations. The main
 characteristics of this
 model are: wages and
 prices are sticky with
 adjustment costs in
 investment and habit
 persistence in
 consumption behavior;
 exchange rate pass-
 through to import prices
 is imperfect. On the
 supply side a domestic
 sector where firms
 produce tradable goods
 and the commodity
 export sector.

Colombia Hamman, This study develops
 Perez and DSGE model for small
 Rodriguez open economy of
 (2006) Colombia. This model
 take in to account two
 main sectors
 categorised as tradable
 and non-tradable
 sectors with three
 agents; households,
 firms and government
 sector. Finally this
 model exhibits two
 features; first nominal
 rigidities in the form of
 Calve pricing in the
 non tradable sector and
 second
 perfect/imperfect pass-
 through of exchange
 rate movements into
 imported goods prices.

Latin America Tovar (2006) This study is focused
 on the analysis of
 effects of currency
 devaluations on output
 in Chile, Colombia and
 Mexico using an
 estimated DSGE model.
 This study also
 Provides comparison
 across these three
 economies by utilising
 the estimated
 parameters.

Czech Republic Benes, This is a small open
 Hledik and economy DSGE model.
 Vavra (2005) The characteristics of
 this model are so broad
 with the innovative
 Benes, features. These are
 international currency
 pricing scheme
 permitting flexible
 calibration of import
 and export price
 elasticities along with
 the disconnect of
 nominal exchange rate.

United States Negro, This paper presents the
Euro Area Schorfheide, modified version of
 Smets and DSGE model for Euro
 Wouters Negro, area. This model
 (2005) introduces stochastic
 trends so that it can be
 fitted to unfiltered time
 series observations. It
 contains a large number
 of nominal and real
 frictions and various
 structural shocks.

Euro Area Wouters and Authors develop the
 Smets (2003) DSGE model with stick
 prices and wages for
 the euro area. This
 model includes many
 other features such as
 habit formation, costs
 of adjustment in capital
 accumulation and the
 variable of capacity
 utilisation.

Country Data Description

Canada This study includes
 the sample of 1981:1
 to 2004:4. Since the
 model is driven by
 four shocks thus it is
 estimated using data
 for four series. The
 variables are output
 in terms of real
 domestic demand,
 inflation, a short
 term interest rate and
 real money balances.

Central Europe Quarterly data for
Transition the sample range
Economies 1996:2 to 2007:2 has
 been used for
 empirical analysis.
 Variables from each
 country is selected.
 These inlcude real
 GDP, household
 consumption,
 nominal wages, CPI
 Inflation, and
 nominal short term
 interest rates.

Poland The sample period is
 1997:1 to 2006:4.
 The model uses GDP
 growth,
 consumption, CPI
 inflation, real wages,
 investment, nominal
 exchange rates and
 interest rates
 variables.

Australia For empirical purpose
 quarterly data has been
 used ranging from
 1983/84:1 to 2005:4.
 Variables are foreign
 interest rate, the foreign
 inflation, foreign output
 gap, domestic interest
 rate, domestic inflation,
 domestic output gap, real
 exchange rate and
 nominal exchange rate
 series.

United Kingdom The sample period is
 1979:2 to 2005:4.
 Variables are UK treasury
 bill rate, real GDP, private
 household consumption,
 gross fixed capital
 formation, business
 investment as an
 alternative investment
 series, productivity and
 inflation.

Low-Income This model is estimated
Countries on quarterly data covering
 the period of 1996:1 to
 2005:4. Variable are
 GDP, consumption,
 exports, imports, the real
 exchange rate, inflation,
 export price inflation,
 import price inflation,
 M2, currency in
 circulation, deposit rates,
 lending rates, foreign
 currency reserves,
 government spending, and
 lending to the private
 sector.

New Zealand Data from 1991QI to
 2004Q4 for New Zealand
 is used. Key variables are
 GDP, overall inflation,
 import inflation, nominal
 interest rate, competitive
 price index, real exchange
 rate, foreign output, and
 foreign real interest rate.

Brazil This model is estimated on
 quarterly data of the
 Barzilian and U.S.
 economies for the periods
 from 1999 Q3 to 2005 Q3.
 Variables included real
 GDP, CPI Inflation, 3
 month T. Bill rate, Real
 Exchange Rate as a proxy
 of short term interest rates,
 Term of Trade, U.S. real
 per capita GDP and U.S.
 CPI Inflation.

Chile Quarterly data for the
 period of 1990: 1 to 2005: 4
 has been used. Variables
 include real GDP,
 consumption, investment,
 exports; commodity
 production by using
 natural-resources based
 GDP as a proxy, short run
 real interest rates, a
 measure of core inflation as
 a proxy for inflation, the
 real exchange rate, nominal
 devaluation, and real
 wages. It also include real
 foreign GDP, foreign
 inflation weighted average
 of inflation in trade
 partners, foreign interest
 rate and the international
 price of copper deflated by
 the foreign price index.

