首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Pass-through of change in policy interest rate to market rates.
  • 作者:Khawaja, M. Idrees ; Khan, Sajawal
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2008
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 关键词:Central banks;Interest rates

Pass-through of change in policy interest rate to market rates.


Khawaja, M. Idrees ; Khan, Sajawal


This paper examines the pass through of the change in policy interest rate of the central bank of Pakistan to market interest rates. The market rates examined include KIBOR, six month deposit rate and weighted average lending rate. More or less complete pass-through of the change in policy rate to KIBOR is observed within one month. However, the magnitude of change in policy rate to deposit and lending rate is not only low but is slow as well. The pass-through to the weighted average lending rate is 47 percent and occurs with a lag of one to one and half year. The pass-through to the deposit rate is only 16 percent and occurs with a lag of one year. The asymmetry between the magnitude of pass-through to lending and deposit rates has served to increase the interest margin of the banks. The slow pass-through to the lending and deposit rate put limits on the effectiveness of interest rate as a policy tool. The pass-through, and hence the effectiveness of monetary policy will increase if all the lending and deposit rates are floating in nature and are quoted as KIBOR-plus and KIBOR-minus respectively.

1. INTRODUCTION

Monetary policy has been aggressively used by the central Bank of Pakistan, in this decade, first to bolster growth and then to contain rampant inflation. Despite the sufficiently tight monetary policy that has remained in vogue in recent times, the inflation is still around 20 percent. This has raised questions about the effectiveness of monetary policy, One possible reason for the lesser effectiveness, if not failure, of monetary policy in taming inflation could be that in recent times, inflation was primarily supply driven and that the monetary tightening was in part offset by fiscal expansion, on the back of heavy bank borrowing by the government. However one cannot rule out the possibility that market imperfections might have also impeded the effectiveness of monetary policy in taming inflation to the desired extent. Incomplete and slow pass through of changes in policy interest rate to deposit rate and lending rate is a kind of imperfection that constrains the effectiveness of monetary policy. This study examines the pass through of policy interest rate to different market rates.

Monetary theory predicts that the change in policy interest rate influences the cost capital which in turn influences consumption, savings, investments, and hence output. However if the impact of the change in policy rate on the cost of capital is less than one for one or if the change in policy rate fails to influence the cost capital immediately then the impact on output would become visible only with a certain lag and the impact would be less than one for one. This implies that if for example only 70 percent of the change in policy rate is passed on to cost of capital, then to manage an increase of 100 basis points in cost capital the policy rate should be raised by 143 basis points. This example serves to emphasise that for effective monetary management knowledge of the magnitude of pass-through of policy rate and the lag structure with which the policy rate influences cost of capital is important. Substantive empirical evidence confirms that changes in policy interest rate are transmitted to the output with a certain lag and that the pass-through of changes in policy rate to output or to other elements of the transmission channel may be less than one for one. Given the policy implications of the information, on the magnitude of pass through and the lag structure with which the policy rate influences different market rates, this Paper seeks to measure the pass-through of the changes in six month Treasury bill rate to six month KIBOR, six month weighted average deposit rate and weighted average lending rate. The study is focused on Pakistan.

Our results, obtained using transfer function approach, show that the pass through of changes in Treasury bill rate to KIBOR is very quick. Eighty seven percent of the change is passed on to KIBOR during one month. However the pass-through to the weighted average lending and six month deposit rate is only 43 percent and 16 percent respectively. The changes in policy rate are transmitted to the lending rate with a lag of one to one and half year while the pass through to six month deposit rate occurs with a lag of one year.

Our results also show that the pass through to lending and deposit rate is asymmetric, with the pass through for the lending rate being greater than that for the deposit rate. One reason for the greater pass-through to lending rate is that some type of loans, including corporate loans and loans to the public sector for commodity operations are linked to KIBOR since the past few years. The pegging of lending rate to KIBOR (quoting the rate as KIBOR plus) implies that if the KIBOR increases by say 100 basis point then lending rate would follow suit by similar magnitude. However deposit rates are mostly not pegged to any rate. This explains the asymmetric pass-through.

