Inter-city variation in prices.
Ahmad, Sonia ; Gulzar, Ahmed
In this paper we have constructed a relative cost of living index
for 32 cities/towns of Pakistan using latest available prices to
understand the extent of current differences in cost of living across
cities and also to compare changes in relative cost of living since 1999
[Pasha and Pasha (2002)]. The index values reveal significant
differences in cost of living across Pakistan and especially across
provinces with prices significantly higher in Baiochistan (overall) and
NWFP (for wheat). When regressed against various explanatory variables,
the variation in cost of living appears to be determined by the
population in cubic form (reaching a minimum for a city size of 2.1
million) and the provincial affiliation of cities. The index also
reveals that relative to 1999, the economy as a whole appears to have
become less integrated as the difference in prices across cities is much
greater than in 1999. However, cities in Sindh due to their close
proximity to the port have become less expensive because of the
increased share of imports in consumption. The findings of this paper
have very important implications for public policy with respect to
transfer payments to relieve poverty, urban development,
inter-provincial trade and transport and allocation of development funds
among provinces.
JEL classification: R, R1, R11
Keywords: Regional Economics Measurement, Regional Economic
Activity, Growth, Development, and Changes
INTRODUCTION
This research has been motivated by the fact that inter-city
variation in prices and hence cost of living has implications for many
aspects of development and public policy. This is true for all countries
and especially for developing countries like Pakistan where one would
expect differences in cost of living to be more pronounced (ceterus
paribus) due to a relatively underdeveloped transport network and a lack
of development of a national common market.
A better understanding of the inter-city variation in prices
indicates the extent to which markets within countries are integrated. A
monitoring of the inter-city price index over time indicates whether the
economy as a whole has become more or less integrated over time i.e. has
there has been convergence or divergence within the local economy (which
has also been one of the objectives of this research).
Secondly, a quantification of inter-city variation in cost of
living is essential to understand differentials in real incomes across
the country. Such an understanding will yield fairer minimum wage
legislation by the government and also wage remuneration packages by
employers in both the public and private sectors operating in multiple
cities thus leading to better equalisation of real wages across
locations. As noted by Haworth and Rasmussen (1973) the pursuit of a
uniform wage policy by the U.S. Post Office in the 1970s led to greater
wage dissatisfaction among workers and labor strikes in areas where cost
of living was relatively higher.
Thirdly, allowing for cost of living differentials among cities
will lead to better estimates of urban inequality and incidence of
poverty. In this context it is particularly important to see if
differences in cost of living mitigate or accentuate the difference in
the magnitude of poverty between richer and poor jurisdictions.
The estimation of cost of living differentials will also lead to
much greater understanding of migration patterns within countries and
the functioning of regional and interregional markets across the country
which are directly related to cost of living, and real wages/incomes.
For example, if the same minimum wage legislation is applicable to the
whole country, it will lead to migration to those cities where cost of
living is relative low and hence the real value of the minimum wages is
high (ceterus paribus). This illustrates the important implications that
uniform minimum wage legislation and welfare packages across the country
have for migration patterns when cost of living differentials are
significant.
Finally, inter-city variation in prices has important implications
for understanding 'optimal' city size and future urban
planning and public policy affecting the pattern of urban development
within the country. It is generally believed that cost of living tends
to first fall as city size increases due to emergence of agglomeration economies but as population increases diseconomies of scale and negative
externalities like traffic congestion, high land rents and pollution set
in that exceed the potential agglomeration economies. The issue then is
discovering the 'optimal' city size at which cost of living is
at a minimum.
REVIEW OF LITERATURE
Pasha and Pasha (2002) conducted a research on cost of living
differentials in Pakistan by calculating a relative price index for 25
cities in Pakistan. They found significant differentials in cost of
living with the maximum difference in cost of living equaling 15 percent
(between Karachi, the largest metropolis and Jhang, a relatively small
town located in Punjab). They set up a model to explain cost of living
differentials among locations in Pakistan and found that cost of living
is explained primarily by population (in cubic form) and per capita incomes. Higher per capita incomes lead to higher cost of living and as
population increases cost of living first increases then decreases and
then increases again. Other variables such as provincial dummies and
distance from national highway emerged as insignificant.
Cebula (1980) constructed a model to estimate the determinants of
cost of living differences in the United States. He found cost of living
to be a positive function of population density (the number of persons
per square mile) because greater congestion will increase transit and
marketing costs; a negative function of population as increased
population will lead to agglomeration economies which will decrease
production costs and hence cost of living; a negative function of
property tax/tax on capital as it will lead to bias towards labor
intensive technology and hence the potential benefits of economies of
scale will not be realised and also tax might be passed on from
producers to consumers in the form of higher prices; a negative
relationship with a dummy for legislation prohibiting trade union
activity--will lead to lower costs of production and hence lower prices.