Colombia Quarterly data with the
 range of 1987:1 to 2005:4
 has been used in estimation.
 The variables are inflation,
 nominal interest rate, and
 real output and exchange
 rate. These variables are
 transformed according to
 the characteristics of the
 model.

Latin America Seasonally adjusted
 quarterly series have
 been used with the range
 from 1989:1 to 2005:4.
 The variables are
 inflation, output, labor,
 private consumption,
 changes of the nominal
 exchange rate, interest
 rate, and the level of
 nominal exchange rate.

Czech Republic This paper uses
 quarterly data with the
 sample range 1996:1 to
 2004:4 for Czech
 economy. The main
 variables are GDP,
 import prices, export
 prices, investment,
 labor, consumption
 expenditures, labor
 participation, wage rate,
 exchange rate, interest
 rate, and inflation.

United States Quarterly data for the
Euro Area sample range 1986:1 to
 2002:4 has been used for
 empirical analysis.
 Variables are GDP per
 capita, investment,
 hourly nominal wages,
 GDP deflator, M2 per
 capita, and nominal
 short term interest rates.

Euro Area The key variables used
 in this study are GDP,
 consumption,
 investment, prices, real
 wages, employment and
 the nominal interest.

Country Estimating Technique

Canada This study-uses slightly
 different estimation strategy
 as compared with others for
 estimating DSGE models.
 For example it points out
 that this estimation shows
 an advantage of estimating
 and forecasting for the log
 levels of the data, rather
 than forecasts for detrended
 series. The method of
 estimation is Maximum
 likelihood. It also describes
 about the impulse response
 drawn from the estimates.

Central Europe This model is estimated by
Transition utilising the Bayesian
Economies techniques utilising
 information from the
 previous studies as priors.

Poland This open economy DSGE
 framework is empirically
 evaluated through
 calibrations and estimated
 by the Bayesian approach
 utilising information from
 the previous studies as
 priors.

Australia In the estimation section
 this study mentions
 different weaknesses of
 different methods to
 estimate this NKPM.
 Therefore, authors prefer
 to estimate this model in
 Bayesian framework.

United Kingdom In the first stage authors
 estimate monetary policy
 shock from a VAR and
 then use minimum-
 distance estimation
 procedures for estimating
 this DSGE model.

Low-Income This DSGE framework is
Countries empirically evaluated
 through calibrations and
 estimated by the Bayesian
 approach utilising
 information from the
 previous studies as priors.

New Zealand Similar to many other
 empirical studies Liu
 (2006) estimates the
 DSGE for small open
 economy in Bayesian
 framework. This method
 provides comparison
 between non-nested
 models and parameter
 uncertainty explicitly.
 The Bayesian inferences
 are in terms of
 probabilistic statements
 rather than the notional
 repeated samples of
 classical hypothesis
 testine procedures.

Brazil This small open economy
 DSGE framework is
 empirically evaluated
 through calibrations and
 estimated by the Bayesian
 approach utilising
 information from the
 previous studies as priors.

Chile The Bayesian
 methodology is applied to
 jointly estimate the
 parameters of this DSGE
 model. This study takes
 into account the
 information of Priors from
 the earlier empirical
 studies for Chile, or
 imposes diffuse Priors by
 setting a relatively large
 standard deviation for the
 corresponding density
 function. By using the
 estimated Posteriors this
 study provides analysis of
 impulse-response for a
 shock to the exported
 commodity good, foreign
 output and a monetary
 shock.

Colombia In this study three
 methods are reviewed and
 used in estimating the
 DSGE model. These
 methods are Calibration,
 Minimum Distance
 Spectral Analysis and the
 Bayesian technique.

Latin America This DSGE model is
 estimated by the Maximum
 Likelihood method. This
 study claims that this method
 is optimal in estimating
 DSGE model for small open
 economy. Estimation through
 this technique however
 creates problem of stochastic
 singularity. Therefore,
 additional shocks were
 created to address this
 problem. In the second stage
 estimation is done by
 introducing measurement
 errors.

Czech Republic The empirical analysis of this
 DSGE model is presented in
 terms of calibration strategy
 and impulse-response setup.

United States This DSGE model is
Euro Area estimated by applying the
 VAR framework.

Euro Area This model is estimated by
 utilising the Bayesian
 techniques. As a part of the
 empirical strategy study
 quantifies the structural
 shocks and their contribution
 to business cycle fluctuations.

Country Concluding Remarks

Canada Through this aspect of model
 building study shows with
 sure that the out of sample
 forecasts are relatively more
 appealing than any other
 model in comparison. For
 some of the variables such as
 interest rate and output in fact
 have very good level of
 accuracy in forecasting. The
 forecasting power however for
 inflation is not so strong yet it
 is not significantly less than
 those of the benchmark VARs.
 In the last this study
 introduces several dimensions
 for improvements in the model
 for future work.

