Pass-through of change in policy interest rate to market rates.
Khawaja, M. Idrees ; Khan, Sajawal
This paper examines the pass through of the change in policy
interest rate of the central bank of Pakistan to market interest rates.
The market rates examined include KIBOR, six month deposit rate and
weighted average lending rate. More or less complete pass-through of the
change in policy rate to KIBOR is observed within one month. However,
the magnitude of change in policy rate to deposit and lending rate is
not only low but is slow as well. The pass-through to the weighted
average lending rate is 47 percent and occurs with a lag of one to one
and half year. The pass-through to the deposit rate is only 16 percent
and occurs with a lag of one year. The asymmetry between the magnitude
of pass-through to lending and deposit rates has served to increase the
interest margin of the banks. The slow pass-through to the lending and
deposit rate put limits on the effectiveness of interest rate as a
policy tool. The pass-through, and hence the effectiveness of monetary
policy will increase if all the lending and deposit rates are floating
in nature and are quoted as KIBOR-plus and KIBOR-minus respectively.
1. INTRODUCTION
Monetary policy has been aggressively used by the central Bank of
Pakistan, in this decade, first to bolster growth and then to contain
rampant inflation. Despite the sufficiently tight monetary policy that
has remained in vogue in recent times, the inflation is still around 20
percent. This has raised questions about the effectiveness of monetary
policy, One possible reason for the lesser effectiveness, if not
failure, of monetary policy in taming inflation could be that in recent
times, inflation was primarily supply driven and that the monetary
tightening was in part offset by fiscal expansion, on the back of heavy
bank borrowing by the government. However one cannot rule out the
possibility that market imperfections might have also impeded the
effectiveness of monetary policy in taming inflation to the desired
extent. Incomplete and slow pass through of changes in policy interest
rate to deposit rate and lending rate is a kind of imperfection that
constrains the effectiveness of monetary policy. This study examines the
pass through of policy interest rate to different market rates.
Monetary theory predicts that the change in policy interest rate
influences the cost capital which in turn influences consumption,
savings, investments, and hence output. However if the impact of the
change in policy rate on the cost of capital is less than one for one or
if the change in policy rate fails to influence the cost capital
immediately then the impact on output would become visible only with a
certain lag and the impact would be less than one for one. This implies
that if for example only 70 percent of the change in policy rate is
passed on to cost of capital, then to manage an increase of 100 basis
points in cost capital the policy rate should be raised by 143 basis
points. This example serves to emphasise that for effective monetary
management knowledge of the magnitude of pass-through of policy rate and
the lag structure with which the policy rate influences cost of capital
is important. Substantive empirical evidence confirms that changes in
policy interest rate are transmitted to the output with a certain lag
and that the pass-through of changes in policy rate to output or to
other elements of the transmission channel may be less than one for one.
Given the policy implications of the information, on the magnitude of
pass through and the lag structure with which the policy rate influences
different market rates, this Paper seeks to measure the pass-through of
the changes in six month Treasury bill rate to six month KIBOR, six
month weighted average deposit rate and weighted average lending rate.
The study is focused on Pakistan.
Our results, obtained using transfer function approach, show that
the pass through of changes in Treasury bill rate to KIBOR is very
quick. Eighty seven percent of the change is passed on to KIBOR during
one month. However the pass-through to the weighted average lending and
six month deposit rate is only 43 percent and 16 percent respectively.
The changes in policy rate are transmitted to the lending rate with a
lag of one to one and half year while the pass through to six month
deposit rate occurs with a lag of one year.
Our results also show that the pass through to lending and deposit
rate is asymmetric, with the pass through for the lending rate being
greater than that for the deposit rate. One reason for the greater
pass-through to lending rate is that some type of loans, including
corporate loans and loans to the public sector for commodity operations
are linked to KIBOR since the past few years. The pegging of lending
rate to KIBOR (quoting the rate as KIBOR plus) implies that if the KIBOR
increases by say 100 basis point then lending rate would follow suit by
similar magnitude. However deposit rates are mostly not pegged to any
rate. This explains the asymmetric pass-through.
Moreover it is beneficial for banks to pass on the changes in
interest rate to the lending when the policy interest rate is on the
rise and to the deposit rate when the policy rate is on the decline.
