Do public expenditure and macroeconomic uncertainty matter to private investment? Evidence from Pakistan.
Ahmed, Imtiaz ; Qayyum, Abdul
1. INTRODUCTION
The study attempts to investigate the determinants of private fixed
investment in Pakistan and determine the interrelationship between
public and private investment. Policy-makers in developing countries
generally believe that private investment would be slow-moving due to
the lack of socio-economic infrastructure and insufficient government
investment in infrastructure and other basic industries.
Keynesians (1936) believed that there is need for government
intervention to activate and regulate saving and investment behaviour of
the society. Generally, it is argued that public investment either
crowd-in or crowd-out private investment. Therefore, the impact of
public expenditures on private investment has received a considerable
attention, both in developed and developing countries. The lack of
strong empirical evidences may lead to irrational policy advice to Least
Developed Countries that are presently struggling for the improvement of
structural imbalances. They may require reducing large fiscal deficits,
but they do not have a clear picture as to which components of
expenditures may be minimised and which can be enhanced to encourage
private investment activities [Hermes and Lensink (2001)]. Thus, an
in-depth analysis of effects of public development and non-development
expenditures on private fixed investment is required.
A number of studies [e.g., Akkina and Celibi (2002); Mamatzakis
(2001); Ghura and Goodwin (2000); Ramirez (1994); Oshikaya (1994);
Shafik (1992); Greene and Villanuva (1991)] have examined the
relationship between public and private investment for developing
countries. However, evidence on these countries is not clear-cut. Most
studies [e.g., Aschauer (1989); Greene and Villanuva (1991); Munnell
(1992); Shafik (1992); Oshikaya (1994); Ramirez (1994); Ghura and
Goodwin (2000) and Mamatzakis (2001)] find a positive relationship.
However, some studies [e.g., Akkina and Celibi (2002); Pereira and
Sagales (2001); Williams and Darius (1998); Wai and Wang (1982)] have
reported a negative relationship.
Studies on private investment behaviour in Pakistan [e.g., Khan
(1988) and Naqvi, et al. (1993)] estimated only disaggregated private
investment functions using conventional econometric methodologies.
Looney (1997) estimated the relationship between private investment in
large-scale manufacturing and infrastructure, applying the Engle-Granger
(1987) methodology. These "studies paid no attention to dynamic
specification of the private investment function and the stability of
the estimated relationships. Naqvi (2002) estimated the relationship
between aggregate public and private fixed capital formation for
Pakistan, but did test stability of preferred function.
In Pakistan, over the past 60 years, GDP growth remained on average
at 5 percent per annum, while investment was around 17 to 18 percent of
GDP which was relatively low as compared to the neighbouring developing
economies. In 1949-50 investment level was just 4.1 percent of GDP, but
at the end of 1950s it had risen to around 10 percent of GDP. It further
increased to 22.3 percent of GDP in 1964-65 because of increase in
foreign aid, improvement in infrastructure level, and profitable
investment opportunities in various sectors of the economy. However,
after 1965 Pak-Indo war, the investment declined sharply and reached at
15.6 percent of GDP in 1969-70. This is mainly due to decline in capital
inflows. Furthermore, manufacturing sector suffered from lack of demand,
private sector was reluctant to invest in new industries and limited
possibility of further extension in existing industries.
In early 1970s, private investment was curtailed due to the
large-scale nationalisation. However, in the same period, public
investment in non-traditional sectors increased rapidly. This led to a
rise in aggregate investment in the 1970s that lies between 12 and 20
percent of the GDP. Despite the reversal of the policies from
nationalisation to denationalisation in the late 1970s, private
investment remained low during 1980s and started increasing after
1987-88. Investment reached at 20.6 percent of GDP in 1992-93.
Subsequently, due to the inconsistency and discontinuity of policies
structural adjustment programmes curtailed development expenditures
[Kemal (2002)]. Total investment in 2001-02 was only 13.9 percent of the
GDP. The deceleration in the public sector investment was more
pronounced than the private sector.
Fixed investment is the main factor to sustain economic growth. In
fiscal year 2004-05, gross fixed capital formation increased by 15.6
percent. However, there was a considerable change in the composition of
private and public investment. Private sector investment increased by
19.3 percent in 2004-05. The private consumer demand backed investment
and supported the major macroeconomic target of the economy.
Section 2 describes theoretical foundation and specification of
econometric model. Section 3 deals with estimation methodology and data
issues. Estimated results of Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error
Correction Mechanism (ECM) are given in Section 4. Finally, conclusions
and policy implications drawn from the analysis are presented in Section
5.
2. ECONOMETRIC MODEL
Theories of investment postulate that investment mainly depends on
interest rate, income factor, and uncertainty variables. Public
development expenditures and public consumption expenditures are
incorporated to capture explicit role of public expenditures in the
determination of investment [Aschauer (1989)]. The interest rate
negatively affects private investment because when interest rate
increases, the returns on investment decline. Private investment is
affected positively by the income level, as higher income level would
tend to dedicate more resources to finance investment. (1) Public
development expenditure provides basic infrastructure to the private
sector and prompts private investment. Whereas the public consumption
expenditures are a substitute of private investment, it is expected that
this type of expenditure may negatively affect private investment.