Central Europe The estimation results of this
Transition illustrate some differences
Economies from the Euro area results in
 structural parameters.
 However, the results exhibit
 some similarities across
 countries, notably in some
 shocks volatilities and high
 habit formation of
 consumption. The results
 illustrate also an important
 degree of rigidity of imported
 goods prices, which implies a
 low pass-through of the
 exchange rate fluctuations.
 Finally, we study the Ramsey
 optimal allocation, in a
 timeless perspective, of the
 estimated model for each
 country in order to analyse the
 convergence criteria of
 entrance in the European
 exchange rate mechanism

Poland Overall, results of this model
 can be seen as rather
 inconclusive about the
 differences in parameters
 describing agent's decision
 making in Poland and in the
 euro area.

Australia The empirical estimates suggest
 that domestic and foreign demand
 shocks and to some extent the
 domestic supply shocks are the
 most influential in Australian
 business cycle. The effect of real
 exchange rate on output is
 somewhat mild. Inflation appears
 very sensitive to the domestic
 supply shocks. The impact of
 domestic monetary policy
 however on inflation is also mild.

United Kingdom This study finds that the results
 are consistent to policy regime
 changes. These regime changes
 include shifts in the role assigned
 to monetary policy, for example
 policy changes made investment
 decision more closely based on
 the market forces. It also shows
 that price stickiness is more than
 wage stickiness as a major source
 of nominal rigidity in the UK.

Low-Income This paper calls itself the first
Countries attempt at estimating DSGE
 model for SSA country and
 projects it as the benchmark for
 low-income countries. Results
 show that a exchange rate peg is
 significantly less successful than
 inflation targeting at stabilising

 the real economy due to higher
 interest rate volatility.

New Zealand The main empirical findings are;
 a) the intertemporal consumption
 substitutability is very little
 which implies that the New Zealand
 does not produce close substitutes
 of the foreign goods. b) Immobile
 labor force is backed by the low
 elasticity of labor supply
 decisions. c) Price contracts were
 estimated around four quarters for
 import retailers and five quarters
 for domestic producers. e)
 Impulse response functions depict
 the dynamic behavior of shocks
 and the monetary transmission
 mechanism for the rest of
 economy.

Brazil The empirical part of the paper
 yields promising qualitative
 results. The main empirical
 findings are: (i) a higher TOT
 improves its external
 competitiveness, shiffngthe
 world demand towards its
 goods. The consequent higher
 output heats the labor market,
 pushing the real wage and
 marginal cost up. (ii) Ceteris
 paribus, a higher TOT increases
 the real wage and marginal cost
 in terms of the domestic goods,
 leading each firm to adjust its
 nominal price up in order to
 increase its relative price--in
 terms of the other domestic
 good--and thereby preserve
 their markup.

Chile Wages are optimally set with
 the span of eight years while the
 prices of domestic goods take
 several years. Prices of
 imported goods take three
 quarters. Results also depict the
 habit persistence in
 consumption and adjustment
 costs in investment are the
 relevant features. Impulse
 response shows that a
 commodity price shock
 generates soft consumption and
 investment booms and a GDP
 expansion. It also shows a real
 exchange rate appreciation
 lowers inflation and reduces
 employment. It depicts that a
 monetary policy shock
 generates positive responses of
 GDP, consumption and
 investment, and a fall in
 inflation.

Colombia This model show that the policy
 shocks explain only 3.7 percent
 variation in inflation, 2.2
 percent in real exchange rate
 and just 0.1 percent in output.
 The largest source of variation
 comes from the shocks in the
 TFP of the non-traded sector.
 Foreign shocks are also taken
 into account, terms of trade
 account for 62 percent in the
 variation of real exchange rate
 and about third of volatility in
 output, interest rates and
 inflation. It is also discussed
 that the DSGE model outcome
 does not show good degree of
 forecasting ability as compared
 with MTYNO.

Latin America The estimates and the impulse
 response analysis shows that
 during the last two decades
 devolutionary policy shocks
 have been on average
 expansionary, in terms of
 output. It also depict that
 contractionary balance sheet
 transmission mechanism has
 been dominated by the
 expenditure-switching effect.
 While the balance sheet
 transmission mechanism has
 been weaker in Mexico than in
 Chile and Colombia.

Czech Republic This model policy reaction with
 a parameterised forecast
 horizon and a generalised
 capital accumulation equation
 with imperfect intertemporal
 substitution of investment
 provide useful forecast of
 Czech Republic monetary
 policy decision variables.

United States This study instead of some
Euro Area focused conclusion provides
 some choices of inferences by
 showing comparisons of the
 values of priors.

Euro Area This study suggested that there
 is large degree of price and
 wage stickiness in the euro
 area. Model based output and
 interest rate gap show a
 considerable uncertainty around
 it. There is not observed the
 liquidity impact and
 expectations take time to adjust
 and the output effects are much
 smaller.