More episodes of increase in policy interest rate, in terms of number as
well as magnitude, relative to decrease, explains the greater pass
through to the lending rate. Lastly little sensitivity of the depositors
to interest rate changes has enabled the banks to get away with the
lower pass through to the lending rate. Finally we have also shown that
slow pass-through further dampens the possibility of applying Taylor
rule in Pakistan.
A word of caution is in order here. Loans and deposits are
contracted in such a manner that the change in lending and deposit rates
mostly applies only to the fresh loans and deposits and not the
outstanding ones. We have calculated the pass through to the outstanding
loans and deposits which include the loans and deposits contracted in
the past at rates prevalent before the change in policy interest rate.
This has been done for want of long enough time series on rates for
fresh lending and deposit mobilisation. This aspect serves to emphasise
the point that loans and deposits need to be contracted on floating
terms, that is linked to some rate which changes almost immediately with
the change treasury bill rate. One such rate is KIBOR.
Rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 is devoted to
review of literature on the subject of interest rate pass through.
Section 3 is about the methodology and describes the data as well.
Section 4 presents and interprets the empirical results. Section 5
discusses the slow pass through in the context of application of the
Taylor rule and Section 6 concludes the paper.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
The literature on interest rate pass-through has two strands. One
that examines just the magnitude of pass-through i.e. whether
pass-through of changes in policy rate to market or deposit and lending
rate is complete or incomplete and the determinants of pass-through. The
second strand of literature, examines the macroeconomic implication of
incomplete/sluggish pass-through. We discuss all the three strands in
this section.
There is near-consensus in literature on pass through that
pass-through in short-term is less than complete while for pass-through
in long-term the evidence is mixed. The studies that report less tha
complete pass-through include [Cottarelli and Kourelis (1994); Hanan and
Berger (1991); Mojon (2000) and Bondt (2002)]. Bondt, Mojon, and Valla
(2005) report, that pass-through in the short-run (monthly) ranges
between 0.25 [Sander and Kleimeier (2002); Hofmann (2006) to 0.76
Heinemann and Sch"uler (2002)]. For long-run Gropp, Kok Sorensen,
and Lichtenberger (2007), report an incomplete pass-through in euro
area, even after controlling for differences in bank soundness, credit
risk, and the slope of the yield curve. The studies that report a
complete pass-through of market rates to short-term interest rates, in
the long-run include, Mojon (2000), Heinemann and Sch"uler (2002),
Hofmann (2003), and Sander and Kleimeier (2002). However Donnay and
Degryse (2001) and Toolsema, Sturm, and de Haan (2001) report an
incomplete pass-through even in the long-run.
2.1. Determinants of Pass-through
The sources of incomplete pass-through that emerge from review of a
number of studies include, menu costs involved in altering the contract,
Implicit contract between banker and customer for protection against
rate volatility, competitiveness of the banking structure, moral hazards
involved in negotiating new loan contracts, capital mobility and private
ownership of banks. These sources are briefly discussed below.
The bank would change the rate only when the expected gain from the
revision is greater than the menu costs involved in altering the rate
[e.g. Hannan and Berger (1991); Hofmann and Mizen (2004)]. Banks that
seek to earn by fostering a long term relationship with their customers
have an implicit contract with their customers to protect them from
interest rate volatility. The response of these banks to changes in
policy rate is likely to be sluggish [Berger and Udell (1992); Allen and
Gale (2000)]. Weyth (2002) provides empirical evidence that banks that
rely on long term stable relationship with their customers are slow to
adjust their lending rates. Specifically they show that small banks that
generate funds from deposits (i.e. rely on relationship with customers)
are slow to adjust their rates while the larger banks that generate
funds from the market are relatively quick to adjust their rates (of
course due the adjustment in the market rate).
Kwapil and Scharler (2006) argue that given asymmetric information,
moral hazards may arise if the lending rate increases, i.e. the borrower
who borrows at a higher rate may undertake risky ventures thereby
endangering bank's money. In this situation the bank may prefer to
rely on changing other terms, like collateral requirement rather than
increasing the rate. The pass-through again would remain incomplete.
Other sources of sluggish pass through that have been identified
empirically include competitiveness of the financial markets [Gropp,
Scrensen, and Lichtenberger (2007)], differences in financial structure
of the banks [Schwarzbauer (2006), Cottarelli and Kourelis (1994)].