Ostrosky (1983) also tries to explain cost of living differentials
in the United States by modifying Cebula's model. Instead of using
a dummy for legislation prohibiting trade union activity, he uses direct
data on the percentage of unionised labour force. Also, he argues that
use of this dummy may actually be leading to a misspecification with
this dummy capturing the impact of differences in climate because most
of the warmer states (by chance) restrict union activity. Warmer states
will have a lower demand for fuels and hence lower prices and a lower
cost of living. He thus includes per capita annual utility bills to
account for this impact in the model.
Haworth and Rasmussen (1973) also constructed a model to explain
cost of living differentials for three different income baskets in the
US. They hypothesise that cost of living is a positive function of
population; a positive function of form/barrier score (the higher the
barrier score, the greater the topological and physical constraints that
limit the expansion of city; (i) a negative function of region--a dummy
for the southeastern states where cost of labor is lower; a positive
function of change in population between 1967 and 1970 because of the
inflationary impact of rapid population increases on prices; and a
positive function of climate/temperature with extremes in either
direction leading to higher fuel consumption. They find that population,
form and region emerge as significant for all budget categories. Climate
is insignificant for all categories and change in population emerges as
significant in the moderate budget equation probably because of scarcity of moderately priced houses.
Henderson (1999) estimated the relationship between housing prices
and commuting times with respect to metro area populations for a
cross-section of 80-90 cities worldwide and finds that housing prices
and commuting times are more than 100 percent higher in a metro area of
5 million people compared to one with a population of 100,000.
Similarly, Rousseau (1995) found that costs of living are about 90
percent higher in Paris at 9 million people than in a typical French
city. These differentials for cost of living have also been found in
other studies for the USA and Brazil [Henderson (1998)] and some other
countries in Latin America [Thomas (1980)]. (1)
Also Langsten, Ramussen, and Simmons (1985) argue that another
explanation for the relationship between city size and the relative cost
of living can be embedded in 'rent' theory. The higher cost of
living in large cities is the result of higher house/land rents and
hence higher land values rather than congestion (although higher land
values may indirectly be the result of higher congestion in some cases).
Thus summarising, previous studies on cost of living differentials
illustrate that urban cost of living can be influenced primarily by one
or more of the following:
Population size--agglomeration economies (+)
Population density--congestion (-)
Per capita income (+)
Land values (+)
Property taxes--high production and living costs (+)
Geographical and provincial/state variations. Also, as noted by
Pasha and Pasha (1999) there is likely to be a very ambiguous
relationship between city size and cost of living, with land values and
congestion costs increasing as city size increases, exerting an upward
influence on cost of living whereas agglomeration economies tend to keep
costs of living relatively low. Pasha and Pasha (2002) use the following
Figure 1 to illustrate these influences on cost of living as city size
increases.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
METHODOLOGY AND DATA
The following methodology and data were used to derive the results:
[P.sub.ij] = retail price of commodity/service j in location i
[Q.sub.j] = share in household consumption nationally of
commodity/service j
[P.sup.*]j = average national price of commodity / service j
[N.sub.i] = population of location i
[I.sub.ij] = index value/relative price of commodity j in city i
[I.sub.ci] = composite cost of living index for city i.
The first step was to calculate the average national price for all
the commodities (for all 32 cities in the sample) using the following
formula:
[P.sup.*]j = [[summation over (i)][N.sub.i][P.sub.ij]/[[summation
over (i)][N.sub.i]
Then relative prices/index values for every commodity in every city
were computed using the following formula:
[I.sub.ij] = [P.sub.ij]/[P.sup.*]j
We then used the relative prices of commodities in every city to
construct a weighted relative composite cost of living index
([I.sub.ci]) for every city:
[I.sub.ci] = [summation over j][I.sub.ji] x [Q.sub.j]
We used the latest (March-April 2008) prices of 133 commodities
from the Monthly Bulletin of Statistics of the Federal Bureau of
Statistics for 32 cities/towns of Pakistan. Out of these cities sixteen
are from Punjab, six are from Sindh, five from NWFP and four from
Balochistan. The data on share in household consumption of commodity j
has been taken from the latest Household Integrated Economic Survey
2005-06. Population figures for the cities have been taken from the
Population Census of 1998.