Authors' Note: Views expressed here are those of the authors and not necessarily of the State Bank of Pakistan or Bond University, Australia. Any errors or omissions in this paper are the responsibility of the authors. The authors are grateful to M. Ali Choudhary for his insightful comments on the earlier draft of this paper. They are also thankful to Macro Ratto, Martin Melecky, Nikolay Iskrev, Philip Liu, Rafael Wouters and Zulfiqar Hyder for their support, guidance and helpful discussions.

REFERENCES

Adolfson, M., S. Laseen, J. Linde, and M. Villani (2007a) RAMSES: A New General Equilibrium Model for Monetary Policy Analysis. Risksbank. Economic Review 2.

Adolfson, M., S. Laseen, J. Linde, and M. Villani (2007b) Bayesian Estimation of an Open Economy DSGE Model with Incomplete Pass-Through. Journal of International Economics 72, 481-511.

Adolfson, M., S. Laseen, J. Linde, and M. Villani (2008) Evaluating an Estimated New Keynesian Small Open Economy Model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32, 2690-2721.

Altug, S. (1989) Time-to-Build and Aggregate Fluctuations: Some New Evidence. International Economic Review 30: 889-920.

An, S., and F. Schorfheide (2007) Bayesian Analysis of DSGE Models. Econometric Reviews 26, 113-172.

Benes, J., T. Hledik, M. Kumhof, and D. Vavra (2005) An Economy in Transition and DSGE: What the Czech National Bank's New Projection Model Needs. Czech National Bank, Research Department. (Working Papers 2005/12).

Bosch, M. (2007) Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Presence of Informal Labour Markets. London School of Economics. (Mimeographed).

Brubakk, L, T. Anders, J. Maih, K. Olsen and M. Ostnor (2006) Finding NEMO: Documentation of the Norwegian Economy Model. Norwegian Central Bank. (Staff Memo No. 2006-6).

Bukhari, S. A. H. A. S. and S. U. Khan (2008) Estimating Output Gap for Pakistan Economy: Structural and Statistical Approaches. State Bank of Pakistan. (Working Paper Series No. 24).

Buncic, D. and M. Melecky (2008) An Estimated New Keynesian Policy Model for Australia. The Economic Society of Australia. The Economic Record 84, 1-16.

Calvo, G. A. (1983) Staggered Price Setting In A Utility-Maximising Framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383-398.

Canova, F. (2002) Validating Two Monetary Models via VARs. (CEPR Working 3442).

Canova, F. (2007) Methods for Applied Macroeconomic Research. Princeton University Press.

Castillo, P., C. Montoro and V. Tuesta (2008) MEGA-D: Modelo de equilibrio general aggregado con dolarizacion parcial para la economia peruana. Central Reserve Bank of Peru. (Forthcoming).

Chisti, U. S. A. Hasan, and S. F. Mahmud (1992) Macroeconometric Modeling and Pakistan's Economy: A Vector Autoregression Approach. Journal of Development Economics 38,353-370.

Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (1997) Sticky Price and Limited Participation Models of Money: A Comparison. European Economic Review 41, 1201-1249.

Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (1998) Monetary Policy Shocks: What have we Learned and to what End? In J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford (eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics. Amsterdam, North-Holland.

Christiano, L. and. M. Eichenbaum (1992) Current Real-Business Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labour-Market Fluctuations. American Economic Review 82, 430-45.

Christiano, L., M. Eichembaum, and C. Evans (2005) Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects to a Shock of Monetary Policy. Journal of Political Economy 113, 1-45.

Christoffel, K., C. Gunter, and W. Anders (2008) NAWM: A Micro-Founded Open-Economy Model for Forecasting and Policy Analysis. (ECB Working Paper No. 944 /October ).

Clarida, R. and M. Gertler (1997) How the Bundesbank Conducts Monetary Policy. Bundesbank. (Memographed).

Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler (1998) Monetary Policy Rules in Practice: Some International Evidence. European Economic Review 42, 1033-1067.

Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler (1999) The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 1661-1707.

Clarida, R., J. Gali and M. Gertler (2000) Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, 147-180.

Colander, D., P. Howwit, A. Kirman, A. Leijonhufvud, and P. Mehrling (2008) Beyond DSGE Models: Toward an Empirically Based Macroeconomics. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 98,236--240.

Copaciu, M. F. Neagu, and H. Braun-Erdei (2005) Survey Evidence on Price Setting Patterns of Romanian Firms. National Bank of Romania. (Mimeographed).

da Silveira, M. A. C. (2006) A Small Open Economy as a Limit Case of a Two-Country New Keynesian DSGE Model: A Bayesian Estimation with Brazilian Data. Instituto de Pesquisa Econ6mica Aplicada. (Discussion Paper No. 1252a).

DeJong, D., B. Ingram, and C. Whiteman (2000) A Bayesian Approach to Dynamic Macroeconomics. Journal of Econometrics 98,201-223.

Dib, A., M. Gammoudi, and K. Moran (2008) Forecasting Canadian Time Series with the New Keynesian Model. Canadian Economics Association. Canadian Journal of Economics 41,138-165.