Private investment is considered to be negatively related to uncertainty
as the fixed investment decisions cannot be undone if future events turn
out to be unfavourable [Dixit and Pindyck (1994)]. Capital once
installed is immobile as compared to labour. (2) There are number of
variable that could be used to capture uncertainty such as lack market
premium, fiscal deficit/surplus and the change in inflation, among
others. The inflation is often taken as a summary measure of the overall
macroeconomic stance, and hence the volatility of its unpredictable
component can be viewed as an indicator of overall macroeconomic
uncertainty [e.g., Eberly (1993)]. Following Able (1980), Pindyck and
Solimano (1993) and Eberly (1993) we use change in inflation as a proxy
to measure uncertainty because inflation is used as a measure of the
overall macroeconomic stance and the volatility of inflation as an
indicates macroeconomic uncertainty.
The function of private investment can be written as:
(1) [PI.sub.t] = F([R.sub.t], [Y.sub.t], [CG.sub.t], [IG.sub.t],
[UN.sub.t], [[epsilon].sub.t])
Where
[PI.sub.t] = Real Private Fixed Investment
[Y.sub.t] = Real Gross domestic product
[IG.sub.t] = Real Public development expenditure
[CG.sub.t] = Real Public consumption expenditure
[R.sub.t] = Interest rate (weighted average rate of return on
advances)
[UN.sub.t] = Uncertainty measure (derived by percentage change in
the annual
inflation rate, where inflation rate is derived from consumer price
index)
[[epsilon].sub.t] = Random error term assumed to be independent and
identically distributed (iid).
Assuming individual time series are non-stationary and the private
investment and its determinants are cointegrated, the dynamic private
investment model can be represented by error correction mechanism. The
relationship between cointegration and error correction mechanism has
already been proved in the Granger representation theorem [Engle and
Granger (1987)].
Following Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) the
dynamic error correction private investment function is thus approached
through the process of autoregressive-distributed lags (ADL). Therefore,
from the above Equation (1) the following ADL formulation could be
achieved.
(2) [X.sub.t] = [micro] + [[PI].sub.1] [X.sub.t-1] + [[PI].sub.2]
[X.sub.t-2] + -- + [[PI].sub.k] [X.sub.t-k] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
Where [X.sub.t] is a vector of variables included in the model,
[micro] is a vector of constant term and [[epsilon].sub.t] is iid with
(0, [[sigma].sup.2]) disturbance term. From this model, using
[DELTA]=1-L, where L is the lag operator, we can deduce the following
dynamic error correction model (ECM) of real private investment.
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where
(4) [[GAMMA].sub.i] =-(I-[[PI].sub.1]-...[[PI].sub.i] i = 1, 2,
3,...,k-1
and
(5) [PI] =-(I-[[PI].sub.1]-...-[[PI].sub.1]
This model includes variables both in levels and in differences. If
individual series have unit root at frequency one, that is they are
individually I (1), then first difference of the series are stationary.
Moreover, if there is a cointegrating relationship between I (1)
variables then linear combination of these variables is I (0). It means
that [[PI].sub.i][X.sub.t] term is stationary. Thus all variables
included in the error corrects model are stationary. Therefore, this
equation can be estimated with the ordinary least square method (3)
[Granger and Lee (1989)]. The error correction model captures the
short-run dynamic of the private investment. The analysis of matrix I]
of Equation 3 is crucial to investigate the long run relationship among
the private investment and its determinants. It contains all relevant
information that is number of cointegrating relationships among the
variables. (4) The long-run matrix ([PI]) can be factorised as (p x r)
matrices of it and [beta] such as [PI] = [alpha][beta]'. In the
presence of cointegrating relationship, vector [beta] has property that
[beta]'[X.sub.t] is stationary, though [X.sub.t] itself is
non-stationary. The vector a is a loading vector, the elements of which
weight each cointegrating relationship in each of the p equation of the
system. The expected sign of error correction parameter is negative. It
gives the speed of adjustment towards state of equilibrium.
The vector [[beta].sub.t] (where i = 1, 2 .... 5) may be
interpreted as the long run cointegrated relationship between aggregate
private investment, real gross domestic product, real public development
expenditures, real public consumption expenditures, rate of interest on
advances and the macroeconomic uncertainty. The theoretical expectations
about the sign of estimated parameters are [[beta].sub.1] > 0,
[[beta].sub.2] > 0, and [[beta].sub.3], [[beta].sub.4],
[[beta].sub.5] < 0. If [[beta].sub.2] > 0, this implies
complementarity hypothesis is true for the public development
expenditures. Public consumption has negative impact on private
investment if [[beta].sub.3] < 0. The [[beta].sub.4] < 0 shows
interest rate is negatively related to private investment and
[[beta].sub.5] < 0 shows that macroeconomic instability and
uncertainty negatively affect private investment.
3. ECONOMETRIC METHODOLOGY
We apply the following three-step methodology [Qayyum (2002)] to
achieve the stable dynamic private investment function.