Evaluation of Results
Overall Trend
The results presented in Table 1 indicate that there are
significant differences in cost of living across Pakistan with the
maximum difference in cost of living equaling 25 percent between Mirpur
Khas (with a population of 250,000) which has an index value of 90.12
and Turbat (with a population of 90,000) having the maximum index value
of 112.15. It is interesting to note that the cost of living is not at a
maximum in the bigger metropolis like Karachi or Lahore but rather in
one of the smallest towns in our sample.
For the food and beverages category, the maximum difference in cost
of living equals 40 percent with the minimum index value recorded for
Dera Ismail Khan and the maximum for Turbat. The low index value of food
items in D. I. Khan is primarily due to very low prices for milk and
milk products, spices, fruits, vegetables, chicken and meat and
relatively low prices for almost all major food items (except for wheat
which is slightly above national average) probably due to sufficient
localised production of these items.
The maximum cost of living index value for Turbat can potentially
be attributed to a lot of varying factors such as the small size of the
city (preventing it from benefiting from economies of scale),
area/provincial bias, and the remoteness of the city. With respect to
Mirpur Khas its low cost of living can be attributed to its locational
advantage/provincial actor, being part of Sindh, enabling it to have
better access to imports and also to the relatively fertile land making
up a major portion of the city allowing for high production of
agricultural items and rearing of livestock. The fact that prices for
wheat, lentils, gur, fruits, vegetables, meat and chicken etcetera for
the city are among the lowest for the sample tends to support the latter
explanation. Also, one of the factors that could be the reason for its
lower cost of living relative to Turbat could be its larger size.
However, given prior literature on optimal city size with respect to
cost of living one would hardly expect a population size of 250,000 to
fully realise the potential benefits of agglomeration economies as a
'medium sized' city in Pakistan will have a population far
greater than 250,000. Thus, one may conclude that the low cost of living
in Mirpur Khas can be attributed to a great extent to its provincial and
geographical advantage.
Construction of the overall index also reveals extreme variation in
the costs of education across the city with the education index having a
standard deviation of as much as 50. This has very important
implications for regional development and 'inclusive growth'
as human capital formation through education is widely recognised to be
one of the major drivers for development.
Provincial Influence on Cost of Living Variations
As noted earlier Turbat's high cost of living could be due to
the provincial factor. Table 2 below gives the (weighted) average
provincial index values for overall cost of living, food and beverage index and the wheat index.
One can see from the above table that prices are more than nine
percent above the national average in Balochistan followed by Islamabad
whereas prices in Punjab and NWFP are just marginally above the national
average and those for Sindh are below the national average. The overall
low prices in Sindh could be due to better access to imports due to the
close proximity to port whereas as high prices in Balochistan could be
indicative of the lack of integration of Balochistan with the rest of
the economy.
For the food and beverages category, prices are significantly
higher than the national average in Islamabad and Balochistan whereas
prices in NWFP and Sindh are marginally above national average and those
in Punjab are marginally below the national average for this category.
The province-wise average for wheat is the most interesting with
prices in NWFP and Balochistan being almost 9 percent above the national
average, marginally above national average for Sindh and below national
average for Islamabad and Punjab (1 percent and 2.85 percent
respectively) implying that there might be some controls on the
inter-provincial movement of wheat from the main wheat growing provinces
of Punjab and Sindh although higher prices in NWFP and Balochistan can
also be the result of higher transportation costs.
Relationship between City Size and Cost of Living Variations
There appears to be a polynomial relationship between cost of
living and city size as Figure 2 below illustrates. Cost of living first
tends to rise as city size increases to about 9,0,000 after which it
starts to fall reaching a minimum for a city with a population of about
350,000 and then starts to rise reaching a maximum for a city the size
of 1.7 million after which cost of living starts to fall again. As noted
earlier, however, we cannot conclude from this analysis that optimal
city size is given by a population of 350,000 as the index values are
influenced by the political affiliation of the cities.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The polynomial relationship can be explained by our previous
discussion on the relationship between city size and cost of living (p.
7). Initially, as population increases land costs increase resulting in
a rise in the cost of living. However, as population increases further,
agglomeration economies set in that further outweigh the increase in the
cost of land and we see costs falling significantly till we reach a
population of 0.3 million after which they begin to rise again as costs
of congestion because of higher population density outweigh the cost
reducing effect of agglomeration economies. The final dip that we see in
our graph can perhaps be attributed to the fact that once a city reaches
the population size of 5-6 million, the agglomeration economies are so
great that they tend to outweigh congestion costs.