Dib, A., M. Gammoudi, and K. Moran (2005) Forecasting with the New-Keynesian Model: An Experiment with Canadian Data. Manuscript, Bank of Canada.

DiCecio, R. and Edward Nelson (2007) An Estimated DSGE Model for the United Kingdom. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Review, July Issue, 215-232.

Diebold, F. X. (1998) The Past, Present, and Future of Macroeconomic Forecasting. Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, 175-192.

Dixit, A., and J. Stiglitz (1977) Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity. American Economic Review 67:297-30

Eichenbaum, M. and C. Evans (1995) Some Empirical Evidence on the Effects of Shocks to Monetary Policy on Exchange Rates. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 975-1010.

Erceg, C., L. Guerrieri, and C. Gust (2006) SIGMA: A New Open Economy Model for Policy Analysis. International Journal of Central Banking 2, 111-144.

Fama, E. (1984) Forward and Spot Exchange Rates. Journal of Monetary Economics 14, 319-338

Faust, J. and J. Rogers (2003) Monetary Policy's Role In Exchange Rate Behaviour. Journal of Monetary Economics 50: 1403-1424.

Favero, C. (2001) Applied Macroeconometrics. Oxford University Press.

Froot, K. and J. Frankel (1989) Forward Discount Bias: Is it an Exchange Risk Premium. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 139-161.

Gali, J. (2008) Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework. Princeton University Press.

Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999) Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 195-222.

Gali, J., and M. Gertler (2007) Macroeconomic Modeling for Monetary Policy Evaluation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, Fall Issue.

Gali, J., and T. Monacelli (2005) Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Review of Economic Studies 72, 707-734.

Gelman, A., J. B. Carlin, H. S. Stern, and D. B. Rubin (2006) Bayesian Data Analysis. Second Edition. Text in Statistical Science, Chapman and Hall.

Geweke, J. (1995) Monte Carlo Simulation and Numerical Integration. Federal Reserve Bank of Mineapolis. (Research Department Staff Report 192).

Geweke, J. (1999) Using Simulation Methods for Bayesian Econometric Models: Inference, Development and Communication. Econometric Reviews 18, 1-73.

Goodfriend, M. (2007) How The World Achieved Consensus on Monetary Policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, Fall Issue.

Goodfriend, M. and R. King (1997) The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997.

Gouvea, S., A. Minella, R. Santos, and N. Souza-Sobrinhoy (2008) Samba: Stochastic Analytical Model with a Bayesian Approach. Central Bank Workshop on Macroeconomic Modeling 2008, Banco de la Republica, Colombia. (Workshop Paper).

Griffolio, T. M. (2007) DYNARE User Manual: An Introduction to the Solution and Estimation of DSGE Models. Unpublished Manuscript.

Hamann, F., J. Perez, and D. Rodriguez (2006) Bringing a DSGE Model into Policy Environment in Colombia. Conference Paper, Central Bank of Chile.

Haque, N. U., A. M. Husain, and P. J. Montiel (1994) An Empirical "Dependent Economy" Model for Pakistan. World Development 22, 1585-597.

Harrison, R., K. Nikolov, M. Quinn, G. Ramsay, A. Scott, and R. Thomas (2005) Bank of England Quarterly Model. Bank of England.

Hastings, W. (1970) Monte Carlo Sampling Methods Using Markov Chains and their Applications. Biometrika 57, 97-109.

Ireland, P. N. (2000a) Sticky-Price Models of the Business Cycle: Specification and Stability. (NBER Working Paper 7511).

Ireland, P. N. (2000b) Sticky-Price Models of the Business Cycle: Specification and Stability. (NBER Working Paper 7511).

Ireland, P. N. (2004) Technology Shocks in the New Keynesian Model. (NBER Working Paper No. W10309).

Justiniano, A., and B. Preston (2004) Small Open Economy DSGE Models: Specification, Estimation and Model Fit. Manuscript, Columbia University.

Justiniano, A., B. Preston (2005) Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account for the Influence of Foreign Shocks. Manuscript, Columbia University.

Kemal, A. R. and M. F. Arby (2004) Quarterization of Annual GDP of Pakistan. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. (Statistical Paper Series 05.)

Keynes, J. M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

Kim, J. (2000) Constructing and Estimating a Realistic Optimising Model of Monetary. Journal of Monetary Economics 45,329-359.

Klein, P. (2000) Using the Generalised Schur Form to Solve a Multivariate Linear Rational Expectations Model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24, 1405-1423.

Kolasa, M. (2008) Structural Heterogeneity or Asymmetric Shocks? Poland and the Euro Area Through the Lens of a Two-Country DSGE Model. National Bank of Poland. (Working Paper No. 49).

Koop, G., D. J. Poirier, and J. L. Tobias (2007) Bayesian Econometric Methods. Cambridge University Press.

Kwapil, C., J. Baumgartner and J. Scharler (2005) The Price-Setting Behavior of Austrian Firms Some Survey Evidence. European Central Bank. (Working Paper Series No. 464).