Step I. The univariate statistical analysis of a time series.
Step II. The multivariate cointegration analysis and the estimation
of the long-rum private investment function by using the Johansen (1988)
maximum likelihood method.
Step III. To obtain a parsimonious short-run dynamic private
investment function through the error correction mechanism.
Step I. Univariate Analysis
In the process of model specification it is assumed that individual
data series are non-stationary. If a variable is stationary, it is said
to be integrated of order zero I(0). If a variable is not stationary at
level but can be transformed into stationary by taking first difference,
it is said to be integrated of order one, or I(1). To test the presence
of unit root in univariate time series, we applied following Augmented
Dickey-Fuller (1979, 1981) and Phillips-Perron (1988) tests.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test considers following regression
equation;
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Where [X.sub.t] is any time series to be tested for unit roots, t
is time trend and [[epsilon].sub.t] is white noise error term. In case i
= 0, it is simple Dickey and Fuller (1979, 1981) test. (5) The lagged
dependent variables in the ADF regression equation are included until
the error term becomes white noise. We test the hypothesis that 6=0 in
Equation 6 by t-test.
Phillips and Perron (PP) have developed a non-parametric method of
detecting whether a time series contain a unit root. Existence of unit
root in a series, say X,, is identified by estimating the following
regressions;
(7) [DELTA][X.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [alpha][X.sub.t-1] +
[u.sub.1t]
(8) [DELTA][X.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1t] +
[beta][X.sub.t-1] + [u.sub.2t]
Where [DELTA][X.sub.t] denotes first difference of [X.sub.t] and t
is a deterministic time trend. In Equation (7), for [X.sub.t] to
stationary, the adjusted t-statistic, i.e., Z([t.sub.[alpha]]) should be
negative and significantly different from zero. For [X.sub.t] to be
stationary around a linear trend in Equation (8), the adjusted
t-statistic, i.e. Z([t.sub.[beta]]) should be negative and significantly
different from zero. The critical values for Philips-Perron statistics
are precisely those that are given for Dickey-Fuller test.
Step II. Multivariate Cointegration Analysis
Multivariate cointegration analysis starts with the testing of
hypothesis of no cointegration between the private investment and its
determinants. To analyse the prospects of existence of cointegrating
relationship between private investment and its determinants Johansen
(1988) maximum likelihood method is applied. Main hypothesis to be
considered is that there exist r cointegration vector(s). Inference on
the "r" of the system is conducted through the method of
likelihood ratio (LR) test. The null of
(9) [H.sub.0(r)]: rank([PI]) [less than or equal to] r (9)
is tested against the unrestricted alternative of
(10) [H.sub.1(r)]: rank([PI]) = P
by the trace statistic. Similarly, the validity of [H.sub.0(r)
against the alternative of [H.sub.1(r+1) is tested by looking at the
maximal eigenvalue statistic. (6) The likelihood ratio (LR) test
statistic for the hypothesis that there are at most "r"
cointegrating vector is:
(11) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Where [??].sub.r+1] [??].sub.p] are the (p-r) smallest canonical
correlations. Johansen (1988) proved that these statistics are
asymptotically distributed as [chi square] with r (p-r) degrees of
freedom. The precise relevant critical values are provided by
OsterwaldLenum (1992). Likelihood Ratio (LR) test is applied to test the
significance of estimated parameters in cointegrating relationship
between the private investment and its determinants. The LR test has
Chi-square distribution and the Chi-square values are calculated by
imposing zero restriction on the estimated coefficients of individual
variables.
Step III. Short-run Dynamic Private Investment Function
This step involves estimation of parsimonious private investment
function specified using the error correction mechanism, that is
Equation (3). Step I indicates the variables that required to be
differenced to achieve stationarity and Step II provides estimates of
the long-run private investment function. It also indicates variables
that are placed in the error correction term that is [PI][X.sub.t-k]. If
these variables are found to be cointegrated, then the combination of
the integrated variables is stationary i.e., I(0). Therefore, the
residual term called error correction term is stationary.
The estimation of dynamic model starts with the unrestricted
general model. In which every variable enters with a predetermined optimal lag length. As all variables of the model are stationary, the
function is estimated by OLS. The preferred dynamic private investment
function would pass a number of diagnostic tests. To test the hypothesis
of no serial correlation in the residual term the Lagrange Multiplier
(LM) test is applied. The Jarque-Bera (1987) test is applied to examine
the normality of the residual term. The LM version of Hetroskedasticity
test and ARCH test are also used. The Brown, et al. (1975), CUSUM and
CUSUM of Squares test of stability are also applied to test the
stability of estimated functions.
3.1. Definition of Variables and Data Sources
The data on variables such as Aggregate Private Investment (P/t),
Gross Domestic Product ([GDP.sub.t]), Public development expenditure
([IG.sub.t]), and Public Consumption Expenditure ([CG.sub.t]) are
collected at constant market prices of 1980-81. The data for Advancing
Rate (At) and Consumer Price Index are taken from various issues of
Annual Report of the State Bank of Pakistan and data for all other
series are obtained from Pakistan Economic Survey (Various Issues),
Government of Pakistan. Each of the variables is defined herein after.