Moreover it is beneficial for banks to pass on the changes in interest rate to the lending when the policy interest rate is on the rise and to the deposit rate when the policy rate is on the decline. More episodes of increase in policy interest rate, in terms of number as well as magnitude, relative to decrease, explains the greater pass through to the lending rate. Lastly little sensitivity of the depositors to interest rate changes has enabled the banks to get away with the lower pass through to the lending rate. Finally we have also shown that slow pass-through further dampens the possibility of applying Taylor rule in Pakistan.

A word of caution is in order here. Loans and deposits are contracted in such a manner that the change in lending and deposit rates mostly applies only to the fresh loans and deposits and not the outstanding ones. We have calculated the pass through to the outstanding loans and deposits which include the loans and deposits contracted in the past at rates prevalent before the change in policy interest rate. This has been done for want of long enough time series on rates for fresh lending and deposit mobilisation. This aspect serves to emphasise the point that loans and deposits need to be contracted on floating terms, that is linked to some rate which changes almost immediately with the change treasury bill rate. One such rate is KIBOR.

Rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 is devoted to review of literature on the subject of interest rate pass through. Section 3 is about the methodology and describes the data as well. Section 4 presents and interprets the empirical results. Section 5 discusses the slow pass through in the context of application of the Taylor rule and Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. LITERATURE REVIEW

The literature on interest rate pass-through has two strands. One that examines just the magnitude of pass-through i.e. whether pass-through of changes in policy rate to market or deposit and lending rate is complete or incomplete and the determinants of pass-through. The second strand of literature, examines the macroeconomic implication of incomplete/sluggish pass-through. We discuss all the three strands in this section.

There is near-consensus in literature on pass through that pass-through in short-term is less than complete while for pass-through in long-term the evidence is mixed. The studies that report less tha complete pass-through include [Cottarelli and Kourelis (1994); Hanan and Berger (1991); Mojon (2000) and Bondt (2002)]. Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005) report, that pass-through in the short-run (monthly) ranges between 0.25 [Sander and Kleimeier (2002); Hofmann (2006) to 0.76 Heinemann and Sch"uler (2002)]. For long-run Gropp, Kok Sorensen, and Lichtenberger (2007), report an incomplete pass-through in euro area, even after controlling for differences in bank soundness, credit risk, and the slope of the yield curve. The studies that report a complete pass-through of market rates to short-term interest rates, in the long-run include, Mojon (2000), Heinemann and Sch"uler (2002), Hofmann (2003), and Sander and Kleimeier (2002). However Donnay and Degryse (2001) and Toolsema, Sturm, and de Haan (2001) report an incomplete pass-through even in the long-run.

2.1. Determinants of Pass-through

The sources of incomplete pass-through that emerge from review of a number of studies include, menu costs involved in altering the contract, Implicit contract between banker and customer for protection against rate volatility, competitiveness of the banking structure, moral hazards involved in negotiating new loan contracts, capital mobility and private ownership of banks. These sources are briefly discussed below.

The bank would change the rate only when the expected gain from the revision is greater than the menu costs involved in altering the rate [e.g. Hannan and Berger (1991); Hofmann and Mizen (2004)]. Banks that seek to earn by fostering a long term relationship with their customers have an implicit contract with their customers to protect them from interest rate volatility. The response of these banks to changes in policy rate is likely to be sluggish [Berger and Udell (1992); Allen and Gale (2000)]. Weyth (2002) provides empirical evidence that banks that rely on long term stable relationship with their customers are slow to adjust their lending rates. Specifically they show that small banks that generate funds from deposits (i.e. rely on relationship with customers) are slow to adjust their rates while the larger banks that generate funds from the market are relatively quick to adjust their rates (of course due the adjustment in the market rate).

Kwapil and Scharler (2006) argue that given asymmetric information, moral hazards may arise if the lending rate increases, i.e. the borrower who borrows at a higher rate may undertake risky ventures thereby endangering bank's money. In this situation the bank may prefer to rely on changing other terms, like collateral requirement rather than increasing the rate. The pass-through again would remain incomplete. Other sources of sluggish pass through that have been identified empirically include competitiveness of the financial markets [Gropp, Scrensen, and Lichtenberger (2007)], differences in financial structure of the banks [Schwarzbauer (2006), Cottarelli and Kourelis (1994)]. Cottarelli and Kourelis argue features of the financial structure that speed up the pass-through include capital mobility, private ownership of banks and stability of money market rates. Another reason for slow pass-through put forth by de Bondt, Mojon, and Valla (2005) is that at times the short term rates of banks are linked to long term market rates. Anticipated changes in monetary policy is another source of slow-pass through identified by Sander and Kleimeier (2006).