It must be noted, however, that the above curve is not independent
of the provincial affiliation/geographical location of the cities and
the final dip that we see in the curve may well be due to the relatively
low cost of living in Karachi attributable to its proximity to the port
(as we will discuss later). However, the polynomial relationship between
population and relative cost of living works very well even when we
isolate the 'provincial affiliation' influence by regressing
relative cost of living against population in polynomial form and
provincial dummies.
Determinants of Cost of Living Variations
Given our analysis of the constructed index, we constructed a model
to explain determinants of cost of living variations using the following
explanatory variables:
Population (P): Given our previous analysis of the relationship
between population and city size, we include this variable as a
third-degree polynomial.
Provincial Dummy Variables: Provincial dummy variables have been
set up for Sindh (D1), NWFP (D2) and Balochistan (D3). Punjab is the
benchmark variable.
We would have ideally liked to have included per capita income to
control for quality differences between similar goods consumed in
various cities on the basis of the assumption that the quality of goods
is better in cities with a higher per capita income and hence they are
also more highly priced. Unfortunately, data for this category was not
available.
We also tried testing for the relationship between cost of living
and distance of the city from the national highway, and distance of the
city from the nearest international border but they came out to be
extremely insignificant and were consequently dropped from the final
model.
The regressions results for the above specified explanatory
variables against overall index, food and beverage index and wheat index
are given in Table 3.
The explanatory variable of population (in millions) in polynomial
form works well for all categories except for food and beverages where
[X.sup.3] does not come out to be significant. Similarly in the overall
category the dummy for Sindh has a negative coefficient (as expected
from our analysis of data) and is significant at the 1 percent level
implying that cost of living in Sindh is less relative to Punjab.
Similarly D3 or the Balochistan dummy has a negative coefficient and is
significant at the 5 percent level implying overall cost of living is
higher in Balochistan than in Punjab. The provincial dummy for NWFP,
however, is insignificant for this category.
Similarly, for the food and beverage category only the provincial
dummy for Balochistan is significant (at the 1 percent level) implying
that prices for food items are significantly above those in Punjab. For
the wheat index category, the NWFP and
Balochistan dummies are both highly significant implying that the
wheat prices are significantly high in these provinces relative to
Punjab whereas the Sindh dummy is insignificant implying that price of
wheat in Sindh is not significantly different from that in Punjab.
The [R.sup.2] for the overall index and the food and beverage index
is relatively low whereas that for the wheat index is quite high. The
low [R.sup.2] in the former may be due to the non-inclusion of per
capita income to account for variations in quality.
Also if we optimise the overall regression equation with respect to
population we find that the cost of living reaches a minimum for a city
with a population of 2.13 million (approx) implying that the cities
targeted for future urban development should be ones with populations
close to 2 million.
Change in Relative Cost of Living Index Over Time
Convergence or Divergence?
A major conclusion of this research has been that there has been
divergence in the economy or that the economy as a whole has become less
integrated since 1999 when Pasha and Pasha (2002) computed a similar
cost of living index for major cities in Pakistan (2) as standard
deviation for the overall index, food and beverage index, apparel and
footwear, and rent has increased. Only for the fuel and lighting
subcategory has standard deviation decreased possibly due to
standardisation of fuel (petrol and diesel) prices across the country
that constitute a major component of this category. This divergent trend
is indicated in Figure 3 below.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Change in Cost of Living Rankings
To compare the change in the relative index values of cities
relative to their 1999 values, the Spearman's Rank Correlation test
(3) was used. A highly significant correlation coefficient value of -0.7
was derived implying that relative to 1999, cities with a relatively
high cost of living index have now become cheaper. This is especially
true for cities in Sindh such as Karachi, Hyderabad, Nawabshah, Larkana
and Mirpur Khas--their ranking in terms of cost of living have fallert
significantly relative to 1999. This change could be attributed to
perhaps a greater share of imported items in consumption especially food
which is reflected in lower prices for Sindh cities due to better access
to imports.
We tested this hypothesis by running a regression of a change in
average annual inflation rates (4) against the distance from port for 21
cities (those that correspond to the sample used by Pasha and Pasha) and
got the results presented in Table 4.
The regression results indicate that the coefficient of distance
from port is positive and significant at the 1 percent level, implying
that average annual inflation rate for cities is less the less the
distance from the port.
Data Limitations
It is worthwhile to note here that for the gas prices component
within the 'fuel and lighting' category, prices were
unavailable for eight cities in our sample (including all cities in
Balochistan excluding Quetta) presumably because there is no gas supply
to these cities implying significant differences in standard of living
not captured by the cost of living index (gas cylinder prices were used
as a proxy).