Private investment ([PI.sub.t]) is the gross fixed capital
formation in private sector. Where, gross fixed capital formation is the
expenditure on purchase and own-account construction of fixed assets which includes improvement of land, construction of buildings, other
construction i.e., roads, dams, culverts, drainage, ports and wharfs,
machinery and transport equipment etc. The capital repairs are also
included while sale of fixed assets is deducted. Gross Domestic Product
([GDP.sub.t]) is derived from gross output of the economy at market
prices i.e., total flow of goods and services, which are produced during
the period.
Public Development expenditure ([IG.sub.t]) is the gross fixed
capital formation in construction, electricity, gas, transport and
communication (railway, post office and T&T plus others) by the
public sector. Public consumption ([CG.sub.t]) is the general Government
current consumption expenditure. Interest Rate ([A.sub.t]) is measured
as weighted average rate of return on advances (total advances).
Inflation Rate ([Inf.sub.t]) is calculated from the consumer price
index. Finally the Uncertainty variable ([UN.sub.t]) is calculated by
percentage change in the annual inflation rate.
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
We have followed three steps methodology, containing the time
series properties of the data, estimation of long run private investment
function and a parsimonious error correction private investment
function. The results are reported here.
4.1. Testing of Unit Roots
First individual series are tested for the order of integration by
Augmented DickyFuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) tests. These two
tests confirmed the order of integration of theses series. The data for
public consumption expenditure ([CG.sub.t]), public development
expenditure ([IG.sub.t]), Private investment ([PI.sub.t]), inflation
rate ([INF.sub.t]), interest rate ([A.sub.t]) and Gross Domestic Product
([GDP.sub.t]) are used in log form. Therefore ADF test is applied on the
log form with an intercept and a linear trend term (as is appropriate)
included in the ADF regression equation of these variables. Appropriate
lag length is used so that serial correlation is removed from error
term. The results are presented in Table 1. The results show that all
variables are integrated of order one i.e., I(1) except [UN.sub.t] that
is I(0). To confirm the finding of I(1) property of variables, the ADF
test is also applied on first difference of the series.
The Phillips-Perron (pp) test is performed on the original series
(in log) at level and also on the first differences. The truncation lag
parameters are determined following Schwert (1987). The results are
reported in Table 2. The results confirm the finding of ADF test that is
there exist unit roots at level of the original series except [UN.sub.t]
which is stationary at level. The findings further highlight that taking
first difference will take care off the problem of non-stationarity.
These results provide ground to move to apply the cointegration method
to estimate the long run private investment function.
4.2. The Long-run Private Investment Function: A Cointegration
Analysis
Major purpose of this paper is to examine the determinants of
private investment. The analysis shows that weighted average rate of
return on advances and rate of inflation are insignificant at 5 percent
level by using LR test. Therefore these variables are dropped from the
final estimation process. The proxy for uncertainty (UN) is to be used
in the short-run ECMs under the assumption that investment decisions are
likely to be affected by recent uncertainty. This variable captures the
instability in the macroeconomic climate.
At this stage, the existence of cointegrating relationship between
the private fixed investment and its determinants are estimated. The
optimal lag structure of the model is necessary before obtaining the
correct model estimation, i.e., the number of lags, which will capture
dynamics of the series. The appropriate lag length of the VAR is three,
which is determined by following Schawarz Bayesian information criteria (SBC) for model selection [Enders (1995)].
We have investigated the number of cointegrating vectors by
applying the likelihood ratio test that is based on the maximal
eigenvalue and trace statistics of the stochastic matrix of the Johansen
(1988) procedure. The critical values depend upon position of
deterministic terms included in the VAR/ECM. Preliminary analysis shows
at least one variable have linear trend therefore we restricted constant
in the cointegration space. The results from the Johansen cointegration
test (both the eigenvalue and the trace test) are presented in Table 3.
The likelihood ratio (LR) statistics from both tests indicate
existence of one cointegrating vector at the 5 level of significance. In
case of finite sample test statistics is biased by a function of
T/(T-pk) and it too often indicate cointegration, therefore, the test
statistics needs to be adjusted accordingly [Reimers (1992) and Cheung
and Lai (1993)]. By using adjusted test statistics (7) we can conclude
that there is one cointegrating relationship among the variables
included in the model. The residual from cointegrating vector is
presented in Figure 1. The error term is well behaved and stationary.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The empirical results suggest that there exist a unique long run
relationship among private investment and its determinants. The long-run
private investment function presented here is obtained by normalising
the estimated cointegrated vector on the private investment (PI). So the
results of estimated long-run private investment function are reported
in Table 4.
As can be seen from the Table 4, estimated coefficients of
[LCG.sub.t], [LIG.sub.t] and [LGDP.sub.t] have expected signs and are
significant at 5 percent level. The estimated equation indicates that
the private investment is mainly determined by the public consumption
expenditure, public development expenditure and national income.
The cointegration analysis indicates that the estimated coefficient
of public consumption is -0.17, implying that in the long run there is
negative effect of public consumption on private investment. This is
mainly the outcome of an increase in government expenditures for wages
and salaries of public sector employees, which captures the biggest
share of public consumption expenditures and has no complementary effect
on private investment.
