Dynamism in the gender wage gap: evidence from Pakistan.
Sabir, Muhammad ; Aftab, Zehra
One of the main caveats of Pakistan's economic development
history is the persistence of gender inequality with respect to almost
all socioeconomic indicators. For instance, Pakistan ranks 66, out of 75
countries, with respect to Gender Empowerment Measure [Human Development
Report (2006)] with a GEM value of 0.377, largely a manifestation of
very low estimated female to male earned income ratio, which is a
depressing 0.29. GEM and other labour force statistics confirm the
gender gap in labour force participation. One of the possible
explanations of this gender gap is gender discrimination in the labour
market, particularly in wages. This study aims to analyse how the gender
wage gap has evolved over the last nine years for the wage-employed, by
using data drawn from the Labour Force Survey at two distinct points in
time: from LFS 1996-97, and then, after almost a decade, in 2005-06. The
analysis is disaggregated by occupation, and by province.
The results confirm significant gender differentials in relative
wages, even after controlling for a range of human capital and job
characteristics in the pooled sample as well as in the pseudo panel data
analysis. Moreover, estimation results from the two respective
cross-sections (1996-97 and 2005-06) show a significant increase in the
wage differential over the last nine years. This dispersion of wages
among male and female workers, even after controlling for observed human
capital and job characteristics, is much higher in Pakistan when
compared to other countries.
JEL classification: J31, J71
Keywords: Gender Wage Differentials, Quantile Regression, Wage
Dispersion, Pakistan
I. INTRODUCTION
One of the main caveats of Pakistan's economic development
history is the persistence of gender inequality with respect to almost
all socioeconomic indicators. For instance, Pakistan ranks 66, out of 75
countries, with respect to the Gender Empowerment Measure (Human
Development Report, 2006) with a GEM value of 0.377, largely a
manifestation of very low estimated female to male earned income ratio,
which is a depressing 0.29. GEM and other labour force statistics
confirm the gender gap in labour force participation. One of the
possible explanations of this gender gap is gender discrimination in the
labour market, particularly in wages.
Evidence with respect to gender discrimination in Pakistan's
labour market is well-documented. Siddique, et al. (2006), Nasir and
Nazli (2000), Siddique, et al. (1998) and Ashraf and Ashraf (1993) all
confirm that men earn higher wages than women even after controlling for
measurable characteristics affecting their productivity. These studies,
however, analyse the gender wage gap by comparing the mean male/female
wage. Studies which compare the gender wage gap at different points
along the wage distribution are not available for Pakistan.
This study aims to examine the evolution of the gender pay gap for
the wage employed in Pakistan over the period covering 1996-97 to
2005-06. The primary objective of the current paper is to provide some
clearer insights on the impact of the recent economic development on the
gender pay gap. The contribution of the current paper, however, compared
to previous research, is two-fold. First, our analysis covers a longer
time period, almost a decade, given our use of data drawn from the
Labour Force Survey at two distinct points in time: from LFS 1996-97,
and then, after almost a decade, in 2005-06. Secondly, in contrast to
the mean regression approach, we enhance the analysis by using a
quantile regression approach [Albrecht, et al. (2003)], that allows us
to explore the gender pay gap at selected points of the conditional wage
distribution. This study provides the estimates of the temporal decomposition of the gender pay gap using both the mean and the quantile
regression approach [Pham and Barry (2006)], which provides quantile
measures of the gender wage at two specific points in time, 1997 and
2006, using respective Labour Force Surveys for each of these years. The
analysis is further disaggregated by occupation, and province.
The paper is organised as follows: Section II presents the
literature review, including both the existing empirical evidence with
regard to the gender wage gap in Pakistan, and also some international
evidence on the pattern followed by the gender wage gap across the wage
distribution, and the glass ceiling effect. Section III discusses the
methodology; Section IV describes the dataset and provides descriptive
statistics which inform us of especial features of female participation
in the Pakistani labour market, including employment and wage ratio.
Section V is a summary of the statistical findings of our analysis,
while Section VI concludes by discussing the relevant policy
implications.
II. LITERATURE REVIEW
Human capital theory of wage determination suggests that wages are
tied to productivity, and in a non-discriminatory environment, the
observed gender wage differential should be completely explained by
differences in productivity between men and women. Gender discrimination
occurs when equally productive male and female workers are paid
differently. Given the gendered division of labour, women are considered
less likely to invest in market-oriented formal education because they
expect a shorter and more discontinuous working life; an investment in
education will therefore not pay off well in the future. More limited
experience and less investment in education will reduce their
productivity and will translate in lower wages. However, as mentioned
earlier, when equally productive male and female workers are paid
differently this phenomenon is described as gender discrimination.
1. International Findings on Gender Pay Gap
Since Becker's (1957) seminal paper on the economics of
discrimination, studies on the magnitude and sources of the gender wage
gap have proliferated [Bayard, et al. (2003); Blau and Kahn (2000);
Groshen (1991); OECD (2002)]. There is ample evidence of gender
discrimination in a host of developed and developing countries. Newell
and Reilly (2001) use the Oxaca-Blinder methodology to investigate the
gender wage gap in former communist countries of eastern Europe and the
Soviet Union; they find that most of the earnings gap in the 16
countries considered is ascribed to the 'unexplained'
component. Further, the study uses the Quantile regression analysis to
demonstrate that in all but one country considered, the ceteris paribus gender pay gap rises as we move up the wage distribution. Similar
findings that confirm that the gender gap increases across the wage
distribution and accelerates in the upper tail of the distribution are
confirmed for European countries [see Albrecht, et al. (2001) for
Sweden]. This acceleration in the wage gap at the upper tail is
interpreted as the presence of a glass ceiling effect. Pereira and
Martins (2000) used the quantile regression framework for an analysis of
changes in the returns to education at distinct points of the log wage
distribution for 15 European countries. The most recent Structure of
Earnings Survey data for 2002, covering only the private sector,
indicate a rather substantial pay gap between men and women. All in all,
the gender pay gap in the 25 member states is almost 25 percent. The
largest gap is found in the UK (30 percent), the smallest in Slovenia
(11 percent).
Some studies using the semi-parametric technique of quantile
regressions also exist for developing economies such as the Philippines
(2004) and Vietnam (2006). These studies find a different pattern in the
gender wage gap across the gender wage distribution. Sakellariou (2004)
using the quantile regression find that the underpayment of women is
much higher for low earnings workers and continuously decreases as we
progress to higher earnings; they find that 'this underpayment at
the lowest income decile is more than twice the underpayment at the
highest income decile'. A similar pattern is confirmed for Vietnam
[Pham and Reilly (2006)].
2. Gender Pay Gap in Pakistan
As mentioned above, the mean gender wage gap has been extensively
studied in Pakistan. Ashraf and Ashraf (1993) estimated the mean gender
wage gap for Pakistan as a whole and also for the four provinces. Using
the Household Income and Expenditure Survey (HIES), the respective
Mincerian Wage equations estimated separately for males and females
confirmed that the earnings level rose monotonically with the level of
educational attainment for both time periods considered (1979 and 1986),
and for both sexes in most cases. They claimed that the wage gap stood
at 63.27 percent in 1979, and declined to 33.09 percent in 1986. They
found that the decline was broad-based and occurred in every province,
and across every industrial group.
Siddique, et al. (1998) also find evidence for gender
discrimination. They used the standard (Oaxaca 1973) decomposition
method to split the gender wage gap into two parts: the part due to
difference in characteristics and the part due to differences in return
to these characteristics. The latter constitutes gender discrimination.
Siddique, et al. estimate discrimination of 55-77 percent, i.e. 55 to 77
percent of the earnings differential between male and female workers is
a result of discrimination in the labour market.
Nasir and Nazli (2000) used the 1995-96 Pakistan Integrated
Household Survey (PIHS) to estimate the Mincerian wage equation. They
estimate a positive and significant gender coefficient (0.264) after
controlling for region (rural/urban), province, and educational
attainment.
Siddique, et al. (2006) used the survey data of export oriented industries located in Karachi, Faisalabed and Sailkot: The results of
the study are in line with other studies and confirm gender
discrimination in export oriented industries. They further concluded
that the impact of adjustment policies, leading to liberalisation, and
resulting change in the labour market, has a disproportionately higher
negative impact on females.
The studies mentioned above provide empirical support for gender
discrimination in the Pakistani labour market; however, these studies
analysed the gender wage gap by comparing the mean male/female wage.