Hanan and Berger (1991) find that pass-through to deposit rate is asymmetric for upward and downward revision of policy rate. To explain the result the authors argue that typically the customers respond with a lag to change in prices. If the deposit rates are changed today then the full expected response in the shape of more deposits will be realised after sometime, say, a month. During this lag period the banks pay more interest to depositors without realising the corresponding benefits in the shape of larger deposit volume. Similarly when the interest rate on deposits is reduced, even the interest sensitive customers, will take time to withdraw their deposits. During this lag-period the bank would pay lesser interest without incurring corresponding penalty in the shape of reduced deposit volume. Given the foregoing HB argues that increasing interest rate on deposits is harmful for banks in while decreasing interest rate is likely to prove fruitful, at least in the short run. This makes the pass through asymmetric.

A problem that arises in empirical estimation of pass-through from policy rate to deposit and lending rates is of maturity mismatch. The issue has been raised by Mojon (2000) and Bondt (2005). The problem is that the instrument which reflects the policy rate policy rate and the money market rate are of short term maturity while the deposit and lending rates could be of longer maturity as well. Bondt (2002) avoids the maturity mismatch problem by examining money market rates of comparable maturity.

3. EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK

To estimate our model we use transfer function approach developed by Box, Jenkins, and Reinsel (1994). The transfer function model in essence shows how a movement in the independent variable influences the changes in dependent variable. The model allows identification of the lag structure with which the independent variable influences the dependent variable and also measure the magnitude of influence. The model is one of the most widely used in linear times series estimation. The methodology is explained below.

Let us assume that an independent variable [x.sub.t] and dependent variable [y.sub.t] are jointly stationary. Now [y.sub.t] can be written as:

[y.sub.t] = [z.sub.t] + [N.sub.t]

Where [z.sub.t] contains that part of [y.sub.t] which can be explained in term of [x.sub.t], and [N.sub.t] is an error or noise term which is auto-correlated but is independent of the input series [x.sub.t]. Here, both y, and [x.sub.t] are observable, while [z.sub.t] is not observable. Suppose the dynamic relationship between [z.sub.t] and [x.sub.t] is represented as:

[z.sub.t] = ([[omega].sub.0] - [[omega].sub.1] - ... - [[omega].sub.s][B.sup.s]/1 - [[delta].sub.1]B - ... - [B.sub.r][B.sup.r]) [x.sub.t-b]

Let us call v(B)= [[omega](B)/[delta](B)][B.sup.b] "the transfer function" where b represents the lag period. The above equation can be written as:

[y.sub.t] = v(B)[x.sub.t] + [N.sub.t]

Mostly the term [N.sub.t] is non-stationary and it can be represented as [N.sub.t] = c + [[theta](B)/[phi](B)][a.sub.t].

Now the model may be written as:

[y.sub.t] = c + v (B) [xsub.t] + [[theta](B)/[phi] (B)] [a.sub.t]

In practice, we normally do not know the form of v (B) and the structure of [N.sub.t] i.e. the parameters r, s, b, p, and q and have to identify them through the analyses of data on variables x, and yr.

The identification consists of pre-whitening the independent as well as dependent variable on the basis of ARMA (p, q) of independent variable. Using correlogram, autocorrelation functions, and partial correlation functions of the pre-whitened variables, the best fitted model is selected for estimation. (1)

Using the methodology discussed above we have estimated the pass through of the six month treasury bill rate to six month KIBOR, Six month deposit rate and weighted average lending rate. For the pass through to KIBOR the data span September 2001-February 2009 and the data frequency is monthly. The reason for the shorter data span is that the KIBOR rate was introduced in 2001. For the lending and deposit rates we have used the span June 1991--June 2008 and the data frequency is biannual. The reason for the choice of frequency in this case is dictated by data availability. Over the recent years the State Bank has used discount rate as an instrument of the policy and it would have been more appropriate to estimate the pass through from the discount rate rather than the treasury bill rate. However following two reasons do not allow the construction of a long enough time series of change in discount rate. First, the changes in discount rate have been occurring at irregular intervals besides the State bank's active use of the discount the rate as an instrument of monetary policy is not too old.