The analysis reveals that there is positive long run relationship
between private investment and public development expenditure. The
estimated coefficient of public development expenditure is 0.21. It
indicates the importance of providing basic infrastructure projects to
the private sector of the economy as a way to create the appropriate
economic environment that prompts private sector incentives to invest.
Public development expenditures such as the gross fixed capital
formation in construction, electricity, gas, transport and communication
reduces the private sector's cost of production or increases the
returns to scale and hence raises the profitability of the private fixed
investment. Thus public sector investment crowds in private investment
activity. Although the negative effect due to increase in interest is
there but complementary effect is more powerful. This result is
consistent with Blejer and Khan (1984), Chhibber and Wijnbergen (1988),
Khan (1988), Shafik (1992), Oshikaya (1994), Looney (1997), Mamatzakis
(2001), Pereira and Sagales (2001). Akkina and Celebi (2002), and Naqvi
(2002) but contradicts the results of Ghani and Din (2006).
The estimated coefficient of gross domestic product (GDP) is 1.10.
This result strongly supports the view that increase in GDP will enhance
private investment in the economy. Also this result shows that there is
demand-pull investment in Pakistan. It indicates that size of the market
plays an important role in increasing the private investment. It shows
GDP has higher impact on private investment as compared to the other
variables in Pakistan. Policy-makers should always keep in mind this
behaviour of investor. This finding is consistent with Blejer and Khan
(1984), Chhibber and Wijnbergen (1988), Shafik (1992), Naqvi (2002) and
Akkina and Celebi (2002).
In order to estimate single equation error correction model it is
required to test weak exogeneity of variables against the parameters of
interest. The weak exogeneity implies that the long run equation xloes
not inter into all equations of the system. Therefore in the presence of
weak exogeneity we can estimate short run error correction model of
private investment by single equation approach rather than vector error
correction approach.
We have tested the presence of weak exogeneity of variables (i.e.,
[LCG.sub.t], [LIG.sub.t] and [LGDP.sub.t]) by imposing restrictions on
adjustment coefficients. It is to test hypothesis [H.sub.0]:
[[alpha].sub.2]=[[alpha].sub.3][[alpha].sub.4]=0 for unrestricted
cointegrating vector ([beta]) by likelihood ratio test. The calculated
chi-squared statistics is 4.41 which is less than critical value of 7.81
= [chi square](3) at 5 percent level. The results indicate that variable
[LCG.sub.t], [LIG.sub.t] and [LGDP.sub.t] are weakly exogenous for the
parameters of interest. This implies that these variables have no
information about the cointegrating vector. The results therefore lead
us to estimate dynamic error correction model of private investment for
Pakistan by using single equation approach. (8)
4.3. Short-run Dynamic Model of Private Investment: The Error
Correction Approach
After establishing the cointegration relationship an Error
Correction Model is estimated to determine the short-run dynamics of
investment behaviour. Following Hendry's general to specific
approach we include different lags from top to low of explanatory
variables and error correction term i.e., [EC.sub.t-1]. The error
correction term (EC) consists of the residual from the long-run private
investment function.
We started with the following general ECM to obtain the short-run
dynamic private investment model.
(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
After estimating this model, we gradually eliminate the
insignificant variables. The results suggest that out of these
regressors only three are establishing short-term relationship with the
private investment significantly. All others insignificant variables are
dropped from the model. Thus in the short-run [DELTA][LPI.sub.t-1],
[DELTA][LIG.sub.t-1] and [UN.sub.t] have emerged significant variables,
while others variables do not prove their existence in the short-run.
The following specific ECM is found to be the most appropriate and fits
the data best.
(13) [DELTA][LPI.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] +
[[beta].sub.1][DELTA][LPI.sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.2][DELTA][LIG.sub.t-1]
+ [[beta].sub.3][UN.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.4][EC.sub.t-1]
All the variables are in first differences except the uncertainty
variable (UN), which is used for capturing the effect of macroeconomic
uncertainty on the private investment. The preferred model passed a set
of diagnostic tests such as LM test of serial correlation, ARCH LM test,
Brown, et al. (1975) CUSUM and CUSUM of Squares test of stability (graph
is presented in Appendix). The results of preferred parsimonious dynamic
error correction model are given in Table 5. Overall results are in line
with theory and consistent with the studies conducted previously.
The estimated error correction coefficient is -0.88 and it is
significant at 5 percent level with theoretically correct sign. The
estimated coefficient of EC indicates that approximately 88 percent of
disequilibrium in the private investment is corrected immediately, i.e.
in the next year. It suggests a high speed of convergence to equilibrium
if a disequilibrating shock appears.
The estimated coefficient of uncertainty proxy is -0.05 and
significant at 5 percent level. This indicates that macroeconomic
instability and uncertainty depresses private investment in Pakistan by
creating uncertainty about current and future macroeconomic environment.