Studies which compare the gender wage gap at different points along the
wage distribution are not available for Pakistan.
III. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY
To analyse the gender pay gap, we choose more than one method to
verify the sensitivity of the gender wage differential with respect to
the choice of technique.
The estimates include a comparison of the mean male-female wage
gap, the Oxaca Blinder decomposition of the male-female wage
differential, and finally, an analysis of the gender wage gap along the
wage distribution. In the context of the quantile regression approach,
we largely relied on the temporal decomposition technique of Pham and
Barry (2006).
1. Analysing the Gender Pay Gap
Perhaps the simplest approach to analysing the gender pay gap is to
divide the mean value of female wage by the mean value of male wage:
[bar.D] = [[bar.w].sub.f]/ [[bar.w].sub.m] (1)
where [w.sub.j] and [w.sub.m] represent the wages of males and
females, D represents discrimination or gender pay gap and the bar sign
indicates averages.
2. The Dummy Approach
Following the seminal work of Mincer (1974), it is conventional to
specify log wages as a function of a set of wage determining
characteristics, which primarily include controls for human capital. In
the empirical literature on the gender pay gap, the simplest way to
analyse the gender pay gap is to perform a regression analysis, with
gender included as a dummy variable, in order to capture the effect of
discrimination:
Wi = [beta]Xi + [gamma]sexi + [epsilon]i (2)
where [w.sub.i] represents the log wage and [X.sub.i] the control
characteristics (e.g. education, job experience, and job
characteristics) of an individual i, [beta] and [gamma] are parameters.
3. The Oxaca--Blinder Decomposition
A relatively more sophisticated procedure to investigate the gender
pay gap is developed by Blinder (1973) and Oaxaca (1973). In this
procedure, wages are estimated separately for individuals, i, of the
different groups, g (males and females). As a result, this procedure
allows that productive characteristics of men and women are rewarded
differently:
wi = [beta]Xi + [epsilon]gi (3)
where g : (m, f), represents the two sexes; Wgi is the log wage,
and Xgi the control characteristics of an individual i of group g.
The total wage differential between men and women can then be
decomposed into an explained part (differential due to differences in
characteristics) and an unexplained residual.
The difference in mean wages can be written as:
[D.sup.A] = [W.sub.m] - [W.sub.f] = ([X.sub.m] - [X.sub.f])
[[??].sub.m] + [[??].sub.m] - [[??].sub.f]) [X.sub.f] [equivalent to] E
+ U, (4)
where Wg denotes the mean log wage, X g represents the control
characteristics of group g and ^[beta]g the estimated parameter from
Equation (3). While the first term represents the effect of different
productive characteristics (the endowment effect E), the second term
represents the unexplained residual U (often referred to as 'wage
discrimination') which includes differences due to unobserved
variables that influence productivity and difference due to a
differential reward for equal characteristics.
In Equation 4 the difference in male and female characteristics are
evaluated using the male wage structure. In principle, it is possible to
use the female wage structure as the reference. This will in general
lead to different outcomes.
4. Temporal Decomposition Using Mean Regression
In the context of the mean regression framework, we can adopt an
index number approach to temporally decompose the gender pay gap. Based
on Equation 4, the overall gender pay gap, at separate points in time
can be expressed as:
[D.sup.A.sub.0] = ([X.sub.om] - [X.sub.0f]) ^[[beta].sub.0m] +
(^[[beta].sub.0m] - ^[[beta].sub.0f]) [X.sub.0f] (5)
[D.sup.A.sub.n] = ([X.sub.nm] - [X.sub.nf]) ^[[beta].sub.nm] +
(^[[beta].sub.nm] - ^[[beta].sub.nf]) [X.sub.nf] (6)
where 0 denotes the base year and n any year after the base year.
The temporal decomposition of the gender pay gap can be expressed as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
After some arithmetic operations the temporal decomposition of the
gender pay gap can be rewritten as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
Thus, the overall change in the gender pay gap between two years
can be decomposed into four parts. The first part is attributable to the
temporal change in the gender differential in realisation of observable
characteristics using the male coefficient. The second part is
attributable to the temporal change in the realisation of the observable
female characteristics. The third part is attributable to the temporal
change in the male wage structure. The final term is attributable to the
temporal change in unequal treatment (or wage discrimination).
5. Analysing Gender Discrimination Using Quantile Regressions
The foregoing decompositions are situated within a mean regression
framework. An exclusive focus on the mean, however, provides an
incomplete account of the gender pay gap. The quantile regression
approach allows the gender pay gap to be estimated at particular
quantiles of the conditional wage distribution as opposed to simply the
mean. The estimation of a set of conditional quantile functions
potentially allows a more detailed portrait of the relationship between
the conditional distribution of the wage and selected covariates. In
contrast to the OLS approach, the quantile regression procedure is
arguably less sensitive to outliers and provides a more robust estimator
in the face of departures from normality than the OLS technique [Koenker
(2005); Koenker and Basset (1978)]. In addition, according to Deaton
(1997), quantile regression models may also have better properties than
the OLS ones in the presence of heteroscedasticity. Using this
methodology, the log wage equation may be estimated conditional on a
given specification and then calculated at various percentiles of the
residuals (e.g., 10th, 25th, 50th 75th or 90th) [see Chamberlain
(1994)].
The quantile regression for both sex groups can be defined as:
[W.sub.g] = [X.sub.g] [[beta].sub.[theta]g] + [[mu].sub.g] (9)
where Q[theta] ([W.sub.g] | [X.sub.g]) = [X.sub.g]'
[[beta].sub.[theta]g], and Q[theta] ([[mu].sub.g], | [X.sub.g]) = 0,
[[beta].sub.[theta]g] denotes the unknown male and female parameter
vector for the 0'h quantile, and 0 denotes the chosen quantile.
From Equation 9
Q[theta]([W.sub.g]) = E([X.sub.g] | [W.sub.g] =
Q[theta]([W.sub.g]))'[[beta].sub.[theta]g] + E([[mu].sub.[theta]g]
| [W.sub.g] = Q[theta](([W.sub.g])) (10)
In this expression, characteristics are evaluated conditionally at
the unconditional quantile log wage value and not unconditionally as in
the case of the mean regression approach. The term E([[mu].sub.[theta]g]
| [W.sub.g] = Q[theta](([W.sub.g])) is thus non-zero for both sex
groups. From Equation (10), the gender pay gap at the [[theta].sup.th]
quantile is defined as [[DELTA].sub.[theta]] and this can be decomposed
into three parts:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
This can be rewritten more compactly as:
[D.sub.[theta]] =
[DELTA][[OMEGA].sub.[theta]]'^[[beta].sub.[theta]] +
[[OMEGA].sub.[theta]f]'[DELTA]^[[beta].sub.[theta]] +
[[eta].sub.[tetha]] (12)
where [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Using mean characteristics in Equation (12) may provide
unrepresentative realisations for the basket of characteristics at
points other than the conditional mean wage to which they actually
relate. Therefore, it is necessary to use realisations for the basket of
characteristics that more accurately reflect the relevant points on the
conditional wage distribution. In this paper, to derive the
characteristics at different quantiles of the wage distribution, the
sampling variances for the quantile regression estimates are obtained
using bootstrapping.
In the context of the quantile regression approach, we use a
relatively ad hoc method for the temporal decomposition of the gender
pay gap at selected quantiles [see Pham and Barry (2006) for details].
The overall gender pay gap at the qth quantile can be expressed as:
[D.sub.[theta]0] =
[DELTA][[OMEGA].sub.[theta]0]'^[[beta].sub.[theta]m0] +
[[OMEGA].sub.[theta]f0]'[DELTA]^[[beta].sub.[theta]0] +
[[eta].sub.[theta]] (13)
[D.sub.[theta]0n] =
[DELTA][[OMEGA].sub.[theta]0n]'^[[beta].sub.[theta]mn] +
[[OMEGA].sub.[theta]fn]'[DELTA]^[[beta].sub.[theta]n] +
[[eta].sub.[theta]n] (14)
where 0 denotes the base year and n any year after the base year.