It is important to note at this point that there might be a bias in
the rent index values as the data available in the Monthly Bulletin of
Statistics was not the actual rental values but the rent index
values--i.e., how much the rent values had changed over and above the
base year values of 2000. Although rent index values can be used as a
proxy for actual rents, rent index values can be biased as they suggest
that two cities with identical index values have the same rents whereas
this only implies that the increase in rents in the two cities has been
similar and that there might have been significant variations in base
year values of rents in these cities.
Policy Implications
Firstly, there appears to have been a decrease in national economic
integration in the last nine years evident in the significant increase
in the standard deviation of cost of living compared to 1999 values and
very high index values for Balochistan especially relative to the other
provinces. This has huge political and economic policy implications as
it implies that federal policy towards the provinces is inequitable and
hence a need for revising policy with respect to development expenditure
allocation among provinces. The stance on wheat policy in Punjab also
needs to be revised in this context (why then should not Balochistan
impose a ban on inter-provincial movement of gas !).
Secondly, the fact that the cost of living in Turbat is 12 percent
above the national overall average and 24 percent above the national
average for the food and beverage category, the welfare payments made by
the government through the Benazir Income Support Programme, for
example, should be adjusted to account for cost of living differences
otherwise they will lead to a very unfair distribution of funds. This is
especially true since Turbat is a very underdeveloped and remote area
with a high incidence of poverty such that the difference in cost of
living compared to the national average is closer to 25 percent rather
than 12 percent as a major share of the income of the poor is spent on
food (much greater than the average expenditure of 35 percent of total
income).
Thirdly, there appear to be huge disparities in cost of education
across the country and hence the need to standardise cost of education
to achieve inclusive and uniform growth across the country.
Fourthly, there appears to be a need for developing a more
efficient transport network to minimise transport distances from the
port to the rest of the country and hence minimise cost of living in
other parts of the country given that imports constitute a significant
portion of overall consumption.
Lastly, the fact that the most efficient city size in
Pakistan's context appears to be a medium sized city with a
population of about 2 million, urban development focus should shift from
the development of (inefficient) large sized metropolis such as Karachi
and Lahore and should concentrate on the development on relatively
smaller cities like Gujranwala, Rawalpindi, Multan, Hyderabad and the
like.
CONCLUSION
The computation and analysis of relative index values for cities
across Pakistan indicates that there are huge differences in cost of
living across cities (with deviation in prices reaching a maximum for
education) and also across provinces and these differences in cost of
living have increased over time. Thus, knowledge of these cost of living
variations is essential when formulating public policy with respect to
allocation of development expenditure among provinces, income support
and consumer subsidy programmes, inter-provincial and cross-country
movement of goods and urban development.
Appendices
Appendix 1
City Size and Relative Index Values
Population 2008 * Overall
City (Millions) Index Value
Loralai 0.03 1.00
Bannu 0.05 1.00
Abbotabad 0.06 1.05
Attock 0.07 0.98
Turbat 0.09 1.12
Mianwali 0.10 1.05
D. I. Khan 0.11 0.98
Khuzdar 0.12 0.98
Vehari 0.12 1.03
Bahawal Nagar 0.14 1.04
Jhelum 0.17 1.04
Nawab Shah 0.24 0.95
Mirpur Khas 0.25 0.90
D.G Khan 0.25 0.93
Okara 0.26 0.93
Mardan 0.32 0.97
Larkana 0.35 0.92
Jhang 0.38 0.94
Sukker 0.43 0.97
Bhawalpur 0.53 1.06
Sialkot 0.54 0.97
Sargodha 0.59 0.97
Islamabad 0.68 1.07
Quetta 0.73 1.11
Peshawar 1.27 1.01
Gujranwala 1.46 1.04
Hyderabad 1.51 0.95
Multan 1.55 1.09
Rawalpindi 1.82 1.02
Faisalabad 2.60 1.06
Lahore 6.65 1.00
Karachi 12.07 0.99
* Population in 2008 was estimated by the following formula;
Population in 2008 = Population in 1998 (1 + average growth rate
of urban population) (10)
Growth rate of urban population: (urban Polwlation in time
Lsjeriod t)--(urban population in time t-1) (Urban population in
time period t-1)
Average growth rate of urban population was estimated over the
period 2000-2005.