4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

4.1. Pass Through from TBR to KIBOR Rate

We estimate the pass through from the 6-month Treasury bill rate to 6-month KIBOR rate using data with monthly frequency. The data span is September 2001-February 2009. The State Bank of Pakistan is now using discount rate as a policy instrument however since the changes in discount rate occurs only at discreet interval we have used 6-month Treasury bill rate as proxy for policy rate.

The first step under the Box Jenkins, transfer function approach is to fit an ARIMA model to the {[DELTA]TBR} series. We obtain the Autocorrelation Function (ACF), Partial Autocorrelation Function (PACF) and the respective correlograms for [DELTA]TBR. These are respectively presented below in Tables l(a and b) and Figures 1(a and b).

[FIGURE 1(a) OMITTED]

[FIGURE 1(b) OMITTED]

Tables 1(a and b), and Figures 1(a and b) show that ACF and PACF are respectively significant up to 3rd and 2nd lag. This suggests ARMA (2, 3) for [DELTA]TBR. The most plausible models for ATBR then is:

[DELTA]TBR =[beta]1[DELTA]TBRt - 1 + [beta]2[DELTA]TBRt -2 + [epsilon]zt (2)

The next step is to obtain pre-whitened series for our dependent variable ([DELTA]TBR) and Independent variable ([DELTA]KIBOR)

Filtered (pre-whitened) series for [DELTA]TBR is:

[alpha]t = [DELTA]TBR - 0.32[DELTA]TBRt -1- 0.31[DELTA]TBRt - 2 (3)

Pre-whitened series for [DELTA]KIBOR is:

[beta]t = [DELTA]KIBOR - 0.32[DELTA]KIBOR t -1- 0.31 [DELTA]KIBORt -2 (4)

Next we obtain cross-correlation and cross-correlogram between our two pre-whitened series: at and [beta]t. These are presented below respectively in Table 2 and Figure 2.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

Table 2 and Figure 2 show that [rho](0), [rho](1) and [rho](2) are statistically significant. Next based on cross-correlation between pre-whitened series at and [beta]t, we select the following model:

[beta]t = al [beta]t-1 + b1[alpha]t +b2[alpha]t-1 + b3[alpha]t-2 + et (4)

Estimation of (4) yields:

[beta]t = 0.09[beta]t- 1 +0.83[alpha]t+0.46[alpha]t- 1-0.22[alpha]t-2 +et (5)

Then we obtain et as:

[e.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.t] (0.83 + 0.46L - 0.22[L.sup.2])/[1 - 0.09] [[alpha].sub.t]

The ACF, PACF of the error term et and the relevant correlograms are presented Below in Tablesd 3(a and b) and Figures 3 (a and b) respectively.

[FIGURE 3(a) OMITTED]

[FIGURE 3(b) OMITTED]

On the basis of ACF and PACF of et the preliminary model for et is:

et = -0.93et-2-0.39 et-4-0.32 et-6 +(0.52[L.sup.2]+ 0.43[Lsup.6]) [epsilon]t (6)

Therefore our tentative Transfer Function is:

[DELTA][KIBOR.sub.t] = (0.83 + 0.46[L.sup.4] - 0.22[L.sup.6]]/[1 - 0.08L] [[alpha].sub.t][DELTA]KIBOR + (0.52[L.sup.2] + 0.43[L.sup.4])/[1 + 0.93[L.sup.2] + 0.39[L.sup.4] + 0.32[L.sup.6] et (7)

Then we expand the first term in Equation 6 using binomial expansion. This yields:

[DELTA][KIBOR.sub.t] = [[1 - 0.08L].sup.-1] [[0.83 + 0.46[L.sup.4] - 0.22[L.sup.6]][DELTA]TBR + (0.52[L.sup.2] + 0.43[L.sup.4])/ [1 + 0.93 [L.sup.2] + 0.39 [L.sup.4] + 0.32 [L.sup.6]] et

Or

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)

It is evident from the Equation 8 that 83 percent of the change in 6-month treasury bill rate is passed on to the 6-month KIBOR during the first month. Slight overshooting is observed in the following months, which is corrected later on.