Cottarelli and Kourelis argue features of the financial structure that
speed up the pass-through include capital mobility, private ownership of
banks and stability of money market rates. Another reason for slow
pass-through put forth by de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005) is that at
times the short term rates of banks are linked to long term market
rates. Anticipated changes in monetary policy is another source of
slow-pass through identified by Sander and Kleimeier (2006).
Hanan and Berger (1991) find that pass-through to deposit rate is
asymmetric for upward and downward revision of policy rate. To explain
the result the authors argue that typically the customers respond with a
lag to change in prices. If the deposit rates are changed today then the
full expected response in the shape of more deposits will be realised
after sometime, say, a month. During this lag period the banks pay more
interest to depositors without realising the corresponding benefits in
the shape of larger deposit volume. Similarly when the interest rate on
deposits is reduced, even the interest sensitive customers, will take
time to withdraw their deposits. During this lag-period the bank would
pay lesser interest without incurring corresponding penalty in the shape
of reduced deposit volume. Given the foregoing HB argues that increasing
interest rate on deposits is harmful for banks in while decreasing
interest rate is likely to prove fruitful, at least in the short run.
This makes the pass through asymmetric.
A problem that arises in empirical estimation of pass-through from
policy rate to deposit and lending rates is of maturity mismatch. The
issue has been raised by Mojon (2000) and Bondt (2005). The problem is
that the instrument which reflects the policy rate policy rate and the
money market rate are of short term maturity while the deposit and
lending rates could be of longer maturity as well. Bondt (2002) avoids
the maturity mismatch problem by examining money market rates of
comparable maturity.
3. EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK
To estimate our model we use transfer function approach developed
by Box, Jenkins, and Reinsel (1994). The transfer function model in
essence shows how a movement in the independent variable influences the
changes in dependent variable. The model allows identification of the
lag structure with which the independent variable influences the
dependent variable and also measure the magnitude of influence. The
model is one of the most widely used in linear times series estimation.
The methodology is explained below.
Let us assume that an independent variable [x.sub.t] and dependent
variable [y.sub.t] are jointly stationary. Now [y.sub.t] can be written
as:
[y.sub.t] = [z.sub.t] + [N.sub.t]
Where [z.sub.t] contains that part of [y.sub.t] which can be
explained in term of [x.sub.t], and [N.sub.t] is an error or noise term
which is auto-correlated but is independent of the input series
[x.sub.t]. Here, both y, and [x.sub.t] are observable, while [z.sub.t]
is not observable. Suppose the dynamic relationship between [z.sub.t]
and [x.sub.t] is represented as:
[z.sub.t] = ([[omega].sub.0] - [[omega].sub.1] - ... -
[[omega].sub.s][B.sup.s]/1 - [[delta].sub.1]B - ... -
[B.sub.r][B.sup.r]) [x.sub.t-b]
Let us call v(B)= [[omega](B)/[delta](B)][B.sup.b] "the
transfer function" where b represents the lag period. The above
equation can be written as:
[y.sub.t] = v(B)[x.sub.t] + [N.sub.t]
Mostly the term [N.sub.t] is non-stationary and it can be
represented as [N.sub.t] = c + [[theta](B)/[phi](B)][a.sub.t].
Now the model may be written as:
[y.sub.t] = c + v (B) [xsub.t] + [[theta](B)/[phi] (B)] [a.sub.t]
In practice, we normally do not know the form of v (B) and the
structure of [N.sub.t] i.e. the parameters r, s, b, p, and q and have to
identify them through the analyses of data on variables x, and yr.
The identification consists of pre-whitening the independent as
well as dependent variable on the basis of ARMA (p, q) of independent
variable. Using correlogram, autocorrelation functions, and partial
correlation functions of the pre-whitened variables, the best fitted
model is selected for estimation. (1)
Using the methodology discussed above we have estimated the pass
through of the six month treasury bill rate to six month KIBOR, Six
month deposit rate and weighted average lending rate. For the pass
through to KIBOR the data span September 2001-February 2009 and the data
frequency is monthly. The reason for the shorter data span is that the
KIBOR rate was introduced in 2001. For the lending and deposit rates we
have used the span June 1991--June 2008 and the data frequency is
biannual. The reason for the choice of frequency in this case is
dictated by data availability. Over the recent years the State Bank has
used discount rate as an instrument of the policy and it would have been
more appropriate to estimate the pass through from the discount rate
rather than the treasury bill rate. However following two reasons do not
allow the construction of a long enough time series of change in
discount rate. First, the changes in discount rate have been occurring
at irregular intervals besides the State bank's active use of the
discount the rate as an instrument of monetary policy is not too old.