Appendix 2
Relative Cost of Living Index in 1999
National Average = 1000
Food and Apparel Fuel and
Province Population Beverages and Lighting
City * ** (000) Footwear
Karachi S 108.23 103.64 99.39
Lahore P 94.46 89.96 102.61
Faisalabad P 96.78 103.70 101.69
Rawalpindi P 100.19 98.54 104.23
Hyderabad S 100.98 102.03 96.74
Multan P 96.16 111.86 100.92
Gujranwala P 90.80 93.65 104.27
Peshawar N 98.20 105.35 99.93
Sialkot P 96.49 103.20 102.97
Sargodha P 91.05 97.54 89.59
Quetta B 104.15 100.24 97.31
Islamabad P 102.84 101.35 104.40
Jhang P 87.86 92.69 92.13
Sukkur S 95.55 105.20 94.99
Bahawalpur P 91.21 89.31 95.97
Gujrat P 97.24 91.02 95.50
Sahiwal P 87.80 103.43 93.01
Mardan N 93.19 91.34 99.04
Mirpurkhas S 92.77 93.61 92.14
Larkana S 92.37 96.05 93.88
Rahim Yar Khan P 91.32 105.85 95.21
Nawabshah S 96.01 92.12 92.40
Abbottabad N 97.82 109.77 94.50
Muzaffargarh P 92.14 95.48 94.24
Bannu N 93.97 85.46 93.24
Standard Deviation 4.88 6.77 4.33
Range (Max-Min) 20.37 25.21 14.81
National Average = 1000
Rent Others All
City *
Karachi 98.00 99.20 104.84
Lahore 101.00 101.76 93.36
Faisalabad 105.00 103.40 99.31
Rawalpindi 99.00 99.39 100.26
Hyderabad 99.00 110.55 102.93
Multan 106.00 100.41 99.30
Gujranwala 98.00 96.73 93.48
Peshawar 99.00 97.16 98.76
Sialkot 100.00 106.76 100.46
Sargodha 105.00 95.59 93.37
Quetta 94.00 95.26 100.84
Islamabad 98.00 100.37 102.28
Jhang 104.00 97.23 91.24
Sukkur 99.00 98.33 96.96
Bahawalpur 106.00 94.02 92.71
Gujrat 98.00 99.65 97.05
Sahiwal 105.00 97.30 92.35
Mardan 99.00 96.38 94.36
Mirpurkhas 99.00 95.32 93.68
Larkana 99.00 98.36 94.33
Rahim Yar Khan 106.00 96.49 94.58
Nawabshah 99.00 103.10 96.66
Abbottabad 99.00 96.95 98.60
Muzaffargarh 106.00 98.36 94.42
Bannu 99.00 91.44 92.56
Standard Deviation 3.36 3.66
Range (Max-Min) 12.00 13.60
* Presented in decending order of population.
** S= Sindh, P = Punjab, N = NWFP, B = Balochistan.
Appendix 3
Cost of Living Index by City (National Average = 100)
National Average = 100
Food and Apparel and
City * Province Beverages Footwear
Karachi S 103.72 104.79
Lahore P 99.59 99.18
Faisalabad P 100.21 92.39
Rawalpindi P 104.26 95.20
Multan P 97.20 108.13
Hyderabad S 96.97 100.86
Gujranwala P 101.86 92.60
Peshawar N 102.52 101.67
Quetta B 107.41 108.37
Islamabad Capital 110.59 99.75
Sargodha P 92.68 95.37
Sialkot P 98.39 89.65
Bhawalpur P 94.61 99.20
Sukker S 97.48 84.52
Jhang P 93.20 86.33
Larkana S 94.41 98.58
Mardan N 99.90 97.31
Okara P 92.96 93.42
D.G Khan P 92.60 88.44
Mirpur Khas S 90.80 83.14
Nawab Shah S 96.41 105.17
Jhelum P 99.03 104.24
Bahawal Nagar P 90.56 98.92
Vehari P 95.08 113.82
Khuzdar B 103.19 83.08
D.I. Khan N 88.75 85.57
Mianwali P 92.47 89.78
Turbat B 124.20 79.87
Attock P 99.71 95.25
Abbotabad N 96.78 91.25
Bannu B 95.41 92.30
Lorali B 104.85 95.90
STDV 6.93 8.18
STDV 2002 * 4.88 6.77
Fuel and Rent Overall
City * Lighting
Karachi 96.34 97.06 99.32
Lahore 102.41 95.60 99.52
Faisalabad 102.50 99.93 105.64
Rawalpindi 102.38 111.85 101.51
Multan 101.88 106.58 108.56
Hyderabad 97.56 100.89 95.00
Gujranwala 100.61 105.59 103.80
Peshawar 101.92 101.09 101.08
Quetta 105.50 107.60 111.27
Islamabad 103.03 113.92 106.63
Sargodha 103.70 99.93 96.89
Sialkot 104.11 94.89 97.28
Bhawalpur 103.74 106.58 105.79
Sukker 101.39 98.42 97.09
Jhang 102.48 99.93 94.46
Larkana 100.33 98.42 92.28
Mardan 100.09 101.09 97.38
Okara 97.89 95.60 93.02
D.G Khan 98.63 106.58 92.85
Mirpur Khas 100.73 100.89 90.12
Nawab Shah 101.48 100.89 94.95
Jhelum 101.41 111.85 103.59
Bahawal Nagar 102.49 106.58 104.26
Vehari 100.46 106.58 102.70
Khuzdar 102.94 107.60 98.25
D.I. Khan 98.20 101.09 98.32
Mianwali 101.84 99.93 104.90
Turbat 102.72 107.60 112.15
Attock 100.15 111.85 98.04
Abbotabad 99.24 101.09 105.43
Bannu 99.66 101.09 99.80
Lorali 103.83 107.60 100.08
STDV 2.11 5.17 5.52
STDV 2002 * 4.33 3.36 3.66
* Based on results derived by Pasha and Pasha (2002).