The temporal decomposition of the gender pay gap is as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (15)
Thus, the overall change in the gender pay gap between two years at
the [[theta].sup.th] quantile can be decomposed into five parts. The
first part is attributable to the temporal change in the gender
differential in realisations of observable characteristics at the
[[theta].sup.th] quantile of the wage distribution evaluated using male
coefficients. The second part is attributable to the temporal change in
the realisations of the observable female characteristics at the
[[theta].sup.th] quantile of the wage distribution. The third part is
attributable to the temporal change in the male wage structure at the
[[theta].sup.th] quantile of the wage distribution. The fourth term is
attributable to the temporal change in unequal treatment (or wage
discrimination) at the [[theta].sup.th] quantile of the wage
distribution. The final term is unexplained and may be attributable to
the changing role of un-observables over time.
The temporal decomposition suggested by Juhn, Murphy and Pierce (1991) could be used to decompose the average pay gap over time but this
procedure is neither outlined nor pursued here in terms of the mean
regression analysis. The Equation 15 is subject to an 'index
number' problem, the temporal gender pay gap can also be re-cast in
another form. However, in this paper we restricted ourselves to Equation
15.
IV. DATA AND SPECIFICATION ISSUES
Respective Labour Force Surveys for 1996-97 and 2005-06 are
employed for our analysis. These surveys provide a narrative of almost a
decade. The survey collects comprehensive information on various
activities of workers. The information about employment status and
distribution of employed labour force by industry division, gender and
regions is particularly important for this study. A comparison of LFS
with other data sources shows the superiority of LFS because of greater
internal and external consistencies [Zeeuw (1996)]. Since the 1990s, the
questionnaire of the LFS has been revised twice and a number of other
changes have been made to improve the quality of data collection as well
as coverage of different sub-groups.
For the purpose of our analysis we restrict our sample to wage
earners and salaried persons of 10 to 70 years of age: for 2005-06 the
sample contains 24,366 individuals, 21,323 males and 3,043 females;
while for the 1996-97 cross-section the 13,594 individuals, 12,229 males
and 1,365 females. The majority of these individuals are fulltime
employees who work more than 35 hours per week. The data on earnings
include only cash payments; other benefits such as bonuses are not
included in these earnings.
1. Specification Issues
The wage regression analysis reported in this study uses monthly
real wage rates. The natural logarithms of these real wage rates are
then used in the augmented Mincerian wage equations, which control for,
inter alia, human capital and other characteristics. It is customary to
use a years-in-education variable in the standard human capital wage
specification. In case of Pakistan, the schooling years would have to be
computed from the information on the highest educational qualifications
obtained as reported in the household surveys. However, as demonstrated
in other studies, this might introduce noise into the measurement of
this particular variable [for instance Pham and Barry (2006), Sabir and
Aftab (2006)] and this study thus uses a set of educational dummies to
capture human capital effects. In addition, the age of an individual is
used to proxy for labour market experience rather than using a potential
labour force measure. This is acknowledged as a constraint in this
application but data limitations prevent use of a more accurate measure.
The econometric specification used in this study is slightly
different from other studies on gender pay gap in Pakistan in a couple
of key respects. Firstly, educational levels and the individual's
age are used instead of years in schooling and potential experience.
This is to avoid the introduction of a possible measurement error in key
explanatory variables, though it is acknowledged that the use of age, a
proxy experience measure, as compared to the use of an actual measure,
is likely to inflate the magnitude of the unequal treatment component in
the decompositions undertaken here. Secondly, occupation controls for
the wage employed workers are not included in our regression models.
This is a judgment call and we take the view that the inclusion of
controls that may reflect the outcome of a labour market discriminatory process is undesirable in this case. In addition, there is also a
concern regarding the potential endogeneity of the occupational
attachment variables.
V. DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
Pakistan's labour market is characterised by a very low female
to male employment ratio of 0.14 in 2005-06 (see Table 1). In 1996-97
for every 9 men employed only one woman was working; in comparison, in
2006 for every 7 men employed only one woman is employed. Although
female to male employment ratio has marginally improved since 1996-97,
however, it still remains very low. The descriptive statistics further
reveal a large and persistent wage gap between males and females. The
gender wage ratio, over the last decade, has only posted a marginal
increase from 0.66 to 0.69: In FY2006 for every Rs 1 earned by a man, a
female worker earns only 69 paisas.
Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for some of the relevant
variables. The average age of employed males has consistently been
higher than the mean age of working women: the mean age of working men
in 1996-97 was 33.7, and has reduced to 32.7 years, in 2006; while the
average age of working women remained unchanged at 30.7 years.
If we look at the education attainment indicators for the employed
sample, we find that, on average, women workers are more qualified than
men, and yet remain underpaid, on average, as compared to their male
counterparts. In 2006, while only 11 percent of the employed men were
graduates, 17 percent of working women had a graduate degree. Finally,
in 2006, the proportion of women in blue collar jobs (defined as
technical jobs, clerks, crafts and other services related jobs) has
increased as compared to 1997.
VI. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The wage regression estimates, using the mean and the quantile
regression models, are provided in the Appendix and are not the subject
of detailed discussion here.
However, it is noteworthy that the fit of the Mincerian equations
have improved for both gender groups over the time period reviewed here
and that the point estimates for the returns to the higher formal human
capital measures have increased sharply. For instance, return to
postgraduate has increased to 0.83 in 2005-06 as compare to 0.71 in
1999-2000 and 0.81 in 1996-97. This could be taken to reflect the
enhanced role of the labour market in valuing human capital in Pakistan
over the high economic growth period.
1. Gender Pay Gap: Pooled Regression
Table 3 reports ceteris paribus gender pay gap estimated over the
1996-9"? to 200506 period using a pooled wage regression model with
a gender intercept term. The estimates reflect the decline in the
relative female wage position. For instance, in 1996-97 a male wage
employee earned 50 percent more than a comparable female, on average and
ceteris paribus, but by 1999-2000 the 'mark-up' had increased
to 53 percent, exhibiting further worsening thereafter in 2006 to 60.5
percent.
Table 3 also provides the estimated gender effects at different
quantiles of the conditional wage distribution. These estimates suggest
mix pattern in the female relative wage position in the Pakistani labour
market. The gender pay gap tends to display a sharp decline with
movement across the conditional wage distribution. This tentatively suggests that gender pay inequality is larger in the low-paid than in
the high-paid jobs though this is interrogated more closely using the
decompositions reported below. The decreasing ceteris paribus gender pay
gap across the different quantiles of the conditional wage distribution,
however, is in marked contrast to what is commonly observed in other
transitional and developed economies where a 'glass-ceiling'
effect is evident at higher points on the conditional wage distribution
[see Reilly (1999) and Newell and Reilly (2001)1.
2. Gender Pay Gap: Oxaca--Blinder Decomposition
The estimation of separate wage equations allows for the
implementation of the various gender pay gap decomposition methodologies
both at the mean and selected quantiles. In reviewing the estimates
reported in Table 4, the expansion in the gender pay gap between 1996-97
and the later years is again evident. In all years, the greater part of
the gender pay gap is attributable to unequal treatment with respect to
gender. Similarly, in accordance with the results reported in Table 3,
which uses an intercept shift to capture gender, the treatment effect
appears to grow across the selected quantiles of the conditional wage
distribution.
There is a substantial expansion in the average gender pay gap over
time. The raw gender pay gap expanded by 0.10 log points between 1996-67
and 2005-06. The expansion in the gender pay gap over these years is
also evident at selected points on the conditional wage distribution,
though it is more pronounced at the bottom rather than at the top end of
the distribution (see Table 4).
3. Temporal Decomposition of the Gender Pay Gap
As highlighted above, there is a substantial increase in the
average gender pay gap over time. The raw gender pay gap expanded by
0.93 log points between 1999-00 and 2005-06. The expansion in the gender
pay gap over these two years is also evident at selected points on the
conditional wage distribution, though it is more pronounced at the
bottom rather than at the top end of the distribution. In fact, the top
end shows a decline in gender pay gap during the same period (see Table
5).
In order to get further insights the mean and the quantile gender
pay gaps between 1999-00 and 2005-06 (i.e. between 1996-97 to 1999-00,
and 1996-97 to 2005-06) are decomposed using both expressions (8) and
(15). The change in observable characteristics like education level,
employment in white or blue collar jobs and residence urban areas at the
mean account for most of the expansion in the gender pay gap during
1999-00 to 2005-06. While from 1996-97 to 1999-00, observable
characteristics, observable gender differentials and wage structure show
a contraction the unequal treatment between the sexes accounts for the
marginal expansion in the gender pay gap. To consolidate, the entire 9
year period, since 1996-97 to 2005-06, expansion in observable
characteristics in the first half, and increased gender discrimination
post 2000 account for the expansion in the gender pay gap.
