Management of energy recourses, marginal input-output coefficients, and layers of techniques: a case study of US chemical industry.
Azid, Toseef ; Anwar, Mumtaz ; Khawaja, M. Junaid 等
This study examines the behaviour of different layers of techniques
which are working simultaneously with the different productive
efficiencies based on the model which was developed by Professor P. N.
Mathur. Considering this phenomenon as input-output table was
constructed based on the marginal input-output coefficients instead of
an average one, which is available in different publications of the
government. Each marginal coefficient represents the behaviour of a
separate layer of techniques. Some forecasting is developed on the basis
of these coefficients. With the help of these coefficients, it is easy
to know how many resources are required for the new techniques and how
many resources are becoming unemployed.
JEL classification: C67,032, Q43
Keywords: Marginal Input-Output Coefficients, Technological Change,
Energy, Layers of Techniques
**********
The embodied technical change should reduce the cost of production
of the commodity. However, price structure, wages and interest rates
also will change over time. Thus if a commodity is following a fixed
price regime, the adjustment of a historical input-output table to
current price wage level will leaves less and less profit per unit of
output. The extent of this reduction will indicate the extent of
technological change. There are different approaches to the prediction
of changes in input-output coefficients. The first approach,
attributable to Leontief (1941) and Stone (1962), assumes that
input-output matrices change over time in a "biproportional"
way. The other approach is to estimate trends in individual coefficients
using statistical data. Former approach is used by a number of experts,
including Fontela, et al. (1970), Almon, et al. (1974) and Carter
(1970). Arrow and Hoffenberg (1959), Henry (1974), Savaldson (1970,
1976), Ozaki (1976), Aujac (1972) and Buzunov (1970). These are examples
of the application of the quantitative approach for forecasting
input-output coefficients. Still another approach which could not get
much attention for forecasting input-output coefficients, is
constructing the marginal input-output coefficients [Tilanus (1967);
Middelhoek (1970)]. Marginal coefficients for forecasting constructed by
Tilanus and Middelhoek are based on average input-output tables, which
shows that still new approach (marginal) is based on the old (average)
one.
However, Professor Mathur (1977, 1986a, 1986b, 1989, 1990) was
interested in both types of firms, i.e., best-practice and least
efficient. According to him, in translating the extra final demand of
macro-models, the best-practice coefficients will be more useful than
the average ones, whereas in assessing the incidence of obsolescence,
unemployment, etc., the least efficient coefficients will be the more
appropriate ones. In the following sections the discussion will be based
more on the Professor Mathur's work. His approach was also later on
discussed theoretically and empirically by Azid (1993), Law and Azid
(1993), Azid and Law (1994, 1995), Azid and Ghosh (1998) and Azid and
Noor (2000), Azid (2002).
When a new technical advance is embodied in the capital equipment,
the old technique also remains producing for a certain time, though by
the nature of things it will more likely be earning lesser returns. The
very fact that the new technology requires an accumulation of the
corresponding capital will allow for the old technology to be in use for
some time, that is, until the time that the accumulated new capital
becomes sufficient to meet the total demand of the product.
Subsequently, investment of various techniques will work with different
efficiencies, and hence with different requirements for inputs, labour
and working stocks to produce a unit of output.
The afore-mentioned make clear that it is not necessary to assume,
as Shumpeter (1934) and Galbraith (1952) do, that there must be monopoly
power with the firm to prevent its capital equipment embodying old
technology from becoming obsolete due to new innovations. Up until the
time that sufficient equipment of new technology is not accumulated, the
equipment of old technology will go on producing. Once sufficient new
capital is accumulated, no amount of monopoly power can prevent the old
capital equipment from being pushed out to the scrap heap, as the demand
will be met cheaply by the processes employing the new capital
equipment.
If the industry is under monopolistic control, the monopolist will
not find it to his advantage to go on using the old capital which
produces at a higher cost. As a matter of fact, new capacity will be
installed when the cost advantage outweighs the loss of abandoning some
old working capacity; or there is sufficient extra demand to justify it,
and the extra revenues generated by increasing prices to equate this
extra demand with supply are expected to be less than those achieved by
increasing the capacity. Nevertheless, the monopolist may delay,
purposely, the process of new capital accumulation thereby giving more
time for the old capital goods to survive economically than would have
been otherwise possible.