4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
4.1. Pass Through from TBR to KIBOR Rate
We estimate the pass through from the 6-month Treasury bill rate to
6-month KIBOR rate using data with monthly frequency. The data span is
September 2001-February 2009. The State Bank of Pakistan is now using
discount rate as a policy instrument however since the changes in
discount rate occurs only at discreet interval we have used 6-month
Treasury bill rate as proxy for policy rate.
The first step under the Box Jenkins, transfer function approach is
to fit an ARIMA model to the {[DELTA]TBR} series. We obtain the
Autocorrelation Function (ACF), Partial Autocorrelation Function (PACF)
and the respective correlograms for [DELTA]TBR. These are respectively
presented below in Tables l(a and b) and Figures 1(a and b).
[FIGURE 1(a) OMITTED]
[FIGURE 1(b) OMITTED]
Tables 1(a and b), and Figures 1(a and b) show that ACF and PACF
are respectively significant up to 3rd and 2nd lag. This suggests ARMA
(2, 3) for [DELTA]TBR. The most plausible models for ATBR then is:
[DELTA]TBR =[beta]1[DELTA]TBRt - 1 + [beta]2[DELTA]TBRt -2 +
[epsilon]zt (2)
The next step is to obtain pre-whitened series for our dependent
variable ([DELTA]TBR) and Independent variable ([DELTA]KIBOR)
Filtered (pre-whitened) series for [DELTA]TBR is:
[alpha]t = [DELTA]TBR - 0.32[DELTA]TBRt -1- 0.31[DELTA]TBRt - 2 (3)
Pre-whitened series for [DELTA]KIBOR is:
[beta]t = [DELTA]KIBOR - 0.32[DELTA]KIBOR t -1- 0.31 [DELTA]KIBORt
-2 (4)
Next we obtain cross-correlation and cross-correlogram between our
two pre-whitened series: at and [beta]t. These are presented below
respectively in Table 2 and Figure 2.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Table 2 and Figure 2 show that [rho](0), [rho](1) and [rho](2) are
statistically significant. Next based on cross-correlation between
pre-whitened series at and [beta]t, we select the following model:
[beta]t = al [beta]t-1 + b1[alpha]t +b2[alpha]t-1 + b3[alpha]t-2 +
et (4)
Estimation of (4) yields:
[beta]t = 0.09[beta]t- 1 +0.83[alpha]t+0.46[alpha]t-
1-0.22[alpha]t-2 +et (5)
Then we obtain et as:
[e.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.t] (0.83 + 0.46L - 0.22[L.sup.2])/[1 -
0.09] [[alpha].sub.t]
The ACF, PACF of the error term et and the relevant correlograms
are presented Below in Tablesd 3(a and b) and Figures 3 (a and b)
respectively.
[FIGURE 3(a) OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3(b) OMITTED]
On the basis of ACF and PACF of et the preliminary model for et is:
et = -0.93et-2-0.39 et-4-0.32 et-6 +(0.52[L.sup.2]+ 0.43[Lsup.6])
[epsilon]t (6)
Therefore our tentative Transfer Function is:
[DELTA][KIBOR.sub.t] = (0.83 + 0.46[L.sup.4] - 0.22[L.sup.6]]/[1 -
0.08L] [[alpha].sub.t][DELTA]KIBOR + (0.52[L.sup.2] + 0.43[L.sup.4])/[1
+ 0.93[L.sup.2] + 0.39[L.sup.4] + 0.32[L.sup.6] et (7)
Then we expand the first term in Equation 6 using binomial expansion. This yields:
[DELTA][KIBOR.sub.t] = [[1 - 0.08L].sup.-1] [[0.83 + 0.46[L.sup.4]
- 0.22[L.sup.6]][DELTA]TBR + (0.52[L.sup.2] + 0.43[L.sup.4])/ [1 + 0.93
[L.sup.2] + 0.39 [L.sup.4] + 0.32 [L.sup.6]] et
Or
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
It is evident from the Equation 8 that 83 percent of the change in
6-month treasury bill rate is passed on to the 6-month KIBOR during the
first month. Slight overshooting is observed in the following months,
which is corrected later on.
We employ similar procedure to estimate the pass through for the
weighted average six month deposit rate and weighted average lending
rate. The final equations for the two are indicated and discussed below.