At the bottom end of the wage distribution the gender pay gap
expanded by 0.146 log points during 1999-00 to 2005-06, with changes in
observable characteristics exerting an important widening role. However,
from 1996-97 to 1999-00, bottom end of the wage distribution experienced
a substantial contraction of 0.121 log points. At the top end of the
wage distribution the gender pay gap contracted by 0.142 log points from
1996-97 to 2005-06 with changes in gender discrimination and wage
structure exerting an important narrowing role. The change in the
unobservable effect appears important in explaining the contraction in
the gap over time at the 90th percentile. The increase in unequal
treatment of men and women appears an important driver for the expansion
in gender pay gap at the 10th and 25th quantile, and the median. Thus,
the underlying narrative regarding the expansion of the gender pay is
sensitive to the selected point on the conditional wage distribution.
VII. CONCLUSION
The recent economic performance has had a significant impact on the
labour market in Pakistan. The statistics reveal that this high growth
period successfully attracted more females than male workers into the
labour market through providing more opportunities to them and reducing
their unemployment rate. However, this increase in female labour supply
translated in widening the gender pay gap.
A contribution of this paper has been the examination of the degree
to which the gender pay gap varies across the conditional wage
distribution. The decomposition analysis suggests that, in contrast to
general perception, the absolute wage gap increase over the wage scale.
In comport with the mean regression findings, there has been a
contraction in the gender pay gap at the top end of the wage
distribution. The change in unobservable characteristics appears
important in explaining the contraction in the gap over time at the 90th
percentile which is again resonant of our findings for the mean
regression. However, the reduction in unequal treatment of men and women
only appear an important driver for the increased gender pay gap in the
lower-middle part of the conditional wage distribution.
We believe our analysis provides an informative portrait of the
gender pay gap over time in the wage employment sector. But note, this
sector only comprises 37.3 percent of those at work in Pakistan by
2005-06. It should be stressed, therefore, that this study thus offers
only a partial insight into the effect of labour market dynamism in
Pakistan. The sizeable increase in the gender wage gap among the wage
employed is not a welcome feature of the transformation process.
However, this finding should not be over-emphasised and some perspective
is clearly required here. For instance, our analysis did not examine the
dynamism on other important employment sectors (e.g., the self-employed
or those employed in the informal sector) or the implications for those
women discouraged from retaining links with the formal labour market.
ANNEX
Table A
Definitions of Explanatory Variables
Variable Description
age Age in years
[Age.sup.2] Square of Age
Gender value 1 for man, otherwise 0
Primary value 1 if the highest level of education is
primary, otherwise 0
Middle value 1 if the highest level of education is
middle, otherwise 0
Matric value 1 if the highest level of education is
matric, otherwise 0
Intermed value 1 if the highest level of education is
intermediate, otherwise 0
Graduate value 1 if the highest level of education is
graduation, otherwise 0
Post_pro value 1 if the highest level of education is
either post graduation or professional education,
otherwise 0
Public value 1 if employed in a government department,
otherwise 0
Urban value 1 if living in urban area, otherwise 0
White_c value 1 if working as a professional (teacher,
lawyers) or managerial position
Blue_c value 1 if working as a technical or clerical
position, or working in crafts and other services
related jobs
Table B
Pooled Regression Model, 2005-06
Variable Mean Q10 Q25 Q50 Q75
age 0.0563 0.0852 0.0648 0.0477 0.0478
0.0017# 0.0044# 0.0021# 0.0017# 0.0016#
age2 -0.0006 -0.0010 -0.0007 -0.0005 -0.0005
0.00002# 0.00006# 0.00003# 0.00002# 0.00002#
gender 0.6053 0.9388 0.7727 0.6036 0.4129
0.0126# 0.0220# 0.0218# 0.0181# 0.0134#
primary 0.0796 0.0838 0.0964 0.0831 0.0755
0.0126# 0.0276# 0.0189# 0.0121# 0.0110#
middle 0.1539 0.1827 0.1448 0.1346 0.1361
0.0141# 0.0249# 0.0142# 0.0096# 0.0077#
matric 0.2442 0.2623 0.2267 0.2314 0.2501
0.0132# 0.0233# 0.0137# 0.0101# 0.0104#
intermed 0.3712 0.3369 0.3563 0.3613 0.3909
0.0179# 0.0207# 0.0159# 0.0120# 0.0127#
graduate 0.6221 0.4745 0.4861 0.5817 0.6741
0.0196# 0.0306# 0.0272# 0.0234# 0.0286#
post-pro 0.8327 0.5796 0.7015 0.8313 0.8821
0.0219# 0.0513# 0.0229# 0.0133# 0.0235#
public 0.3267 0.5313 0.4333 0.3441 0.2005
0.0113# 0.0139# 0.0119# 0.0075# 0.0105#
urban 0.1182 0.1232 0.1181 0.0980 0.1004
0.0085# 0.0146# 0.0093# 0.0046# 0.0070#
white_c 0.4469 0.2657 0.3075 0.5048 0.6333
0.0371# 0.0835# 0.0618# 0.0342# 0.0525#
blue_c 0.1095 0.1665 0.1267 0.1331 0.1318
0.0330# 0.0896# 0.0574# 0.0281# 0.0464#
_cons 6.1754 4.6519 5.5720 6.3404 6.8287
0.0441# 0.1274# 0.0841# 0.0418# 0.0517#
Adj R-squared 0.398 0.2392 0.2579 0.267 0.2782
Number of Obs 24366 24366 24366 24366 24366
Variable Q90
age 0.0433
0.0026#
age -0.0004
0.00004#
gender 0.3303
0.0319#
primary 0.0565
0.0175#
middle 0.1412
0.0170#
matric 0.2525
0.0172#
intermed 0.4559
0.0180#
graduate 0.7419
0.0291#
post-pro 0.9510
0.0502#
public 0.0846
0.0180#
urban 0.0800
0.0132#
white_c 0.5961
0.1098#
blue_c 0.0158
0.1200#
_cons 7.4018
0.1124#
Adj R-squared 0.2895
Number of Obs 24366
Note: Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors
are based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression model
estimates are based on bootstrapping.
Note: Standard errors are in italics is indicated with #.
Table C
Pooled Regression Model. 1999-00
Variable Mean Q10 Q25 Q50 Q75
age 0.0665 0.0992 0.0654 0.0542 0.0461
0.0025# 0.0048# 0.0049# 0.0032# 0.0025#
age2 -0.0008 -0.0012 -0.0008 -0.0006 -0.0005
0.00003# 0.00007# 0.00007# 0.00004# 0.00003#
gender 0.5334 0.7364 0.6381 0.4978 0.4059
0.0185# 0.0360# 0.0294# 0.0172# 0.0204#
primary 0.0827 0.0472 0.0551 0.0775 0.0957
0.0187# 0.0301# 0.0233# 0.0195# 0.0141#
middle 0.1158 0.1113 0.1175 0.1035 0.1068
0.0210# 0.0347# 0.0279# 0.0191# 0.0229#
matric 0.2554 0.2468 0.2253 0.2168 0.2279
0.0192# 0.0284# 0.0236# 0.0211# 0.0225#
intermed 0.3248 0.3157 0.2901 0.2721 0.2999
0.0255# 0.0552# 0.0347# 0.0219# 0.0325#
graduate 0.5154 0.4037 0.3994 0.4399 0.4986
0.0275# 0.0397# 0.0320# 0.0323# 0.0292#
post_pro 0.7118 0.5202 0.5553 0.6012 0.6882
0.0326# 0.0310# 0.0275# 0.0376# 0.0597#
public 0.1259 0.3757 0.2625 0.1240 0.0337
0.0151# 0.0233# 0.0199# 0.0166# 0.0139#
urban 0.1888 0.2138 0.1559 0.1728 0.1784
0.0124# 0.0218# 0.0141# 0.0063# 0.0095#
white_c 0.3558 0.1200 0.2867 0.4261 0.5783
0.0561# 0.0444# 0.0455# 0.0467# 0.0558#
blue_c 0.0659 -0.0309 0.0900 0.0923 0.1460
0.0510# 0.0340# 0.0408# 0.0389# 0.0415#
cons 5.7713 4.4309 5.4217 6.0579 6.5075
0.0671# 0.1190# 0.0990# 0.0645# 0.0671#
Adj R-squared 0.3533 0.1959 0.1953 0.1871 0.209
Number of Obs 10991 10991 10991 10991 10991
Variable Q90
age 0.0471
0.0037#
age2 -0.0005
0.00005#
gender 0.3815
0.0292#
primary 0.0865
0.0191#
middle 0.1281
0.0239#
matric 0.2533
0.0191#
intermed 0.3583
0.0286#
graduate 0.5552
0.0484#
post_pro 0.7978
0.0702#
public -0.0589
0.0135#
urban 0.1661
0.0191#
white_c 0.5948
0.0928#
blue_c 0.1003
0.0986#
cons 6.8454
0.1310#
Adj R-squared 0.2501
Number of Obs 10991
Note: Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors are
based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression model estimates
are based on bootstrapping.