In the estimated dynamic error correction model the coefficient of
lagged changes in private investment is positive and significant, which
shows that the changes in previous period's private investment
positively effect the short-term changes in the current private
investment. This implies that present outcomes are not instantaneous;
rather they are affected by the previous period's decisions.
The changes in public development expenditure having the negative
and significant sign, shows that the changes in private investment are
negatively related to the gross fixed capital formation in construction,
electricity, gas, transport and communication in short run. This may be
due to the reason that the speed of development work in public sector is
very slow but the nominal adjustment, i.e. in interest rate is quick. So
in short run substitution effect is stronger than complementary effect.
This finding reflects another fact that in short-period, public
development expenditure initially crowds out private investment. This
may be due to competition for human and financial resources. Over the
long run, however, public development expenditure complements private
fixed investment.
5. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The empirical findings support the proposition that public
development expenditures lead to enhance the private investment in the
economy. The well targeted public investments complements private
investment and stimulate private sector's initiatives.
Public non-development expenditures have considerable negative
effect on the private fixed investment. This result might be interpreted
as a view that a larger government size is an obstacle to the private
sector. It can be argued that higher public non-development expenditures
leave less resource for development. It can also be argued that higher
expenditures create expectations of higher future tax that might
discourage the private investment activities in the economy.
We have found that Pakistan has been facing the macroeconomic
instability and uncertainty that leads to depress the private sector. We
can conclude that macroeconomic stability and policy credibility are key
factors for the achievement of strong investment response. If the policy
measures are perceived as inconsistent or suspected to be only
temporary, then investors will prefer to wait and see before committing
resources to irreversible fixed investment. Therefore, the present
stabilisation programme should continue for the macroeconomic stability.
The results of the study also strongly support the view that
private investment is positively related with the income level. It may
also be argued that higher the size of market, higher will be the
private investment in the economy. So it can be said that results are
satisfied and provide the better basis for policy formulation and the
future research.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Abel, B. A. (1983) Optimal Investment under Uncertainty. American
Economic Review 73:1, 228-233.
Abel, B. A. and B. C. Janice (1994) A Unified Model of Investment
under Uncertainty. American Economic Review 84:5.
Able, S. L. (1980) Inflation Uncertainty, Investment Spending and
Fiscal Policy, Economic Review. February, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City.
Akkina, K. R. and M. A. Celebi (2002) Determinants of Private Fixed
Investment and the Relationship between Public and Private Capital
Accumulation in Turkey. The Pakistan Development Review 41:3,243-254.
Aschauer, D. A. (1989) Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private
Capital. Journal of Monetary Economics 24, 171-188.
Banerjee, A., J. Dolado, J. Galbraith, and D. F. Hendry (1993)
Co-integration, Error Correction and the Economic Analysis of
Non-stationary Data. New York: Oxford University Press.
Banerjee, A., J. Galbraith, and J. Dolado (1990) Dynamic
Specification with General Error-Correction Form. Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics 52, 95-104.
Blejer, M. and M. S. Khan (1984) Government Policy and Private
Investment in Developing Countries. IMF Staff Papers 31:2, 379-403.
Brown, R. L., J. Durbin, and J. M. Evans (1975) Techniques for
Testing the Constancy of Regression Relationships Over Time. Journal of
the Royal Statistical Society 37, 149-163.
Cheung, Y. W. and K. S. Lai (1993) Finite Sample Sizes of
Johansen's Likelihood Ratio Tests for Cointegration. Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 55.
Chhibber, A. and V. S. Wijnbergen (1988) Public Policy and Private
Investment in Turkey. The World Bank. (Working Paper (PPR), WPS 120.)
Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1979) Distribution of the
Estimators for Auto Regressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Journal of
the American Statistical Association 74, 366, 427-431.
Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1981) Likelihood Ratio Statistics
for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Econometrica 49:4,
1057-1072.
Dixit, K. A. and R. Pindyck (1994) Investment under Uncertainty.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Eberly, J. (1993) Comment on Pindyck and Solimano. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 303-312.
Enders, W. (1995) Applied Econometric Time Series. New York: John
Wiley and Sons Inc.
Engle, R. F. and C. W. J. Granger (1987) Co-integration and Error
Correction: Representation, Estimations and Testing. Econometrica 55:2.
Ghani, E. and Musleh-ud Din (2006) Impact of Public Investment on
Economic Growth in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 45:1,
87-98.
Ghura, D. and B. Goodwin (2000) Determinants of Private Investment:
A Cross-regional Empirical Investigation. Applied Economics 32,
1819-1829.
Granger, C. W. J. and T. Lee (1989) Multicointagration. Advances in
Econometrics 8:1, 71-84.
Greene, J. and D. Villanueva (1991) Private Investment in
Developing Countries. IMF Staff Papers 38:1, 33-58.
Hermes, N. and R. Lensink (2001) Fiscal Policy and Private
Investment in Less Developed Countries. World Institute for Development
Economics Research.-(WDP 2001/32.)
Jarque, C. M. and A. K. Bera (1987) A Test for Normality of
Observations and Regression Residuals. International Statistics Review
55, 163-173.
Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical Analysis of Co-integration Vectors.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12:2-3, 231-254.