(2)
4.2. Pass-through from Treasury Bill Rate to Lending Rate
The pass of the 6-month Treasury bill rate to the weighted average
lending rate has been estimated for the period June 1991 to June 2008.
The data frequency is bi-annual. The transfer function developed for the
weighted average rate of return on loans using procedure similar to the
one used for KIBOR is:
[DELTA][WARRA.sub.t] = (0.16[L.sup.2] + 0.27 [L.sup.3]) [DELTA]TBR
+ (0.55L + 0.43[L.sup.2])/[1 + 0.71L + 0.75 [[L.sup.2]].sup.et] (9)
The equation shows that a total of 43 percent the change in six
Treasury bill rate is passed is passed on to the lending rate (16
percent with a lag of two periods and 27 percent with a lag of three
periods, each period being of six months) with a lag of one to one and a
half year. The total pass-through to the lending rate being only 43
percent we can say that the lending rate exhibit rigidity.
4.3. Pass-through from Treasury Bill Rate to Six-month Deposit Rate
The pass through of changes in 6-month Treasury bill rate to the
6-month weighted average deposit rate has been estimated for the Period
June 1991 to June 2008. The frequency used is bi-annual. The transfer
function developed for six-month weighted average rate of return on
deposits, using procedure described earlier for KIBOR is:
[DELTA][WARRD.sub.t] = (0.16[L.sup.2])[DELTA]TBR -
(0.86[L.sup.4])/[1 + 0.47 [L.sup.2]] (10)
The transfer function described above shows that that only 16
percent of the change in treasury bill rate is passed on to the weighted
average rate of deposits and that too with a lag of two periods, that
is, after one year.
4.4. Reasons for Slow and Asymmetric Pass Through
While the pass through for the lending rate is 43 percent the pass
through for the deposit rate is only 16 percent. This implies that banks
are slow to change deposit rates relative to lending rates. The question
is who benefits from asymmetric in pass through between lending and
deposit rates. The answer is; it depends whether the asymmetry occurs in
an environment of increasing interest rate or when the interest rate are
on the decline. If the policy rate is on the rise, greater pass through
to the lending rate relative to deposit rate would increase the interest
margin of the banks therefore the banks seek to benefit from asymmetry
while the converse holds true when the interest rates are on the
decline. The greater pass through observed for lending rate relative to
deposit rate leads one to suspect that, by and large, the asymmetry has
occurred in an environment of increasing interest rates. Our data span
covers a period of 17 years (June 1990-June 2008). During this period
there have three major episodes of change in interest Treasury bill rate
(Table 4).
It is evident from Table 4 that out of the 17 years data span, the
treasury bill rate has followed an upward course for a period of twelve
years while the downward trend has been observed for only five years.
Moreover the magnitude of increase has also been greater than the
decline. This explains why the pass through to the lending rate is
greater than pass through to deposit rate: because in an environment of
increasing interest rates greater pass through to lending rate increases
the interest income of the banks but the cost of funds does not increase
by corresponding magnitude. Therefore the greater pass through to
lending rates suits the banks.
Pegging of the lending rate to KIBOR is another important reason
that explains the relatively greater pass through to the lending rate.
The State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) has instructed all the banks to link
their corporate lending rate to KIBOR. Moreover loans for commodity
operations to government departments have also been linked with KIBOR of
appropriate tenor since 2006. Loans against export refinance facility,
the subsidised credit to exporters, have also been pegged to the
Treasury bill rate. Pegging of lending rate to these reference rate
quickens the pass through, because as soon as the reference rate (KIBOR
or Treasury bill rate) the change in lending rate (for fresh loans)
invariably fallows.
One reason for the slow pass through observed for weighted average
lending rate and 6 month deposit rate is that these rates are for
outstanding loans and deposits, which includes loans extended and
deposits mobilised at the rates prevailing before the change in treasury
bill rate. It is note worthy here that the volume of loans extended and
deposit mobilised at previous rates is understandably much higher than
the fresh loans extended and deposits mobilised after the change in the
treasury bill rate. This brings us to the question: What manner of
quoting interest/return on loans and deposits would speed up the
transmission mechanism of monetary policy? The answer is that the
floating rate, (3) that is, the rate specified with reference to some
other interest rate, for example KIBOR will facilitate pass-through of
interest rate from policy rate to lending and deposit rates. We have
observed that the pass through to the KIBOR is very fast, therefore if
all lending rates of banks are quoted in terms of KIBOR plus and
deposits rates are quoted as KIBOR minus then the lending and deposit
rates will change as soon as the KIBOR changes.