Note: Standard errors are in italics is indicated with #.
Table D
Pooled Regression Model, 1996-97
Variable Mean Q10 Q25 Q50 Q75
age 0.0607 0.0963 0.0649 0.0535 0.0438
0.0022# 0.0047# 0.0030# 0.0024# 0.0080#
age2 -0.0007 -0.0011 -0.0007 -0.0006 -0.0004
0.00008# 0.00006# 0.00004# 0.00008# 0.00004#
gender 0.4969 0.7728 0.5922 0.4064 0.3481
0.0186# 0.0444# 0.0472# 0.0180# 0.0170#
primary 0.1111 0.1173 0.1071 0.0813 0.0862
0.0177# 0.0820# 0.0257# 0.0188# 0.0159#
middle 0.1605 0.1398 0.1970 0.1579 0.1661
0.0199# 0.0845# 0.0256# 0.0174# 0.0172#
matric 0.2174 0.2613 0.2353 0.1971 0.1914
0.0178# 0.0265# 0.0189# 0.0148# 0.0142#
intermed 0.3327 0.3288 0.2880 0.2844 0.2959
0.0282# 0.0275# 0.0214# 0.0176# 0.0151#
graduate 0.5583 0.4410 0.4778 0.4846 0.6175
0.0266# 0.0868# 0.0294# 0.0249# 0.0841#
post_pro 0.8183 0.5912 0.7186 0.7967 0.9065
0.0800# 0.0502# 0.0868# 0.0824# 0.0271#
public 0.0486 0.2686 0.1398 0.0229 -0.0772
0.0189# 0.0199# 0.0152# 0.0188# 0.0124#
urban 0.1283 0.1074 0.1264 0.1358 0.1269
0.0116# 0.0157# 0.0081# 0.0095# 0.0082#
white_c 0.4164 0.4501 0.3351 0.3706 0.4204
0.0396# 0.0599# 0.0428# 0.0812# 0.0404#
blue_c 0.2136 0.3644 0.2192 0.1829 0.1906
0.0849# 0.0617# 0.0839# 0.0298# 0.0894#
_cons 5.7194 4.0956 5.2866 6.0255 6.5149
0.0500# 0.1165# 0.0862# 0.0564# 0.0715#
Adj R-squared 0.3043 0.2419 0.2175 0.1921 0.2102
Number of Obs 13594 13594 13594 13594 13594
Variable Q90
age 0.0388
0.0038#
age2 -0.0004
0.00005#
gender 0.3286
0.0248#
primary 0.0859
0.0206#
middle 0.1361
0.0200#
matric 0.1672
0.0221#
intermed 0.3222
0.0328#
graduate 0.6766
0.0570#
post_pro 0.9309
0.0543#
public -0.1440
0.0182#
urban 0.1422
0.0159#
white_c 0.4274
0.0644#
blue_c 0.0932
0.0579#
_cons 6.9840
0.0979#
Adj R-squared 0.2343
Number of Obs 13594
Note: Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors
are based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression model
estimates are based on bootstrapping.
Note: Standard errors are in italics is indicated with #.
Table E
Female and Male Regression Model, 2005-06
Female Sample only
Variable Mean Q10 Q25
Age 0.0307 0.0594 0.0308
0.0055# 0.0160# 0.0092#
age2 -0.0003 -0.0007 -0.0003
0.00008# 0.00024# 0.00012#
Primary 0.0474 0.0621 -0.0388
0.0533# 0.1170# 0.0775#
Middle 0.2085 0.1035 -0.1459
0.0730# 0.0995# 0.0892#
Matric 0.2446 0.1138 -0.0793
0.0496# 0.0694# 0.0962#
Intermed 0.3941 0.2466 0.2712
0.0559# 0.1083# 0.0567#
Graduate 0.6440 0.4565 0.5229
0.0569# 0.0880# 0.0780#
post_pro 0.8998 0.9890 0.7670
0.0621# 0.1331# 0.0653#
Public 0.7265 0.9467 0.9654
0.0399# 0.0931# 0.0702#
Urban 0.2031 0.2260 0.1669
0.0292# 0.0447# 0.0506#
white_c 0.5326 0.9658 0.7787
0.1441# 0.3968# 0.3314#
blue_c -0.0895 0.6799 0.1784
0.1232# 0.4002# 0.3238#
_cons 6.6656 4.5662 6.0537
0.1526# 0.4456# 0.2975#
Adj R-squared 0.4504 0.1671 0.2161
Number of Obs 3043 3043 3043
Female Sample only
Variable Q50 Q75 Q90
Age 0.0297 0.0261 0.0135
0.0064# 0.0087# 0.0088#
age2 -0.0003 -0.0002 -0.0001
0.00009# 0.00014# 0.00012#
Primary 0.0982 -0.0062 0.0321
0.0557# 0.0464# 0.0948#
Middle 0.2607 0.3420 0.4499
0.1304# 0.0702# 0.2170#
Matric 0.2702 0.3879 0.5603
0.0632# 0.0556# 0.0621#
Intermed 0.4525 0.5235 0.5618
0.0571# 0.0631# 0.0521#
Graduate 0.6526 0.7627 0.8588
0.0683# 0.0648# 0.0700#
post_pro 0.8352 0.8804 1.0356
0.0527# 0.0758# 0.1015#
Public 0.8457 0.5815 0.3161
0.0453# 0.0476# 0.0483#
Urban 0.1701 0.1577 0.1723
0.0350# 0.0338# 0.0335#
white_c 0.6182 0.4961 0.2551
0.2003# 0.1743# 0.2721#
blue_c -0.1398 -0.2721 -0.4404
0.1916# 0.1525# 0.2364#
_cons 6.7339 7.3555 8.1124
0.2165# 0.2177# 0.2431#
Adj R-squared 0.3066 0.3542 0.3333
Number of Obs 3043 3043 3043
Male Sample only
Variable Mean Q10 Q25
Age 0.0607 0.0925 0.0697
0.0017# 0.0041# 0.0021#
age2 -0.0006 -0.0011 -0.0008
0.00002# 0.00005# 0.00003#
Primary 0.0703 0.0891 0.0901
0.0127# 0.0264# 0.0127#
Middle 0.1381 0.1836 0.1495
0.0140# 0.0236# 0.0196#
Matric 0.2286 0.267 0.2332
0.0135# 0.0264# 0.0110#
Intermed 0.3494 0.3341 0.3528
0.0186# 0.0179# 0.0199#
Graduate 0.5984 0.4573 0.4749
0.0207# 0.0321# 0.016#
post_pro 0.7699 0.5003 0.6451
0.0234# 0.0294# 0.0220#
Public 0.2708 0.4988 0.4001
0.0115# 0.0137# 0.0126#
Urban 0.1041 0.1200 0.1146
0.0057# 0.0160# 0.0073#
white_c 0.4456 0.2365 0.2890
0.0376# 0.0821# 0.0468#
blue_c 0.1303 0.1748 0.1313
0.0333# 0.0724# 0.0417#
_cons 6.7073 5.4683 6.2633
0.0440# 0.0856# 0.0529#
Adj R-squared 0.3501 0.1733 0.2036
Number of Obs 21323 21323 21323
Male Sample only
Variable Q50 Q75 Q90
Age 0.0515 0.0478 0.0454
0.0017# 0.0021# 0.0020#
age2 -0.0005 -0.0005 -0.0004
0.00002# 0.00003# 0.00003#
Primary 0.0738 0.0682 0.0442
0.0110# 0.0020# 0.0224#
Middle 0.1250 0.1237 0.1177
0.0121# 0.0130# 0.0179#
Matric 0.2210 0.2390 0.2170
0.0089# 0.0108# 0.0204#
Intermed 0.3432 0.3633 0.4039
0.0122# 0.0102# 0.0237#
Graduate 0.5434 0.629 0.7197
0.0155# 0.0304# 0.0316#
post_pro 0.7719 0.8454 0.9302
0.0241# 0.0275# 0.051#
Public 0.3016 0.1547 0.0516
0.0098# 0.0098# 0.0153#
Urban 0.0852 0.0836 0.0685
0.0052# 0.0071# 0.0095#
white_c 0.4908 0.6312 0.6018
0.0435# 0.0503# 0.0646#
blue_c 0.1362 0.1486 0.0503
0.0308# 0.0393# 0.0538#
_cons 6.8973 7.2413 7.6872
0.0376# 0.0351# 0.0655#
Adj R-squared 0.24 0.2679 0.2872
Number of Obs 21323 21323 21323
Note: Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors are
based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression model estimates
are based on bootstrapping.