Appendix 4
Ranking of Cities in Descending Order on
the Basis of Overall Cost of Living Index
City Ranking 1998 Ranking 2008
Karachi 1 12
Hyderabad 2 17
Islamabad 3 3
Quetta 4 1
Sialkot 5 14
Rawalpindi 6 8
Faisalabad 7 5
Multan 8 2
Peshawar 9 9
Abbotabad 10 6
Sukker 11 15
Nawab Shah 12 18
Mardan 13 13
Larkana 14 20
Mirpur Khas 15 21
Gujranwala 16 7
Sargodha 17 16
Lahore 18 11
Bhawalpur 19 4
Bannu 20 10
Jhang 21 19
Spearman's rank correlation (p) = 1-6 [summation
over ([d.sup.2.sub.i])]-n([n.sup.2] -1)
'd' equals the difference between column 1 and column 2
(p) for the sample is -0.70 which is significant at 1 percent.
Appendix 5
Average Annual Inflation Rates of Cities and Distance from Port
Cumulative Growth Rate Distance
Inflation * of Cumulative from Karachi
City (1998-2008) Inflation ** Port (Miles)
Karachi 1.601 4.82 0
Lahore 1.801 6.06 646
Faisalabad 1.798 5.87 589
Gujranwala 1.877 6.49 669
Rawalpindi 1.711 5.37 708
Multan 1.848 6.33 461
Hyderabad 1.560 4.54 94
Jhang 1.750 5.75 552
Sialkot 1.636 5.05 701
Sargodha 1.754 5.75 609
Bhawalpur 1.928 6.78 428
Peshawar 1.730 5.63 692
Larkana 1.653 5.15 204
Mardan 1.744 5.72 716
Nawab Shah 1.660 5.19 131
Sukker 1.692 5.40 229
Mirpur Khas 1.626 4.98 134
Abbotabad 1.807 6.10 744
Islamabad 1.762 5.83 714
Quetta 1.866 6.43 374
Bannu 1.822 6.18 615
* Cumulative inflation = Overall index value2008 * 1.68/
Overall index value 1998
where
1.68 = 1 + (CPI 2008 - CPI 1998-99)/
(CPI 1998)
* CPI (consumer price index) values have been taken from the
Government Economic Survey 2007-8) 1.68 percent shows that
inflation increased by 68 percent over the last 10 years.
** Growth rate of cumulative inflation = [(Anti log
(log cumulative inflation value /10)) - 1] * 100.
REFERENCES
Asra, Abuzar (1999) Urban-Rural Differences in Costs of Living and
Their Impact on Poverty Measures. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic
Studies 35:3, 51-69.
Cebula, Richard J. (1980) Determinants of Geographic Living-Cost
Differentials in the United States: An Empirical Note. Land Economics
56:4, 477-481.
Henderson, J. Vernon, Zmarak Shalizi, and Anthony J. Vernables
(2001) Geography and Development. Journal of Economic Geography 1:1,
81-105.
Haworth, C. T. and D. W. Rasmussen (1973) Determinants of
Metropolitan Cost of Living Variations. Southern Economic Journal 40:2,
183-192.
Langston, D., D. W. Rasmussen and J. C. Simmons (1985) A Note on
Geographic Cost of Living Differentials. Land Economics 61:3, 314-318.
Ostrosky, Anthony L. (1983) Determinants of Geographic Living-cost
Differentials in the United States: Comment. Land Economics 59:3,
350-352.