We employ similar procedure to estimate the pass through for the weighted average six month deposit rate and weighted average lending rate. The final equations for the two are indicated and discussed below. (2)

4.2. Pass-through from Treasury Bill Rate to Lending Rate

The pass of the 6-month Treasury bill rate to the weighted average lending rate has been estimated for the period June 1991 to June 2008. The data frequency is bi-annual. The transfer function developed for the weighted average rate of return on loans using procedure similar to the one used for KIBOR is:

[DELTA][WARRA.sub.t] = (0.16[L.sup.2] + 0.27 [L.sup.3]) [DELTA]TBR + (0.55L + 0.43[L.sup.2])/[1 + 0.71L + 0.75 [[L.sup.2]].sup.et] (9)

The equation shows that a total of 43 percent the change in six Treasury bill rate is passed is passed on to the lending rate (16 percent with a lag of two periods and 27 percent with a lag of three periods, each period being of six months) with a lag of one to one and a half year. The total pass-through to the lending rate being only 43 percent we can say that the lending rate exhibit rigidity.

4.3. Pass-through from Treasury Bill Rate to Six-month Deposit Rate

The pass through of changes in 6-month Treasury bill rate to the 6-month weighted average deposit rate has been estimated for the Period June 1991 to June 2008. The frequency used is bi-annual. The transfer function developed for six-month weighted average rate of return on deposits, using procedure described earlier for KIBOR is:

[DELTA][WARRD.sub.t] = (0.16[L.sup.2])[DELTA]TBR - (0.86[L.sup.4])/[1 + 0.47 [L.sup.2]] (10)

The transfer function described above shows that that only 16 percent of the change in treasury bill rate is passed on to the weighted average rate of deposits and that too with a lag of two periods, that is, after one year.

4.4. Reasons for Slow and Asymmetric Pass Through

While the pass through for the lending rate is 43 percent the pass through for the deposit rate is only 16 percent. This implies that banks are slow to change deposit rates relative to lending rates. The question is who benefits from asymmetric in pass through between lending and deposit rates. The answer is; it depends whether the asymmetry occurs in an environment of increasing interest rate or when the interest rate are on the decline. If the policy rate is on the rise, greater pass through to the lending rate relative to deposit rate would increase the interest margin of the banks therefore the banks seek to benefit from asymmetry while the converse holds true when the interest rates are on the decline. The greater pass through observed for lending rate relative to deposit rate leads one to suspect that, by and large, the asymmetry has occurred in an environment of increasing interest rates. Our data span covers a period of 17 years (June 1990-June 2008). During this period there have three major episodes of change in interest Treasury bill rate (Table 4).

It is evident from Table 4 that out of the 17 years data span, the treasury bill rate has followed an upward course for a period of twelve years while the downward trend has been observed for only five years. Moreover the magnitude of increase has also been greater than the decline. This explains why the pass through to the lending rate is greater than pass through to deposit rate: because in an environment of increasing interest rates greater pass through to lending rate increases the interest income of the banks but the cost of funds does not increase by corresponding magnitude. Therefore the greater pass through to lending rates suits the banks.

Pegging of the lending rate to KIBOR is another important reason that explains the relatively greater pass through to the lending rate. The State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) has instructed all the banks to link their corporate lending rate to KIBOR. Moreover loans for commodity operations to government departments have also been linked with KIBOR of appropriate tenor since 2006. Loans against export refinance facility, the subsidised credit to exporters, have also been pegged to the Treasury bill rate. Pegging of lending rate to these reference rate quickens the pass through, because as soon as the reference rate (KIBOR or Treasury bill rate) the change in lending rate (for fresh loans) invariably fallows.

One reason for the slow pass through observed for weighted average lending rate and 6 month deposit rate is that these rates are for outstanding loans and deposits, which includes loans extended and deposits mobilised at the rates prevailing before the change in treasury bill rate. It is note worthy here that the volume of loans extended and deposit mobilised at previous rates is understandably much higher than the fresh loans extended and deposits mobilised after the change in the treasury bill rate. This brings us to the question: What manner of quoting interest/return on loans and deposits would speed up the transmission mechanism of monetary policy? The answer is that the floating rate, (3) that is, the rate specified with reference to some other interest rate, for example KIBOR will facilitate pass-through of interest rate from policy rate to lending and deposit rates. We have observed that the pass through to the KIBOR is very fast, therefore if all lending rates of banks are quoted in terms of KIBOR plus and deposits rates are quoted as KIBOR minus then the lending and deposit rates will change as soon as the KIBOR changes.