Kydland, F. E. and E. C. Prescott (1996) The Computational Experiment: An Econometric Tool. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, Winter Issue.

Kydland, F. E., and E. C. Prescott (1982) Time to Build And Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 50, 1345-370.

Laforte, J. P. (2004) Comparing Monetary Policy Rules in an Estimated General Equilibrium Model of the U.S. Economy. Federal Reserve Board of Governors. (Memographed).

Lancaster, T. (2004) An Introduction to Modern Bayesian Econometrics. Blackwell Publishing.

Landon-Lane, J. (1998) Bayesian Comparison of Dynamic Macroeconomic Models. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Minnesota.

Laxton, D. (2008) Getting to Know the Global Economy Model and its Philosophy. IMF Staff Papers 55, 213-242.

Leeper, E., and C. Sims (1994) Toward a Modern Macroeconomic Model Usable for Policy Analysis. In Stanley Fischer and Julio Rotemberg (eds.) NBER Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press.

Liu, P. (2006) A Small New Keynesian Model of the New Zealand Economy. Reserve Bank of New Zealand. (Discussion Paper Series, No. 03/06).

Lubik, T. and F. Schorfheide (2005) A Bayesian Look at New Open Economy Macroeconomics. In M. Gertler, and K. Rogoff, (eds.) NBER Macroeconomics Annual 313- 336.

Lucas, J. R. (1976) Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In K. Brunner and A. Meltzer (eds.) The Phillips Curve and Labour Markets. North Holland.

Lucas, J. R. and T. J. Sargent (1979) After Keynesian Macroeconomics. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Quarterly Review 3, 1-16.

Malik, W. S. and A. M. Ahmed (2007) The Taylor Rule and the Macroeconomic Performance in Pakistan. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Pakistan. (Working Paper Series No. 2007:34).

Mankiw, G. N. (1985) Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeconomic Model of Monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 529-539.

Mankiw, G. N. (1989) Real Business Cycle: A New Keynesian Perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, 79-90.

Mankiw, G. N. (1990) A Quick Refresher Course in Macroeconomics. Journal of Economic Literature 28, 1645-1660.

Mankiw, G. N. (2006) The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall Issue 20, 29-461.

Mankiw, G. N. and D. Romer (1990) New Keynesian Economics. Boston: MIT Press.

McCarthy, F. D. and L. Taylor (1980) Macro Food Policy Planning: A General Equilibrium Model for Pakistan. Review of Economics and Statistics 62, 107-121.

McGrattan, E. (1994) The Macroeconomic Effects of Distortionary Taxation. Journal of Monetary Economics 33,573-601.

Medina, J. and C. Soto (2007) The Chilean Business Cycle Through the Lens of a Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Central Bank of Chile. (Working Papers No. 457).

Medina, J. P. and C. Soto. (2006) Model for Analysis and Simulations: A Small Open Economy DSGE for Chile. Conference Paper, Central Bank of Chile.

Monacelli, T. (2003) Monetary Policy in a Low Pass-through Environment. European Central Bank. (Working Paper No. 227).

Murchison, S. and A. Rennison (2006) TOTEM: The Bank of Canada's New Quarterly Projection Model. Bank of Canada, (Technical Report No. 97).

Naqvi, S. N. H. and A. M. Ahmed (1986) Preliminary Revised P.I.D.E. Macroeconometric Model of Pakistan's Economy. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.

Naqvi, S. N. H., A. M. Ahmed, et al. (1983) The P1DE Macroeconometric Model of Pakistan's Economy. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.

Negro, M. D., F. Schorfheide, F. Smets, and R. Wouters (2005) On the Fit and Forecasting Performance of New-Keynesian Models. European Central Bank. (Working Paper Series 491).

Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff (2002) New Directions for Stochastic Open Economy Models. Journal of International Economics 50, 117-153.

Omer, M. and O. F. Saqib (2008) Monetary Targeting in Pakistan: A Skeptical Note. State Bank of Pakistan. (Working Paper Series No. 25).

Onatski, A. and N. Williams (2004) Empirical and Policy Performance of a Forward-Looking Monetary Model. Princeton University. (Mimeographed).

Otrok, C. (2001) On Measuring the Welfare Cost of Business Cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 47, 61-92.

Pasha, H. A., M. A. Hasan, A. G. Pasha, Z. H. Ismail, A. Rasheed, M. A. Iqbal, R. Ghaus, A. R. Khan, N. Ahmed, N. Bano, and N. Hanif (1995) Integrated Social Policy and Macro-Economic Planning Model for Pakistan. Social Policy and Development Center, Karachi. (Research Report, No. 7).

Peiris, S. J. and M. Saxegaard (2007) An Estimated DSGE Model for Monetary Policy Analysis in Low-Income Countries. (IMF Working Paper No. 07/282).

Pesenti, E. (2008) The Global Economy Model: Theoretical Framework. IMF Staff Papers 55,243-284.

Prescott, E. (1986) Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Quarterly Review Fall, 9-22.