Note: Standard errors are in italics is indicated with #.
Table F
Female and Male Regression Model, 1999-2000
Female Sample only
Variable Mean Q10 Q25
Age 0.0387 0.0328 0.0231
0.0080# 0.0201# 0.0082#
age2 -0.0004 -0.0004 -0.0002
0.00011# 0.00025# 0.00011#
Primary 0.0806 0.0077 0.0602
0.0959# 0.1356# 0.0908#
Middle 0.2894 -0.3204 0.0113
0.1087# 0.1828# 0.1761#
Matric 0.3466 0.0077 0.1661
0.0645# 0.1050# 0.0837#
Intermed 0.3530 0.0467 0.1669
0.0778# 0.1386# 0.1009#
Graduate 0.5918 0.3287 0.2963
0.0843# 0.1132# 0.0645#
post_pro 0.7649 0.3639 0.4516
0.0971# 0.1776# 0.1084#
Public 0.5414 1.1048 0.9626
0.0520# 0.0702# 0.0625#
Urban 0.1913 0.1356 0.1555
0.0419# 0.0686# 0.0383#
white_c 0.3324 0.0659 0.2381
0.1603# 0.1916# 0.1539#
blue_c -0.1194 -0.2705 -0.1917
0.1404# 0.1639# 0.1191#
cons 6.3173 5.9192 6.2810
0.1955# 0.4089# 0.1434#
Adj R-squared 0.4621 0.2398 0.3053
Number of Obs 1280 1280 1280
Female Sample only
Variable Q50 Q75 Q90
Age 0.0240 0.0372 0.0383
0.0086# 0.0089# 0.0088#
age2 -0.0002 -0.0004 -0.0004
0.00013# 0.00012# 0.00012#
Primary 0.0690 0.0268 -0.0648
0.1075# 0.0599# 0.0897#
Middle 0.1823 0.4068 0.7426
0.1366# 0.1036# 0.1689#
Matric 0.3180 0.4054 0.4531
0.0694# 0.0596# 0.0992#
Intermed 0.3134 0.3930 0.4961
0.0750# 0.0712# 0.1757#
Graduate 0.4712 0.6160 0.9681
0.0610# 0.1009# 0.2129#
post_pro 0.7729 0.9072 0.1808
0.0894# 0.1251# 0.2453#
Public 0.6672 0.3425 0.0984
0.0623# 0.0623# 0.0973#
Urban 0.1921 0.1964 0.2089
0.0346# 0.0512# 0.0786#
white_c 0.1897 0.4422 0.7489
0.1382# 0.1971# 0.5158#
blue_c -0.1583 0.1017 0.3242
0.1099# 0.1284# 0.4482#
cons 6.5699 6.5097 6.6115
0.1400# 0.1478# 0.4334#
Adj R-squared 0.3501 0.3265 0.3019
Number of Obs 1280 1280 1280
Male Sample only
Variable Mean Q10 Q25
Age 0.0715 0.1065 0.0765
0.0025# 0.0047# 0.0040#
age2 -0.0008 -0.0013 -0.0009
0.00003# 0.00006# 0.00005#
Primary 0.0661 0.0368 0.0403
0.0188# 0.0349# 0.0201#
Middle 0.0958 0.1054 0.1031
0.0211# 0.0333# 0.0227#
Matric 0.2232 0.2341 0.2033
0.0199# 0.0284# 0.0209#
Intermed 0.3083 0.3190 0.2854
0.0267# 0.0255# 0.0221#
Graduate 0.4952 0.4036 0.3861
0.0288# 0.0253# 0.0244#
post_pro 0.6953 0.4938 0.5410
0.0343# 0.0377# 0.0318#
Public 0.0663 0.3349 0.2022
0.0157# 0.0239# 0.0215#
Urban 0.1720 0.2036 0.1386
0.0129# 0.0227# 0.0134#
white_c 0.3318 0.1211 0.2866
0.0594# 0.0666# 0.0898#
blue_c 0.0799 0.0097 0.1333
0.0542# 0.0718# 0.0935#
cons 6.2341 5.0195 5.8671
0.0686# 0.1207# 0.1159#
Adj R-squared 0.3099 0.2043 0.1925
Number of Obs 9711 9711 9711
Male Sample only
Variable Q50 Q75 Q90
Age 0.0571 0.0482 0.0517
0.0027# 0.0024# 0.0035#
age2 -0.0006 -0.0005 -0.0005
0.00004# 0.00003# 0.00005#
Primary 0.0727 0.0892 0.0764
0.0210# 0.0162# 0.0256#
Middle 0.0897 0.0945 0.1054
0.0194# 0.0241# 0.0166#
Matric 0.1945 0.1906 0.2206
0.0155# 0.0195# 0.0222#
Intermed 0.2548 0.2806 0.3316
0.0140# 0.0226# 0.0376#
Graduate 0.4099 0.4961 0.5215
0.0202# 0.0431# 0.0418#
post_pro 0.5834 0.6681 0.7459
0.0343# 0.0492# 0.0828#
Public 0.0767 -0.0190 -0.0939
0.0117# 0.0119# 0.0158#
Urban 0.1494 0.1597 0.1683
0.0085# 0.0127# 0.0170#
white_c 0.3773 0.5627 0.5779
0.0556# 0.0711# 0.0841#
blue_c 0.0907 0.1314 0.0776
0.0350# 0.0505# 0.0761#
cons 6.5444 6.9211 7.1848
0.0500# 0.0535# 0.0839#
Adj R-squared 0.1883 0.2175 0.2604
Number of Obs 9711 9711 9711
Note: Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors are
based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression model estimates
are based on bootstrapping.
Note: Standard errors are in italics is indicated with #.