4.5. Slow Pass through to Deposit Rate

One reason for the slow pass-through to the deposit rate could be that behaviour of the depositors is not sufficiently interest sensitive. This is evident from the overtime composition of the total deposits, shown in Table 5.

If the depositors are not too sensitive to interest rate changes then one may expect that the banks can get away with incomplete pass through and delayed pass through. It is evident from table that majority of the deposits are held either in current account or savings account. The current account earns no interest while very little interest is paid to the holders of savings account. Given the failure of the banks to raise the rate on their own the SBP mandated only about a year ago to pay a minimum of 5 percent interest on savings account. This speaks volumes about the gravity of the situation regarding the low pass through to the deposit rate. It is clear from the composition of the deposits shown in Table 5 that the behaviour of the depositors holding a sizable deposit volume is not interest sensitive. Given the less sensitivity of the depositors to interest rate changes the banks in Pakistan have been able to get away with incomplete pass through, and delayed pass through on deposit rates. Hence the slow pass through to deposit rates. To quicken the pass through to deposit rates it is important that like the lending rate the deposit may also be linked KIBOR. However to implement such a regime effectively requires greater ability on the part of potential borrowers and depositors to forecast interest rate changes and mental preparedness that change in policy rate at times may adversely influence the depositors or the borrowers.

5. MACROECONOMIC IMPLICATION OF LIMITED PASS-THROUGH

Pass-through and Taylor Principle

Incomplete pass-through has macroeconomic implications. One consequence is that this alters the popular Taylor rule [Kwapil and Scharler (2006)]. The rule, in essence implies that to maintain equilibrium, for every one percentage point increase in inflation, the interest rate should rise by more than one percentage point. The rule also implies that if the nominal interest rate does not rise, as suggested by Taylor, a rise in expected inflation causes the real interest rate to decline. The resultant stimulus to aggregate demand causes the inflation to rise further and thus initial expectations are fulfilled. Kwapil and Scharler contend that that an economy subject this type of shock will be highly unstable. To understand how the incomplete pass-through alters the Taylor rule let us very briefly examine the Taylor rule. The rule can be written as:

[i.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.[tau]] + [r.sub.[tau].sup.*] + [a.sub.[pi]] ([[pi].sub.[tau]] - [[pi].sup.*.sub.[tau]]) + [a.sub.y] ([y.sub.t] - [y.sup.*.sub.[tau]])

Where [i.sub.[tau]] is the targeted short term interest rate, [[pi].sub.[tau]] and [[pi].sub.[tau]].sup.*] are the actual and targeted inflation rate respectively, [r.sub.[tau]].sup.*] is the assumed equilibrium interest rate ([y.sub.t] - [y.sub.t.sup.*])is the output gap. To satisfy Taylor rule [a.sub.[pi]] > 0. If this does not hold the real interest rate would decline with the change in policy rate. Kwapil and Scharler (2006) argue that limited pass-through alters the Taylor rule--because even if the nominal interest rate rises by 1 percentage point, still in the face of incomplete pass through, the pass-through to market rates rate will be less than 1 percentage point. The Taylor rule, according to Kawpil and Scharler (2006) under an environment of incomplete pass-through, will be satisfied if as [lambda] > 0, where [lambda], is the long-run pass-through to retail rates. Kwapil and Scharler (2006) citing various studies suggests that since the value as is sufficiently greater than one (in the rage 1.8-2.15) for US and euro area therefore even in the face of incomplete pass through the monetary policy rules will most probably satisfy the conditions for determinate equilibrium in US and euro area. For Pakistan only one study [Malik and Ahmad (2007)] has estimated the Taylor rule. The value of [a.sub[pi]] according to this study is 0.51. If we take the pass through to the lending rate as 0.43, as worked out in this study, then the value of [a.sub.[pi]] [lambda] comes to only 0.22. Clearly Pakistan's economy is far from satisfying the modified Taylor rule. Irrespective of the fact that whether the SBP is following the Taylor principle for monetary management, the low value [a.sub.[pi]] coupled with limited pass-through has made the monetary management more difficult for the authorities.