Johansen, S., and K. Juselius (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation
and Inference on Co-integration with Application to the Demand for
Money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 52:2.
Kemal, A. R. (2002) Productivity Growth in Pakistan: A Study for
the Asian Productivity Organisation. Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics, Islamabad.
Keynes, J. M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money. London: Macmillan.
Khan, A. H. (1988) Macroeconomic Policy and Private Investment in
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 27:3, 277-291.
Khan, M. S. (1996) Government Investment and Economic Growth in the
Developing World. The Pakistan Development Review 35:4, 419-439.
Khan, S. M. and M. S. Kumar (1997) Public and Private Investment
and the Growth Process in the Developing Countries. Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics 59, 69-88.
Kim, Byung-Hwa and Hyun-Joon Lim (2004) Investment Behaviour in
Korea, Economic Paper. The Bank of Korea.
Looney, R. E. (1997) Infrastructure and Private Sector Investment
in Pakistan. Journal of Asian Economics 8:3, 1-41.
Mamatzakis, E. C. (2001) The Effect of Public Expenditure on
Private Investment: An Empirical Application. In Christos C.
Paraskevopoulos, T. Geogakopoulos, and L.
Michelis (eds.) The Asymmetric Global Economy; Growth, Investment
and Public Policy. Toronto: APF Press.
Monadjemi, M. S. (1996) Public Expenditure and Private Investment:
A Study of OECD Countries. University of Kent, Studies in Economics.
Munnell, H. Alicia (1992) Policy Watch Infrastructure Investment
and Economic Grbwth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 6:4, 189-198.
Naqvi, H. N. (2002) Crowding-in or Crowding-out? Modelling the
Relationship between Public and Private Fixed Capital Formation Using
Co-integration Analysis: The Case of Pakistan, 1964-2000. The Pakistan
Development Review 41: 3, 255-276.
Naqvi, S. N. H., A. H. Khan, and A. M. Ahmad (1993) Macro-economic
Framework for the Eighth Five-Year Plan. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute
of Development Economics. Oshikaya, T. W. (1994) Macro Economic
Determinants of Domestic Private Investment in Africa: An Empirical
Analysis. Economic Development and Cultural Change 573-596.
Osterwald-Lenum, M. (1992) A Note with Quintiles of the Asymptotic
Distribution of the Maximum Likelihood Cointegration Rank Statistics.
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 54:3, 451-472.
Ouattara, B. (2005) Modelling the Long Run Determinants of Private
Investment in Senegal. Centre for Research in Economic Development and
International Trade, University of Nottingham. (Credit Research Paper
No. 04/05.)
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Pakistan Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.
Pereira, A. M. and O. R. Sagales (2001) Infrastructures and Private
Sector Performance in Spain. Journal of Policy Modeling. 23:4, 371-384.
Phillips. R. and P. Perron (1988) Testing for a Unit Root in Time
Series Regression. Biometrika, 335-346.
Pindyck, R. and A. Solimano (1993) Economic Instability and
Aggregate Investment. BER Macroeconomics Annual 8, 259-303.
Qayyum, A. (2002) An Error Correction Model of the Demand for
Narrowly Defined Money in Pakistan. The Research Journal of Social
Sciences 1:1, 8-19.
Ramirez, D. M. (1994) Public and Private Investment in Mexico,
1950-90: An Empirical Analysis. Southern Economic Journal 61:1, 1-17.
Reimers, H. E. (1992) Comparisons of Tests for Multivariate
Cointegration. Statistical Papers 33.
Schwert, W. G. (1987) Effect of Model Specification on Tests for
Unit Roots in Macroeconomic Data. Journal of Monetary Economics 20,
73-103.
Shafik, N. (1992) Modeling Private Investment in Egypt. Journal of
Development Economics 39, 263-277.
State Bank of Pakistan (Various Issues) Annual Report. Karachi:
Central Directorate, State Bank of Pakistan.
Wai, V. Tun and Wang (1982) Determinants of the Private Investment
in Developing Countries. The Journal of Development Studies 19.
Williams and R. Darius (1998) Private Investment Adjustment with in
the ECCB Monetary Union. Social and Economic Studies 47:2 and 3, 59-87.
Imtiaz Ahmed is <imtiaz2073@yahoo.com> and Abdul Qayyum
<abdulqayyum@pide.org.pk> are Deputy Chief at the Planning
Commission of Pakistan and Professor at the Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad, respectively.
Authors' Note: The authors are thankful to Dr Faiz Bilquees,
Dr Shehnaz Ranf, and the anonymous referees of this journal for their
comments and suggestions on an earlier draft of the paper.
(1) Private investment is positively affected by income level as
Chhibber and Wijnbergen (1988) for Turkey, Ramirez (1994) for Mexico,
Monadjemi (1996) for Australia, and US, Mamatzakis (2001) for Greece,
Pereira, and Sagales (2001) for Spain, Akkina, and Celibi (2002) for
Turkey, Kim and Lim (2004) for Korea and Ouattara (2005) for Senegal.
(2) Capital equipment becomes industry-specific and can hardly be
put to another use or productive process or activity without incurring a
substantial cost.