Table G
Female and Male Regression Model, 1996-97
Female Sample only
Variable Mean Q10 Q25
Age 0.0412 0.0793 0.0454
0.0074# 0.0734# 0.0149#
age2 -0.0005 -0.0010 -0.0006
0.00010# 0.00017# 0.00022#
Primary 0.0417 0.1000 -0.0061
0.0862# 0.0640# 0.0794#
Middle 0.0481 -0.3156 0.1293
0.1018# 0.3021# 0.1261#
Matric 0.1592 -0.0811 0.1733
0.0703# 0.1319# 0.0685#
Intermed 0.1672 0.0058 0.2425
0.0813# 0.2684# 0.0692#
Graduate 0.5336 0.3963 0.4503
0.0816# 0.1336# 0.0473#
post_pro 0.9052 0.4799 0.7352
0.0922# 0.1084# 0.0825#
Public 0.4763 0.9651 0.8268
0.0542# 0.1055# 0.0583#
Urban 0.0797 0.1373 0.0776
0.0436# 0.0647# 0.0545#
white_c 0.1747 0.2571 -0.0414
0.1008# 0.2858# 0.1103#
blue_c 0.0281 0.1775 -0.1175
0.0845# 0.2444# 0.1023#
cons 6.2552 4.6553 5.9034
0.1378# 0.3371# 0.1706#
Adj R-squared 0.3644 0.1856 0.259
Number of Obs 1365 1365 1365
Female Sample only
Variable Q50 Q75 Q90
Age 0.0459 0.0324 0.0240
0.0082# 0.0093# 0.0166#
age2 -0.0006 -0.0004 -0.0003
0.00012# 0.00013# 0.00023#
Primary -0.0640 0.1045 0.0167
0.0943# 0.1073# 0.1225#
Middle 0.2653 0.3020 0.0674
0.0948# 0.0850# 0.2273#
Matric 0.3696 0.3495 0.2112
0.0542# 0.0543# 0.0893#
Intermed 0.3988 0.3731 0.1764
0.0560# 0.0660# 0.0871#
Graduate 0.5798 0.6475 0.6033
0.0514# 0.0693# 0.1296#
post_pro 1.0898 1.2464 1.1287
0.0609# 0.0815# 0.0973#
Public 0.4308 0.1363 0.0753
0.0622# 0.0518# 0.0522#
Urban 0.0688 0.0882 0.1559
0.0285# 0.0351# 0.0499#
white_c 0.0457 0.1668 -0.068
0.0545# 0.1884# 0.1569#
blue_c -0.0172 0.0823 -0.1541
0.0500# 0.1995# 0.1302#
cons 6.1893 6.7388 7.4740
0.1121# 0.2551# 0.2759#
Adj R-squared 0.2976 0.2486 0.2604
Number of Obs 1365 1365 1365
Male Sample only
Variable Mean Q10 Q25
Age 0.0637 0.0996 0.0676
0.0023# 0.0064# 0.0027#
age2 -0.0007 -0.0012 -0.0008
0.00003# 0.00009# 0.00004#
Primary 0.1081 0.1135 0.1118
0.0179# 0.0304# 0.0176#
Middle 0.1612 0.1401 0.1916
0.0201# 0.0299# 0.0217#
Matric 0.2126 0.2743 0.2330
0.0183# 0.0225# 0.0156#
Intermed 0.3425 0.3584 0.2986
0.0241# 0.0319# 0.0144#
Graduate 0.5563 0.4560 0.4520
0.0282# 0.0225# 0.0275#
post_pro 0.8035 0.5842 0.7150
0.0319# 0.0384# 0.0208#
Public 0.0086 0.2280 0.1057
0.0143# 0.0177# 0.0125#
Urban 0.1329 0.1068 0.1190
0.0120# 0.0153# 0.0074#
white_c 0.4385 0.4187 0.3509
0.0436# 0.0740# 0.0406#
blue_c 0.2450 0.3517 0.2666
0.0386# 0.0719# 0.0366#
cons 6.1286 4.8185 5.7995
0.0529# 0.1409# 0.0542#
Adj R-squared 0.2698 0.1932 0.1775
Number of Obs 12229 12229 12229
Male Sample only
Variable Q50 Q75 Q90
Age 0.0551 0.0452 0.0411
0.0029# 0.0040# 0.0035#
age2 -0.0006 -0.0005 -0.0004
0.00004# 0.00006# 0.00005#
Primary 0.0827 0.0746 0.0850
0.0126# 0.0146# 0.0259#
Middle 0.1493 0.1554 0.1386
0.0223# 0.0161# 0.0268#
Matric 0.1804 0.1629 0.1644
0.0/10 # 0.0153# 0.0258#
Intermed 0.2651 0.2833 0.3235
0.0177# 0.0234# 0.0265#
Graduate 0.4748 0.6412 0.6538
0.0/79 # 0.0337# 0.0411#
post_pro 0.7983 0.8449 0.8712
0.0228# 0.0275# 0.0469#
Public -0.0102 -0.0967 -0.1626
0.0082# 0.0099# 0.0194#
Urban 0.1369 0.1255 0.1386
0.0099# 0.0125# 0.0204#
white_c 0.3345 0.4550 0.5659
0.0402# 0.0550# 0.0675#
blue_c 0.1863 0.1816 0.1593
0.0418# 0.0432# 0.0535#
cons 6.4141 6.8574 7.2085
0.0669# 0.0673# 0.0923#
Adj R-squared 0.1735 0.2028 0.2312
Number of Obs 12229 12229 12229
Note: Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors are
based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression model estimates
are based on bootstrapping.
Note: Standard errors are in italics is indicated with #.
REFERENCES
Albrecht, et al. (2003) Is There are Glass Ceiling in Sweden?
Journal of Labour Economics 21, 145-77.
Ashraf, J, and B. Ashraf (1993) Estimating An Analysis of the
Male-Female Earnings Differential in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development
Review 32:4, 895-904.
Ashraf, J, and B. Ashraf (1993) Estimating the Gender Wage Gap in
Rawalpindi City. Journal of Development Studies 29:2.
Bayard, et al. (2003) New Evidence on Sex Segregation and Sex
Differences in Wages from Matched Employer-Employee Data. Journal of
Labour Economics 21:4, 887-922.
Becker, G. S. (1957) The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: The
University of Chicago Press.
Blau, Francine D. and Lawrence M. Kahn (2000) Gender Differences in
Pay. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14:4, 75-99.
Blinder, A. (1973) Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and Structural
Estimates. Journal of Human Resources 8, 436-465.
Buchinsky, M. (1994) Changes in the US wage structure 1963-1987: an
application of quantile regression. Econometrica 62, 405-458.
Buchinsky, M. (1998) Recent Advances in Quantile Regression Models.
Journal of Human Resources 33, 88-126.
Deaton, A. (1997) The Analysis of Household Surveys: A
Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. John Hopkins University
Press.
FBS (Various Years) Labour Force Survey. Islamabad: Federal Bureau
of Statistics, Government of Pakistan.
Garcia, Hernandez, and Lopez-Nicolas (2001) How Wide is the Gap? An
Investigation of Gender Wage Differences Using Quantile Regression.
Empirical Economics 26:1, 149-167.
Groshen, Erica L. (1991) The Structure of the Female/Male Wage
Differential: Is it Who You Are, What You Do, or Where You Work? Journal
of Human Resources 26:3, 457-472.
Huber, P. J. (1967) The Behaviour of Maximum Likelihood Estimates
Under Nonstandard Conditions. In Proceedings of the Fifth Berkley
Sumposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Berkley, CA:
University of California Press, 1, pp. 221-23.
Jones, F. (1983) On Decomposing the Wage Gap: A Critical Comment on
Blinder's Method. Journal of Human Resources 18, 126-130.
Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M. Murphy, and Brooks Pierce (1991) Accounting
for the Slowdown in Black-White Wage Convergence. In Marvin H. Kosters
(ed.) Workers and Their Wages. Washington, DC: AEI Press, 107-143.
Khan, Shahrukh R. and Mohammad Irfan (1985) Rate of Returns to
Education and Determinants of Earnings in Pakistan. The Pakistan
Development Review 24:3&4, 471-680.
Koenker, R. (2005) Quantile Regression. Econometric Society Monograph Series, Cambridge University Press.
Koenker, R. and G. Basett (1978) Regression Quantiles. Econometrica
46:1, 33-50.
Mincer, J. (1974) Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York:
Columbia University.
Monazza Aslam, Rates of Return to Education by Gender in Pakistan,
GPRG-WPS-064, Global Poverty Research Group, Website:
http://www.gprg.org/
Nasir, Z. M. and Hina Nazli (2000) Education and Earnings in
Pakistan. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
(Research Report No. 177.)
Nasir, Zafar M. (1998), Determinants of Personal Earnings in
Pakistan: Findings from the Labour Force Survey 1993-94. The Pakistan
Development Review 37:3, 251-274.
Newell, A. and B. Reilly (2001) The Gender Pay Gay in the
Transition from Communism: Some Empirical Evidence. Economic Systems 25,
287-304.
Oaxaca, R. (1973) Male-female Wage Differentials in Urban Labour
Markets. International Economic Review 14, 693-709.
Oaxaca, R. and M. Ransom (1994) On Discrimination and the
Decomposition of Wage Differentials. Journal of Econometrics 61, 5-21.
OECD (2002) Manual for the PISA 2000 Database. Paris: OECD.
Pereira, P. and P. Martins (2000) Does Education Reduce Wage
Inequality? Quantile Regressions Evidence from Fifteen European
Countries. Bonn Institute for the Study of Labour (IZA). (Discussion
Paper No. 120.)
Pham, Hung T. and Barry Reilly (2006) The Gender Pay Gap in
Vietnam, 1993-2002: A Quantile Regression Approach. (PRUS Working Paper
No 34.)
Reilly, B. (1999) The Gender Pay Gap in Russia during the
Transition, 1992-1996. Economics of Transition 7:1, 245-64.
Sabir, M. and Z. Aftab (2006) Province-wise Growth Patterns in
Human Capital Accumulation. The Pakistan Development Review 45:4,
873-92.