Ratto, M. (2007) Analysing DSGE models with Global Sensitivity Analysis. Computational Economics 31, 115-139.

Ratto, M., W. Roeger, J. in 't Veld (2008) QUEST III: An Estimated Open-economy DSGE Model of the Euro Area with Fiscal And Monetary Policy. Economic Modeling. (Forthcoming Issue).

Romer, C. and D. Romer (1997) Reducing Inflation. NBER and University of Chicago Press.

Romer, D. (1993) The New Keynesian Synthesis. American Economic Association, Journal of Economic Perspectives 7, 5-22.

Romer, D. (2006) Advanced Macroeconomics. Third Edition. New York: Graw-Hill.

Ruge-Murcia, F. (2003) Methods to Estimate Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Models. Cahier 17-2003.

Sadeq, T. (2008) Bayesian Estimation of a DSGE Model and Optimal Monetary Policy for Central Europe Transition Countries. EPEE, Universite d.Evry Val d.Essonne. (Memographed).

Sargent, T. J., and N. Wallace (1975) Rational Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule. Journal of Political Economy 83, 241-254.

Schmidtt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe (2003) Closing Small Open Economy Models. Journal of International Economics 61,163-185.

Schorfheide, F. (2000) Loss Function Based Evaluation of DSGE Models. Journal of Applied Econometrics 15,645-670.

Siddiqui, R. and A. R. Kemal (2006) Poverty-reducing or Poverty-Inducing? A CGE-based Analysis of Foreign Capital Inflow in Pakistan. PIDE, Islamabad, Pakistan. (PIDE Working Paper No. 2).

Siddiqui, R. and Z. Iqbal (1999) Social Accounting Matrix of Pakistan for 1989-90. PIDE, Islamabad. (Research Report Series No. 171).

Siddiqui, R. and Z. Iqbal (2001) Tariff Reduction and Functional Income Distribution in Pakistan: A CGE Approach", PIDE, Islamabad, Pakistan. (MIMAP Technical Paper Series, No. 10).

Sims, C. (1996) Macroeconomics and Methodology. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 105-120.

Sims, C. (2002) Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models. Computational Economics 20, 1-20.

Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2003) Monetary Policy in an Estimated Stochastic Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1, 1123-1175.

Taylor, J. (1993) Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice. North-Holland, Amsterdam Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 39, 195-214.

Taylor, J. B. (1980) Aggregate Dynamics And Staggered Contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88, 1-23.

Taylor, J. B. (1998) Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomics. In J. B. Taylor, and M. Woodford (eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics. Amsterdam, North-Holland.

Taylor, J. B. (1999) Monetary Policy Rules. Chicago: NBER and University of Chicago Press.

Tovar, E. C. (2005) The Mechanics of Devaluations and the Output Response in a DSGE Model: How Relevant is the Balance Sheet Effect? Bank for International Settlements. (BIS Working Papers No. 192).

Tovar, E. C. (2008) DSGE Models and Central Banks. Bank for International Settlements. (BIS Working Paper No. 258.)

Uhlig, H. (1999) A Toolkit for Analysing Nonlinear Dynamic Stochastic Models Easily. In Ramon Marimom and Adrian Scott (eds.) Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies. Oxford University Press.

Woodford, M. (2004) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press.

Yun, T. (1996) Nominal Price Rigidity, Money Supply Endogeneity and Business Cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 37,345-370.

Adnan Haider <adnan.haider@sbp.org.pk> is affiliated with Economic Modeling Division, Research Department, State Bank of Pakistan, Karachi. Safdar Ullah Khan <skhan@bond.edu.au> is affiliated with Faculty of Business, Technology and Sustainable Developmen t, Bond University Australia.

(1) Well known DSGE models developed by most of ,the central banks and international policy institutions as noted by Tovar (2008) are (a) Bank of Canada ('TotEM), (b) Bank of England (BEQM), (c) Central bank of Brazil (SAMBA), (d) Central bank of Chile (MAS), (e) Central bank of Peru (MEGA-D), (f) European Central bank (NAWM), (g) Norges Bank (NEMO), (h) S veriges Riksbank (RAMSES), (i) US Federal Reserve (SIGMA) and (j) IMF (GEM and GIMF). A bird's eye vie w of various country specific DSGE models is also provided in Table C 1 of Appendix-C.

(2) For recent contributions that estimate small open economies, see Adolfson, et al. (2008), Dib, et al. (2008), Justiniano and Preston (2004), Liu (2006) and Lubik and Schortheide (2005).

(3) In macroeconomic literature, the terms "new-Keynesian" or "new neoclassical synthesis" are being used synonymously; see, Clarida, Gali and Getler (1999), Gali and Getler (2007), Goodfriend (2007), Goodfriend and King (1997), Mankiw (2006) and Romer (1993).

(4) Lucas (1976) and Lucas and Sargent (1979 argue that if private agents behave according to a dynamic optimisation approach and use available information rationally, they should respond to economic policy announcements by adjusting their supposedly behavior. Hence reduced form parameter results are subject to Lucas critique. But, DSGE models are based on optimising agents; deep parameters of these models are therefore less susceptible to this critique.