Pasha, Hafiz A. and Aisha Ghaus Pasha (2002) Cost of Living Index
by City of Pakistan. Social Policy and Development Center, Pakistan.
(Research Report 43).
Authors' Note: We would like to thank Dr Hafiz A Pasha for his
help and guidance.
Sonia Ahmad <sonianaseer@hotmail.com> is Assistant Professor,
Department of Economics, Beaconhouse National University, Lahore. Ahmed
Gulzar <ahmed G2008@live.com> is Research Assistant, Department of
Economics, Beaconhouse National University, Lahore.
(1) The source of all the citations in this paragraph is Henderson,
Shalizi, and Venables (2001).
(2) Summary of their results is presented in Appendix 2.
(3) Refer to Appendix 4 for derivation.
(4) Refer to Appendix 5 for derivation.
Table 1
Cost Of Living Index by City * (National Average = 100)
National Average = 100
Food and Wheat Non-food Overall
City Beverages
Islamabad 110.59 99.00 105.01 106.63
Punjab
Lahore 99.59 99.70 100.24 99.52
Faisalabad 100.21 99.85 106.66 105.64
Rawalpindi 104.26 97.95 100.27 101.51
Multan 97.20 91.03 113.15 108.56
Gujranwala 101.86 100.46 101.98 103.80
Sargodha 92.68 92.25 97.17 96.89
Sialkot 98.39 93.15 94.91 97.28
Bhawalpur 94.61 87.06 111.09 105.79
Jhang 93.20 90.11 92.92 94.46
Okara 92.96 89.50 90.89 93.02
D.G Khan 92.60 87.99 91.92 92.85
Jhelum 99.03 96.68 103.54 103.59
Bahawal Nagar 90.56 84.02 109.68 104.26
Vehari 95.08 89.33 104.79 102.70
Mianwah 92.47 94.98 109.33 104.90
Attock 99.71 93.10 98.09 98.04
Sindh
Karachi 103.72 103.02 95.63 99.32
Hyderabad 96.97 97.41 93.17 95.00
Sukker 97.48 94.98 95.99 97.09
Larkana 94.41 93.76 91.08 92.28
Mirpur Khas 90.80 90.11 88.32 90.12
Nawab Shah 96.41 90.11 93.27 94.95
NWFP
Peshawar 102.52 111.17 100.15 101.08
Mardan 99.90 105.69 94.30 97.38
D.I. Khan 88.75 103.50 103.97 98.32
Abbotabad 96.78 99.85 109.78 105.43
Bannu 95.41 109.59 100.76 99.80
Balochistan
Quetta 107.41 114.46 112.54 111.27
Khuzdar 103.19 91.33 94.51 98.25
Turbat 124.20 97.41 104.37 112.15
Lorali 104.85 107.16 96.33 100.08
* Presented province- wise in descending order of population.
Table 2
Province-wise Comparison
Food and Wheat Overall
Province/Capital Beverages Index Index Index
Punjab 99.23 97.15 101.68
Sindh 102.30 101.57 98.43
NWFP 100.82 109.30 100.37
Balochistan 108.35 109.85 109.39
Islamabad 110.59 99.00 106.63
Table 3
Empirical Results
Variable Food and Beverages Wheat Overall
Constant 94.29 89.02 99.02
(50.29) *** (54.00) *** (60.19) ***
P 7.34 9.32 5.86
(2.062) ** (2.97) *** (1.87) *
P2 -1.94 -2.12 -1.81
(-1.62) * (-2.01) ** (-1.72) *
P3 0.14 0.14 0.14
(1.46) (1.64) * (1.63) *
D1 -1.66 0.87 -7.11
(-0.61) (0.37) (-2.95) ***
D2 0.69 14.74 0.09
(0.25) (6.02) *** (0.036)
D3 14.39 11.99 5.46
(4.68) *** (4.44) *** (2.02) **
[R.sup.2] 0.52 0.68 0.42
Degrees of 25 25 25
Freedom
F 4.59 *** 8.81 *** 3.04 **
* Significant at 10 percent.
** Significant at 5 percent.
*** Significant at 1 percent.
Table 4
Annual Average Inflation Rate *
Constant 5.06
(20.29) ***
Distance from Karachi Port 0.0013
(2.79) ***
[R.sup.2] 0.29
F-Statistics 7.81 ***
* Based on data given in Appendix 5.
(2) Summary of their results is presented in Appendix 2.
(3) Refer to Appendix 4 for derivation.
(4) Refer to Appendix 5 for derivation.