Sakellariou, C. (2004) The Use of Quantile Regressions in
Estimating Gender Wage Differentials: A Case Study of the Philippines.
Applied Economics 36:9, 1001-1007.
Shabbir, Tayyeb (1994) Mincerian Earnings Function for Pakistan.
The Pakistan Development Review 33:4, 1-18.
Shabbir, Tayyeb and Alia H. Khan (1991) Mincerian Earnings Function
for Pakistan: A Regional Analysis. Pakistan Economic and Social Review
24, 99-111.
Siddiqui, et al. (1998) A Decomposition of Male-Female Earnings
Differentials. The Pakistan Development Review 37:4, 885:98.
Siddiqui, et al. (2006) Gender and Empowerment, Evidence from
Pakistan. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
Welch, F. (1973) Black-White Differences in Returns to Schooling.
American Economic Review 63, 893-907.
Zeeuw, Maarten de (1996) The Household Integrated Economic Survey
of Pakistan 1990-91: Internal and External Consistency. The Pakistan
Development Review 35:1, 71-84.
Muhammad Sabir <sabir@spdc-pak.com> is Principal Economist,
SPDC, Islamabad. Zehra At'tab <aftab.zehra@ gmail.com> is
Research Fellow, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Employment and Wage Ratios
Employment Ratio Wage Ratio
2005-06 1999-00 1996-97 2005-06 1999-00 1996-97
Pakistan 0.143 0.132 0.112 0.693 0.692 0.660
Punjab 0.212 0.201 0.186 0.616 0.632 0.584
Sindh 0.091 0.056 0.059 0.933 0.783 0.803
NWFP 0.089 0.099 0.061 0.901 0.984 0.914
Balochistan 0.038 0.039 0.029 0.918 0.946 0.909
Source: Authors estimates based on LFS 1996-67, 1999-00 and 2006-07.
Note: Employment ratios are computed by dividing number of employed
female by number of employed males.
Wage ratios are computed as defined in Equation 1.
Table 2
Employed Labour Force Characteristics by Gender
2005-06 1999-00 1996-97
Women Men Women Men Women Men
age 30.654 32.758 32.820 33.001 30.675 33.681
Employed 3,043 21,323 1,280 9,711 1,365 12,229
primary 0.077 0.158 0.040 0.145 0.056 0.134
middle 0.038 0.123 0.030 0.109 0.039 0.102
matric 0.112 0.150 0.138 0.142 0.138 0.149
intermed 0.085 0.068 0.079 0.070 0.095 0.080
graduate 0.084 0.058 0.084 0.071 0.104 0.060
post_pro 0.094 0.052 0.073 0.056 0.070 0.053
public 0.246 0.252 0.303 0.316 0.360 0.342
urban 0.517 0.515 0.607 0.613 0.578 0.596
white_c * 0.062 0.082 0.120 0.106 0.251 0.124
blue_c ** 0.927 0.901 0.863 0.881 0.692 0.854
Wage 3,943 5,691 2,599 3,754 2,296 3,478
Source: Authors estimates based on LFS 1996-67, 1999-00 and 2006-07.
* White colour jobs are defined as professional and managerial jobs.
** Blue colour jobs are defined as technical, clericals, crafts and
other services related jobs.
Table 3
Gender Pay Gap Based on Pooled Regression
Year Mean Q10 Q25 Q50 Q75 Q90
2005-06 0.6053 0.9388 0.7727 0.6036 0.4129 0.3303
0.0126 0.0220 0.0218 0.0181 0.0134 0.0319
1999-2000 0.5334 0.7364 0.6381 0.4978 0.4059 0.3815
0.0185 0.0360 0.0294 0.0172 0.0204 0.0292
1996-97 0.4969 0.7728 0.5922 0.4064 0.3481 0.3286
0.0186 0.0444 0.0472 0.0180 0.0170 0.0248
Note: Estimates are based on Equation 2.
Standard errors are in italics. The OLS standard errors are
based on Huber (1967) and the quantile regression
model estimates are based on bootstrapping.
Table 4
Oaxaca-Blinder Decomposed Gender Pay Gap
Mean Mean Q10 Q25 Q50 Q75
In 2005-06
endowment effect 0.011 0.032 0.018 0.009 0.009
wage discrimination 0.603 0.858 0.724 0.595 0.491
Unobservable Effect 0.000 0.033 0.197 0.091 -0.145
Estimated Pay Gap 0.614 0.923 0.940 0.695 0.355
In 1999-2000
endowment effect -0.016 -0.015 -0.013 -0.011 -0.013
wage discrimination 0.537 0.616 0.613 0.572 0.486
Unobservable Effect 0.000 0.175 0.232 0.085 -0.183
Estimated Pay Gap 0.520 0.777 0.831 0.645 0.290
In 199G-97
endowment effect 0.023 0.063 0.043 0.020 -0.006
wage discrimination 0.489 0.638 0.538 0.475 0.403
Unobservable Effect 0.000 0.197 0.254 -0.089 -0.163
Estimated Pay Gap 0.513 0.898 0.835 0.406 0.234
Mean Q90
In 2005-06
endowment effect 0.001
wage discrimination 0.418
Unobservable Effect -0.255
Estimated Pay Gap 0.164
In 1999-2000
endowment effect -0.018
wage discrimination 0.425
Unobservable Effect -0.225
Estimated Pay Gap 0.182
In 199G-97
endowment effect -0.025
wage discrimination 0.393
Unobservable Effect -0.063
Estimated Pay Gap 0.306
Note: Estimates are based on Equation 4 for mean regression
model and equation 12 for quantile regression models.
Table 5
Temporal Decomposition of the Gender Pay Gap:
Mean and Quantile Regression Approach
Mean Q10 Q25
Change in Gender Pay Gap During 1999-00 to 2005-06
Change in Observable Gender Differentials 0.023 0.031 0.021
Change in Observable Characteristics 0.049 0.232 0.075
Change in Wage Structure 0.004 0.016 0.010
Change in Unequal Treatment 0.017 0.010 0.037
Unobservable Effect 0.000 -0.142 -0.034
Change in Pay Gap 0.093 0.146 0.109
Change in Gender Pay Gap During 1996-67 to 1999-00
Change in Observable Gender Differentials -0.026 -0.061 -0.037
Change in Observable Characteristics -0.007 -0.089 0.000
Change in Wage Structure -0.013 -0.017 -0.019
Change in Unequal Treatment 0.054 0.068 0.081
Unobservable Effect 0.000 -0.022 -0.022
Change in Pay Gap 0.008 -0.121 -0.004
Change in Gender Pay Gap During 1996-67 to 2006-07
Change in Observable Gender Differentials 0.018 -0.022 -0.004
Change in Observable Characteristics 0.065 0.134 0.089
Change in Wage Structure -0.030 -0.009 -0.021
Change in Unequal Treatment 0.049 0.086 0.098
Unobservable Effect 0.000 -0.164 -0.056
Change in Pay Gap 0.101 0.025 0.105
Q50 Q75 Q90
Change in Gender Pay Gap During 1999-00 to 2005-06
Change in Observable Gender Differentials 0.020 0.025 0.026
Change in Observable Characteristics 0.002 -0.003 0.001
Change in Wage Structure 0.000 -0.003 -0.007
Change in Unequal Treatment 0.021 0.008 -0.008
Unobservable Effect 0.000 0.038 -0.030
Change in Pay Gap 0.049 0.065 -0.018
Change in Gender Pay Gap During 1996-67 to 1999-00
Change in Observable Gender Differentials -0.012 0.007 0.011
Change in Observable Characteristics 0.058 0.073 0.033
Change in Wage Structure -0.019 -0.015 -0.004
Change in Unequal Treatment 0.039 0.011 -0.001
Unobservable Effect 0.173 -0.020 -0.162
Change in Pay Gap 0.240 0.056 -0.124
Change in Gender Pay Gap During 1996-67 to 2006-07
Change in Observable Gender Differentials 0.027 0.043 0.054
Change in Observable Characteristics 0.076 0.098 0.047
Change in Wage Structure -0.038 -0.028 -0.029
Change in Unequal Treatment 0.044 -0.010 -0.022
Unobservable Effect 0.179 0.018 -0.192
Change in Pay Gap 0.289 0.121 -0.142
Note. Estimates are based on Equation 8 for mean regression model
and Equation 15 for quantile regression models.