4.5. Slow Pass through to Deposit Rate
One reason for the slow pass-through to the deposit rate could be
that behaviour of the depositors is not sufficiently interest sensitive.
This is evident from the overtime composition of the total deposits,
shown in Table 5.
If the depositors are not too sensitive to interest rate changes
then one may expect that the banks can get away with incomplete pass through and delayed pass through. It is evident from table that majority
of the deposits are held either in current account or savings account.
The current account earns no interest while very little interest is paid
to the holders of savings account. Given the failure of the banks to
raise the rate on their own the SBP mandated only about a year ago to
pay a minimum of 5 percent interest on savings account. This speaks
volumes about the gravity of the situation regarding the low pass
through to the deposit rate. It is clear from the composition of the
deposits shown in Table 5 that the behaviour of the depositors holding a
sizable deposit volume is not interest sensitive. Given the less
sensitivity of the depositors to interest rate changes the banks in
Pakistan have been able to get away with incomplete pass through, and
delayed pass through on deposit rates. Hence the slow pass through to
deposit rates. To quicken the pass through to deposit rates it is
important that like the lending rate the deposit may also be linked
KIBOR. However to implement such a regime effectively requires greater
ability on the part of potential borrowers and depositors to forecast
interest rate changes and mental preparedness that change in policy rate
at times may adversely influence the depositors or the borrowers.
5. MACROECONOMIC IMPLICATION OF LIMITED PASS-THROUGH
Pass-through and Taylor Principle
Incomplete pass-through has macroeconomic implications. One
consequence is that this alters the popular Taylor rule [Kwapil and
Scharler (2006)]. The rule, in essence implies that to maintain
equilibrium, for every one percentage point increase in inflation, the
interest rate should rise by more than one percentage point. The rule
also implies that if the nominal interest rate does not rise, as
suggested by Taylor, a rise in expected inflation causes the real
interest rate to decline. The resultant stimulus to aggregate demand
causes the inflation to rise further and thus initial expectations are
fulfilled. Kwapil and Scharler contend that that an economy subject this
type of shock will be highly unstable. To understand how the incomplete
pass-through alters the Taylor rule let us very briefly examine the
Taylor rule. The rule can be written as:
[i.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.[tau]] + [r.sub.[tau].sup.*] + [a.sub.[pi]]
([[pi].sub.[tau]] - [[pi].sup.*.sub.[tau]]) + [a.sub.y] ([y.sub.t] -
[y.sup.*.sub.[tau]])
Where [i.sub.[tau]] is the targeted short term interest rate,
[[pi].sub.[tau]] and [[pi].sub.[tau]].sup.*] are the actual and targeted
inflation rate respectively, [r.sub.[tau]].sup.*] is the assumed
equilibrium interest rate ([y.sub.t] - [y.sub.t.sup.*])is the output
gap. To satisfy Taylor rule [a.sub.[pi]] > 0. If this does not hold
the real interest rate would decline with the change in policy rate.
Kwapil and Scharler (2006) argue that limited pass-through alters the
Taylor rule--because even if the nominal interest rate rises by 1
percentage point, still in the face of incomplete pass through, the
pass-through to market rates rate will be less than 1 percentage point.
The Taylor rule, according to Kawpil and Scharler (2006) under an
environment of incomplete pass-through, will be satisfied if as [lambda]
> 0, where [lambda], is the long-run pass-through to retail rates.
Kwapil and Scharler (2006) citing various studies suggests that since
the value as is sufficiently greater than one (in the rage 1.8-2.15) for
US and euro area therefore even in the face of incomplete pass through
the monetary policy rules will most probably satisfy the conditions for
determinate equilibrium in US and euro area. For Pakistan only one study
[Malik and Ahmad (2007)] has estimated the Taylor rule. The value of
[a.sub[pi]] according to this study is 0.51. If we take the pass through
to the lending rate as 0.43, as worked out in this study, then the value
of [a.sub.[pi]] [lambda] comes to only 0.22. Clearly Pakistan's
economy is far from satisfying the modified Taylor rule. Irrespective of the fact that whether the SBP is following the Taylor principle for
monetary management, the low value [a.sub.[pi]] coupled with limited
pass-through has made the monetary management more difficult for the
authorities.