(5) Christanio, et al. (2005) and Smets and Wouters (2003) argued that endogenous persistence mechanism, such as habit formation and price indexation, must be added to the basic DSGE model in order to reproduced the observed output and inflation persistence.

(6) See, for instance; Kwapil, et al. (2005), Copaciu, et al. (2005), and Bosch (2007).

(7) For detail description, see Table AI of Appendix A.

(8) Using Global Sensitivity Analysis (GSA) toolkit, we computed model parameter stability estimates, which are also provided in the Appendix-B of this paper.

(9) Each household lives in one of two countries, individual defined on the interval, i [member of] [0, n] lives in the home-country, and remaining on the interval i [member of] [0, n] lives in the foreign-country. The value of n measures the relative size of the home-country.

(10) We do not include real money balances (M/P) into our utility function. Because DSGE models assume nominal short-term interest rate as the monetary policy instrument, so that money supply is considered as endogenous; see for instance, Woordford (2003). In the case of Pakistan, this critical assumption also holds as a recent empirical study by Omer and Saqib (2008) argue that money supply in Pakistan is endogenous.

(11) It also shows habit persistence parameter to reproduce observed output, rages from 0 [less than or equal to] h [less than or equal to] 1.

(12) In terms of this discount factor, the riskless short term nominal interest rate [R.sub.t] corresponds to the solution to the equation: 1/[R.sub.t] = [E.sub.t] ([Q.sub.t t+1]).

(13) [Q.sub.t t+1] remains a stochastic variable at time t, and [E.sub.t] denotes expectations conditional upon the state of the world at time t.

(14) To drive, FOCS from objective function subject to budget constraint, it is assumed that inverse of wage elasticity of labour supply is zero.

(15) [[theta].sub.t], firms adjust prices according to steady state inflation rate [[pi].sub.t]. This notion introduces inflation persistence by allowing for price indexation to previous inflation.

(16) The degree of price stickiness is assumed to be same as the fraction of past inflation indexation. The reason of this crude assumption is that it validates a basic rationale of Phillips curve. "In the long-run Phillips Curve is vertical", see for instance, Gali and Gertler (1999).

(17) In the limiting case with no price rigidities (say, [theta] = 0), the previous condition collapses to the familiar optimal price-setting condition under flexible prices. See., Gali (2008).

(18) If PPP holds, then l.o.p gap is translated into [[psi].sub.F,t] = 1. This implies that pass-through from exchange rate movements to the domestic currency prices of imports is imperfect as importers adjust their pricing behaviour to extract optimal revenue from consumers. See, Monacelli (2005).

(19) These fixed parameters are also known as stick priors in Bayesian sense.

(20) For US economy price stickiness parameter value is also taken as 0.5, see for instance Lubik and Schorfiede (2005).

(21) http://eemc.jrc.ec.europa.eu//softwareDYNARE-Dowload.htm

(22) The impulse responses to a one unit increase in the various structural shocks are calculated using 10,000 random draws from the posterior distribution of the model parameters. Initially we draw posterior distributions using 1.5 million Markov chains. But for impulse responses we use only limited random draws due to computational complexity.

(23) In this case, the monetary authority can afford to loosen monetary policy to bring inflation back to zero.

(24) As inflation dynamics modeled with the New Keynesian Philips Curve, so this shock is also considered as a supply shock.

(25) Adolfson, et al. (2008) noted that the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) condition is a key equation in open economy DSGE models. It shows the difference between domestic and foreign nominal interest rates equals the expected future change in the nominal exchange rate. The UIP condition is a key equation in open economy models not only for the exchange rate but also for many macroeconomic variables, since there is a lot of internal propagation of exchange rate movements working through fluctuating relative prices. There is, however, strong empirical evidence against the standard UIP condition, see for instance, e.g., Eichenbaum and Evans, (1995); Faust and Rogers, (2003). Moreover, a DSGE model with a standard UIP condition cannot account for the so-called 'forward premium puzzle' recorded in the data, i.e. that a currency whose interest rate is high tends to appreciate which implies that the risk premium must be negatively correlated with the expected exchange rate depreciation see, e.g., Fama, (1984); Froot and Frankel (1989).

(26) Figure A4 of Appendix-A, plots the residuals of uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) condition generated from Pakistan's data by utilising theory based and regression based methodologies, see, Lubik and Schorfeide (2005) for further detail. This figure also provides a historical description of monetary expansion and tightness in the case of surge and decline in UIP. The recent negative values of UIP show the tight monetary policy stance which is in line with the standard macroeconomic theory.

(27) The foreign sector economy consists of two main Equations; (a) output and (b) real interest rate as a proxy of foreign monetary policy instrument. This sector is assumed to be completely exogenous to the small open economy, Pakistan.

(28) Any other method can also be used to solve the log-linear approximation to the rational expectations solution, e.g., Sims (2002).
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有