(3) Moreover, Banerjee, et al. (1990) show that Instrumental
Variable method and OLS yield same estimates.
(4) The r can be said: (1) the number of cointegrating vectors, (2)
the rank of [PI], (3) the number of columns of [alpha] (4) the number of
columns in [beta] and (5) the number of nonzero canonical correlations
between the elements of [DELTA]Y, and the elements of [Y.sub.t-1].
(5) Banerjee, et al. (1993) says that the lag structure in the ADF
tests is ad hoc; it seems safest to over-specify the ADF regression.
(6) Johansen and Juselius (1990) suggested that the maximal
eigenvalue test has greater power than the Trace test.
(7) We used Cheung and Lai (1993) method who suggested scaling up
the Johansen critical values by factor T/(T-pk). Where 'T' is
for number of observations, 'p' is for number of variables
included in the analysis and 'k' is for number lags used.
(8) This point is suggested by the anonymous referee.
Table 1
Results for Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test of Unit Roots
Variables
Variables Lag First
Level ADF-slats Length Result Difference
[LCG.sub.t] -1.8929 (C) 1 I (1) [DELTA]LCG.sub.t]
[LIG.sub.t] -2.0418 (C) 0 I (1) [DELTA]LIG.sub.t]
[LPI.sub.t] -2.9464 (C,T) 0 I (1) [DELTA]LPI.sub.t]
[LGDP.sub.t] -1.8033 (C) 0 I (1) [DELTA]LGDP.sub.t]
[LINF.sub.t] -0.8715 0 I (1) [DELTA]LINF.sub.t]
[LA.sub.t] -2.4434 (C) 0 I (1) [DELTA]LA.sub.t]
[UN.sub.t] -6.6425 (C) * 0 I (0)
Variables Lag
Level ADF-slats Length
[LCG.sub.t] -5.7572 (C) * 0
[LIG.sub.t] -6.3662 * 0
[LPI.sub.t] -4.1524 * 0
[LGDP.sub.t] -4.8653 (C) * 0
[LINF.sub.t] -6.9322 * 0
[LA.sub.t] -4.0108 * 0
[UN.sub.t]
Note: * Denote significance at 5 percent; "c" indicates the constant
term is significant; c, t indicates that both the constant and the
trend are significant.
Table 2
Results for Phillips-Perron Test of Unit Roots
Series in Level First Differences
PP Test-statistic PP Test-statistic
Truncation Lag Truncation Lag
Parameters Parameters
Variables L 4=2 L 12=8 L 4=2 L 12=8 Result
[LCG.sub.t] -1.3749 -1.3978 -5.7480 * -5.8181 * I (1)
[LIG.sub.t] -2.0655 -2.0954 -6.3157 * -6.2686 * I (1)
[LPI.sub.t] -3.0923 -3.1636 -4.1008 * -4.3389 * I (1)
[LGDP.sub.t] -1.7435 -1.6257 -4.9082 * -5.1849 * I (1)
[LINF.sub.t] -0.8504 -0.8594 -7.0026 * -7.0527 * I (1)
[LA.sub.t] -2.0841 -2.0830 -3.8157 -3.7881 I (1)
[UN.sub.t] -6.7503 * -7.1177 * -- -- I (0)
Note: * Denote significance at 5 percent.
Table 3
Johansen Tests for Cointegration *
Maximum Eigenvalue Test
Null Alternative
Hypothesis Hypothesis Test Statistic
R = 0 R = 1 55.76606 **
R = 1 R = 2 21.1981
R = 2 R = 3 5.891993
R = 3 R = 4 0.6192
Trace Test
Null
Hypothesis Alternative Hypothesis Test Statistic
r = 0 R [greater than or equal to] 1 75.64948 **
r = 1 R [greater than or equal to] 2 25.1116
r = 2 R [greater than or equal to] 3 5.900783
r = 3 R [greater than or equal to] 4 0.561155
Note: * We used Johansen maximum likelihood method. For this
purpose we used Eviews 5.
** Indicates significant at the 5 percent level. Variables included
in the cointegrating vector: LPI, LCG, LIG and [LGDP.sub.t]
Table 4
Normalised Coefficients of Cointegrating Vector on [LPI.sub.t]
Standard
Variables Coefficients Error t-value Chi-square
[LCG.sub.t] -0.174164 * 0.0730 -2.38 6.06
[LIG.sub.t] 0.207556 * 0.0650 3.19 13.89
[LGDP.sub.t] 1.097379 * 0.0698 15.73 28.11
Constant -3.94 -- -- --
Note: (*) represent significance at 5 percent critical values.
Table 5
Error Correction Model of Private Investment ([DELTA]LPI)
Variables Coefficients Standard Error t-value
[DELTA][LPI.sub.t-1] 0.365729 0.109396 3.34
[DELTA][LIG.sub.t-1] -0.172844 0.070931 -2.44
[UN.sub.t] -0.047826 0.022856 -2.09
[EC.sub.t-1] -0.884592 0.141633 -6.24
Constant 0.027069 0.011745 2.30
R-square = 0.73 F (5, 32) = 16.18