6. CONCLUSIONS
We have estimated the pass through from six month treasury bill
rate to different market rates including KIBOR, six month deposit rate
and weighted average lending rate. While the pass through of the 6-month
Treasury bill rate to 6-month KIBOR is almost complete and immediate the
pass through to the 6-month deposit rate and weighted average lending
rate takes from a year to year and a half. Moreover the pass through to
lending rate is much greater than the one observed for the deposit rate.
Less interest sensitive behaviour of the depositors has enabled the
banks to get away with slow pass through to deposits. On the other hand
pegging of the rate on corporate loans and rate on loans for commodity
operation to KIBOR has increased the pace of pass through to lending
rate. This implies pegging can enhance the pass through, and therefore
the effectiveness of the interest rate channel of monetary policy
transmission. Moreover if the deposit rates, like lending rates for
certain types of loans, are also pegged to KIBOR the pass through to the
deposit rate would also increase and the asymmetry issue will be taken
care off. However such pegging requires greater ability of the
bank's customers to forecast interest rate changes and be prepared
for the worst as well. Finally we also showed that less than one for one
pass through to the lending rate makes it more difficult to apply even
if one attempts to apply the Taylor rule in Pakistan.
REFERENCES
Allen, F. and D. Gale (2000) Comparing Financial Systems.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Berger, A. and G. Udell (1992) Some Evidence on the Empirical
Significance of Credit Rationing. Journal of Political Economy 25,
291-299.
Bondt, G. (2002) Retail Bank Interest Rate Pass-through: New
Evidence at the Euro Area Level. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. (ECB Working Paper No. 136.)
Bondt, G., B. Mojon, and N. Valla (2005) Term Structure and the
Sluggishness of Retail Bank Interest Rates in Euro Area Countries. (ECB
Working Paper Series No. 518.)
Box, J., G. Jenkins, and G. Reinsel (1994) Time Series Analysis.
373-84. Prentice-Hall.
Cottarelli, C. and Angeliki Kourelis (1994) Financial Structure,
Bank Lending Rates, and the Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy.
IMF Staff Papers 41:4, 587-623.
Donnay, M. and H. Degryse (2001) Bank Lending Rate Pass-through and
Differences in the Transmission of a Single EMU Monetary Policy.
(Discussion Paper No. 0117.)
Gropp, R., C. Kok Sorensen, and J. Lichtenberger (2007) The
Dynamics of Bank Spreads and Financial Structure. (ECB Working Paper
Series No. 714.)
Hanan, T. and Allen Berger (1991) The Rigidity of Prices: Evidence
from the Banking Industry. American Economic Review 81:4, 938-945.
Heinemann, F. and M. Sch"uler (2002) Integration Benefits on
EU Retail Credit Markets--Evidence from Interest Rate Pass-Through. (ZEW Discussion Paper No. 02-26.)
Hofmann, B. (2003) EMU and the Transmission of Monetary Policy:
Evidence from Business Lending Rates. ZEI University of Bonn.
Hofmann, B. and P. Mizen (2004) Interest Rate Pass-through and
Monetary Transmission: Evidence from Individual Financial
Institutions' Retail Rates. Economica 71, 99-123.
Kwapil, C. and Johann Scharler (2006) Limited Pass-through from
Policy to Retail Interest Rates: Empirical Evidence and Macroeconomic
Implications. Monetary Policy and the Economy Q4/06, 26-36.
Malik, Wasim Shahid and Ather Maqsood Ahmed (2007) The Taylor Rule
and the Macroeconomic Performance in Pakistan. (PIDE Working Papers No.
34.)
Mojon, B. (2000) Financial Structure and the Interest Rate Channel
of ECB Monetary Policy. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. (ECB Working
Paper No. 40.)
Qayyum, Abdul, Sajawal Khan, and M. Idrees Khawaja (2005) Interest
Rate Pass-through in Pakistan: Evidence from Transfer Function Approach.
The Pakistan Development Review 44:4, 975-998.
Sander, H. and S. Kleimeier (2002) Asymmetric Adjustment of
Commercial Bank Interest Rates in the Euro Area: An Empirical
Investigation into Interest Rate Pass-through. Kredit und Kapital 2,
161-92.
Sander, H. and S. Kleimeier (2006) Convergence of Interest Rate
Pass-through in a Wider Euro Zone? Economic Systems 30, 405-23.