6. CONCLUSIONS

We have estimated the pass through from six month treasury bill rate to different market rates including KIBOR, six month deposit rate and weighted average lending rate. While the pass through of the 6-month Treasury bill rate to 6-month KIBOR is almost complete and immediate the pass through to the 6-month deposit rate and weighted average lending rate takes from a year to year and a half. Moreover the pass through to lending rate is much greater than the one observed for the deposit rate. Less interest sensitive behaviour of the depositors has enabled the banks to get away with slow pass through to deposits. On the other hand pegging of the rate on corporate loans and rate on loans for commodity operation to KIBOR has increased the pace of pass through to lending rate. This implies pegging can enhance the pass through, and therefore the effectiveness of the interest rate channel of monetary policy transmission. Moreover if the deposit rates, like lending rates for certain types of loans, are also pegged to KIBOR the pass through to the deposit rate would also increase and the asymmetry issue will be taken care off. However such pegging requires greater ability of the bank's customers to forecast interest rate changes and be prepared for the worst as well. Finally we also showed that less than one for one pass through to the lending rate makes it more difficult to apply even if one attempts to apply the Taylor rule in Pakistan.

REFERENCES

Allen, F. and D. Gale (2000) Comparing Financial Systems. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Berger, A. and G. Udell (1992) Some Evidence on the Empirical Significance of Credit Rationing. Journal of Political Economy 25, 291-299.

Bondt, G. (2002) Retail Bank Interest Rate Pass-through: New Evidence at the Euro Area Level. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. (ECB Working Paper No. 136.)

Bondt, G., B. Mojon, and N. Valla (2005) Term Structure and the Sluggishness of Retail Bank Interest Rates in Euro Area Countries. (ECB Working Paper Series No. 518.)

Box, J., G. Jenkins, and G. Reinsel (1994) Time Series Analysis. 373-84. Prentice-Hall.

Cottarelli, C. and Angeliki Kourelis (1994) Financial Structure, Bank Lending Rates, and the Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy. IMF Staff Papers 41:4, 587-623.

Donnay, M. and H. Degryse (2001) Bank Lending Rate Pass-through and Differences in the Transmission of a Single EMU Monetary Policy. (Discussion Paper No. 0117.)

Gropp, R., C. Kok Sorensen, and J. Lichtenberger (2007) The Dynamics of Bank Spreads and Financial Structure. (ECB Working Paper Series No. 714.)

Hanan, T. and Allen Berger (1991) The Rigidity of Prices: Evidence from the Banking Industry. American Economic Review 81:4, 938-945.

Heinemann, F. and M. Sch"uler (2002) Integration Benefits on EU Retail Credit Markets--Evidence from Interest Rate Pass-Through. (ZEW Discussion Paper No. 02-26.)

Hofmann, B. (2003) EMU and the Transmission of Monetary Policy: Evidence from Business Lending Rates. ZEI University of Bonn.

Hofmann, B. and P. Mizen (2004) Interest Rate Pass-through and Monetary Transmission: Evidence from Individual Financial Institutions' Retail Rates. Economica 71, 99-123.

Kwapil, C. and Johann Scharler (2006) Limited Pass-through from Policy to Retail Interest Rates: Empirical Evidence and Macroeconomic Implications. Monetary Policy and the Economy Q4/06, 26-36.

Malik, Wasim Shahid and Ather Maqsood Ahmed (2007) The Taylor Rule and the Macroeconomic Performance in Pakistan. (PIDE Working Papers No. 34.)

Mojon, B. (2000) Financial Structure and the Interest Rate Channel of ECB Monetary Policy. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. (ECB Working Paper No. 40.)

Qayyum, Abdul, Sajawal Khan, and M. Idrees Khawaja (2005) Interest Rate Pass-through in Pakistan: Evidence from Transfer Function Approach. The Pakistan Development Review 44:4, 975-998.

Sander, H. and S. Kleimeier (2002) Asymmetric Adjustment of Commercial Bank Interest Rates in the Euro Area: An Empirical Investigation into Interest Rate Pass-through. Kredit und Kapital 2, 161-92.

Sander, H. and S. Kleimeier (2006) Convergence of Interest Rate Pass-through in a Wider Euro Zone? Economic Systems 30, 405-23.

Schwarzbauer, W. (2006) Financial Structure and Its Impact on the Convergence of Interest Rate Pass-Through in Europe: A Time-varying Interest Rate Pass-through Model. Institute for Advanced Studies. (Economics Series 191.)