Schwarzbauer, W. (2006) Financial Structure and Its Impact on the
Convergence of Interest Rate Pass-Through in Europe: A Time-varying
Interest Rate Pass-through Model. Institute for Advanced Studies.
(Economics Series 191.)
Toolsema, L. A., J. Sturm, and J. de Haan (2001) Convergence of
Monetary Transmission in EMU: New Evidence. (CESifo Working Paper No.
465.)
Weyth, M. A. (2002) The Pass-through from Market Interest Rates to
Bank Lending Rates in Germany. Deutsche Bundesbank. (Economic Research
Centre Discussion Paper 11/02.)
M. Idrees Khawaja <khawajami@yahoo.com> is Consultant at the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Sajawal Khan
<sajawal.khan@sbp.org.pk> is Research Economist, Research
Department, State Bank of Pakistan, Karachi.
(1) For detail see Box and Jenkins (1994).
(2) Detailed results for weighted average six months deposit rate
and weighted average lending rate are available from the authors upon
request.
(3) Floating rate implies that rate for the entire term is not
quoted when the loans or deposits are contracted, rather the rate
changes (after a specified interval) with the change in reference rate
to which the deposit or lending rate is pegged.
Table 1(a)
Auto Correlation Function (ACF) of [DELTA]TBR
[rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)
Q-Stat. 0.468 0.474 0.302 0.170 0.144
[rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9) [rho](10)
Q-Stat. 0.091 0.096 0.055 0.040 0.099
[rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14) [rho](15)
Q-Stat. 0.142 0.145 0.225 0.176 0.1270
[rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)
Q-Stat. 0.063 0.120 0.039
Table 1(b)
Partial Auto Correlation Function (PA CF) of ATBR
Q-Stat. [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)
0.468 0.327 -0.001 -0.114 0.026
Q-Stat. [rho](10) [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14)
0.107 0.129 0.011 0.095 0.002
Q-Stat. [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9)
0.031 -0.027 -0.023
Q-Stat. [rho](15) [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)
0.072 0.061 -0.062 0.026
Table 2
Cross Correlation between at and [beta]t
[rho](0) [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4)
S.Dev. 0.637 0.327 -0.257 0.048 -0.019
0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014
[rho](5) [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9)
S.Dev. -0.073 0.100 0.020 -0.05 -0.094
0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014
[rho](10) [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14)
S.Dev. -0.023 0.012 -0.011 0.037 0.010
0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014
[rho](15) [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18) [rho](19)
S.Dev. -0.055 -0.024 -0.067 0.002 0.094
0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014
Table 3(a)
Auto Correlation Function (ACF) of et
[rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)
Q-Stat. -0.022 -0.360 -0.060 -0.120 -0.019
[rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9) [rho](10)
Q-Stat. 0.200 0.026 -0.014 -0.095 -0.140
[rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14) [rho](15)
Q-Stat. 0.014 0.113 0.039 0.003 -0.089
[rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)
Q-Stat. -0.113 0.028 0.103
Table 3(b)
Partil auto correlation Function (PACF) of et
[rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)
Q-St(a)t. -0.022 -0.361 -0.090 -0.297 -0.132
[rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9) [rho](10)
Q-St(a)t. 0.019 -0.055 0.051 -0.113 -0.117
[rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14) [rho](15)
Q-St(a)t. -0.093 0.041 -0.044 -0.040 -0.105
[rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)
Q-St(a)t. -0.136 -0.087 -0.051
Table 4
Episodes of Changes in Treasury Bill Rate
Number of Direction of Change Change
Time Period Years in Treasury Bill rate (Basis points)
June 90-June 98 8 Upward 641
Dec 98-Dec 03 5 Downward 1411
June 04-June 08 4 Upward 1232
Table 5
Trend in Composition of Deposits
Type of Deposits
Year
(June) Current Savings Non Fixed
1998 16 46 66
1998 15 47 68
2000 15 51 71
2001 18 51 73
2002 20 53 76
2003 21 57 81
2004 24 56 84
2005 26 52 81
2006 26 47 76
2008 25 43 70
Type of
Deposits
Year T. Bill
(June) Fixed Rate
1998 34 15.75
1998 32 10.6
2000 29 7.14
2001 27 12.88
2002 24 6.33
2003 19 3.84
2004 16 2.08
2005 19 7.92
2006 24 8.45
2008 30 9.02