Toolsema, L. A., J. Sturm, and J. de Haan (2001) Convergence of Monetary Transmission in EMU: New Evidence. (CESifo Working Paper No. 465.)

Weyth, M. A. (2002) The Pass-through from Market Interest Rates to Bank Lending Rates in Germany. Deutsche Bundesbank. (Economic Research Centre Discussion Paper 11/02.)

M. Idrees Khawaja <khawajami@yahoo.com> is Consultant at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Sajawal Khan <sajawal.khan@sbp.org.pk> is Research Economist, Research Department, State Bank of Pakistan, Karachi.

(1) For detail see Box and Jenkins (1994).

(2) Detailed results for weighted average six months deposit rate and weighted average lending rate are available from the authors upon request.

(3) Floating rate implies that rate for the entire term is not quoted when the loans or deposits are contracted, rather the rate changes (after a specified interval) with the change in reference rate to which the deposit or lending rate is pegged.
Table 1(a)

Auto Correlation Function (ACF) of [DELTA]TBR

 [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)
Q-Stat. 0.468 0.474 0.302 0.170 0.144

 [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9) [rho](10)
Q-Stat. 0.091 0.096 0.055 0.040 0.099

 [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14) [rho](15)
Q-Stat. 0.142 0.145 0.225 0.176 0.1270

 [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)
Q-Stat. 0.063 0.120 0.039

Table 1(b)
Partial Auto Correlation Function (PA CF) of ATBR

Q-Stat. [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)
 0.468 0.327 -0.001 -0.114 0.026

Q-Stat. [rho](10) [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14)
 0.107 0.129 0.011 0.095 0.002

Q-Stat. [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9)
 0.031 -0.027 -0.023

Q-Stat. [rho](15) [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)
 0.072 0.061 -0.062 0.026

Table 2

Cross Correlation between at and [beta]t

 [rho](0) [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4)

S.Dev. 0.637 0.327 -0.257 0.048 -0.019
 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014

 [rho](5) [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9)

S.Dev. -0.073 0.100 0.020 -0.05 -0.094
 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014

 [rho](10) [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14)

S.Dev. -0.023 0.012 -0.011 0.037 0.010
 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014

 [rho](15) [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18) [rho](19)

S.Dev. -0.055 -0.024 -0.067 0.002 0.094
 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014 0.014

Table 3(a)

Auto Correlation Function (ACF) of et

 [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)

Q-Stat. -0.022 -0.360 -0.060 -0.120 -0.019

 [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9) [rho](10)

Q-Stat. 0.200 0.026 -0.014 -0.095 -0.140

 [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14) [rho](15)

Q-Stat. 0.014 0.113 0.039 0.003 -0.089

 [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)

Q-Stat. -0.113 0.028 0.103

Table 3(b)

Partil auto correlation Function (PACF) of et

 [rho](1) [rho](2) [rho](3) [rho](4) [rho](5)

Q-St(a)t. -0.022 -0.361 -0.090 -0.297 -0.132

 [rho](6) [rho](7) [rho](8) [rho](9) [rho](10)

Q-St(a)t. 0.019 -0.055 0.051 -0.113 -0.117

 [rho](11) [rho](12) [rho](13) [rho](14) [rho](15)

Q-St(a)t. -0.093 0.041 -0.044 -0.040 -0.105

 [rho](16) [rho](17) [rho](18)

Q-St(a)t. -0.136 -0.087 -0.051

Table 4
Episodes of Changes in Treasury Bill Rate

 Number of Direction of Change Change
Time Period Years in Treasury Bill rate (Basis points)

June 90-June 98 8 Upward 641
Dec 98-Dec 03 5 Downward 1411
June 04-June 08 4 Upward 1232

Table 5
Trend in Composition of Deposits

 Type of Deposits
Year
(June) Current Savings Non Fixed

1998 16 46 66
1998 15 47 68
2000 15 51 71
2001 18 51 73
2002 20 53 76
2003 21 57 81
2004 24 56 84
2005 26 52 81
2006 26 47 76
2008 25 43 70

 Type of
 Deposits

Year T. Bill
(June) Fixed Rate

1998 34 15.75
1998 32 10.6
2000 29 7.14
2001 27 12.88
2002 24 6.33
2003 19 3.84
2004 16 2.08
2005 19 7.92
2006 24 8.45
2008 30 9.02
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有