If the industry is working in a competitive environment, the firms
possessing the technologically advanced outfit, which leads to the
reduction of the production cost, would have to see that others with old
capital equipment stop producing so that it can use its modern capital
to the fullest capacity. This can be achieved by reducing the price of
the product in such a way that production from the capital of old
technology becomes loss making. The monopolist, however, needs not
reduce the price to achieve this objective. He can switch off the
machines of old techniques without reducing the price to such an extent
as to make its use unprofitable.
The next section makes a quick review of the work done in this
field. Then we set up a mathematical model generalising the input-output
analysis to take account of the situation, and examine how this model
with the layers of techniques can be constructed. For the empirical
analysis the data of US 3-digit chemical industry will be used.
1, LAYERS OF TECHNIQUES
The fixed capital embodies the technology of the time when it was
newly installed. This embodied technology remains almost the same up to
the time the equipment embodying it is scrapped. The technological
progress comes about by the installation of new equipment, embodying
more profitable techniques at the current price structure. At a
particular time equipment installed at different past dates will be
simultaneously working, having, of course, different productivities and
profits. In understanding the working of the economy, we can neglect
this embodiment of technological change in the equipment only at the
cost of relevance. Thus in a growing economy there will be a layers of
techniques of different technologies working simultaneously.
Let [C.sup.K.sub.j] represent the capacity of the fixed capital
equipment of the kth technique for producing the jth commodity.
Similarly, [A.sup.K.sub.j] and [L.sup.K.sub.j] stand for the column
vectors of the commodity and labour inputs per unit of production of the
jth commodity by the kth technique. Furthermore, let
[sup.f][B.sup.K.sub.j] and [sup.w][B.sup.K.sub.j] give the column
vectors of the fixed and working capital stock requirements respectively
per unit of production of the jth commodity by the kth techniques. And
finally, let there may be [m.sub.j] techniques working to produce the
jth commodity.
If all the capital equipments are working to the full capacity,
then the total output of the jth commodity will be
[X.sub.j] = [[m.sub.j].summation over (K=1)][C.sup.K.sub.j] where j
= 1,2,3,.... n (1)
the average input-output coefficients will be given by
[a.sub.ij] = ([[m.sub.j].summation over (K=1)][C.sup.K.sub.j]
[a.sup.K.sub.ij]/[X.sub.j]) i = 1,2,...., n (2)
whereas the price structure will be such that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
for all k and in matrix algebra notation
[P.sub.j] = [PA.sup.K.sub.j] + w[L.sup.K.sub.j] + rP
[sup.w][B.sup.K.sub.j] [S.sup.K.sub.j] (4)
It is noted as while the row vector of prices (p), the wage rate
(w) and the interest rate (r) are the same for all the techniques, the
residual [S.sup.K.sub.j] are different for each one, which emphasises
that the technical change comes about by the installation of new
equipment embodying more profitable techniques at the current price
structure. In fact it is on the value of this residual that the actions
of units depend. When an investment is being done in an equipment
pertaining to a new technology, the expected residual should be large as
not only to cover the interest and depreciation charges of the fixed
capital but also the risk as well as the profit expectations of the
entrepreneur. It may be recalled that this residual is not like a fixed
annuity over the physical life time of the equipment, as it is the case
if there is no technical progress and, hence, no obsolescence. In the
age of advancing technology, the value of this residual should be
gradually declining and an investor should take this into account while
making his investment.
However, the returns on the fixed capital are not essential for the
firm to remain in production. Once the fixed capital is installed and if
it is not economically worthwhile to produce with it, it can only fetch
its scrap value. So its opportunity cost is almost zero. This, of
course, does not imply that there must not be expectation of sufficient
returns before it is installed at all. Therefore, in taking decisions
whether to continue the production process, the unit will not take into
consideration any returns on the fixed capital by continuing production.
It should go on producing until it can cover the variable cost of
production. In other words, a unit will remain in production until its
residual is not negative. Thus the price of the jth commodity [P.sub.j]
will determine which techniques should be used in the production and
which should not.
Let [m.sub.j] be the least efficient technique required to be in
production to meet with the demand. For that
[P.sub.j] = [PA.sup.mj.sub.j] + w[L.sup.mj.sub.i] + rP
[sup.w][B.sup.mj.sub.j] + [S.sup.mj.sub.j] (5)
The above equation will be valid for one technique of each of the
industries, namely for the marginal technique which is on the verge of
obsolescence. The condition that the total output of each industry
should be just sufficient to meet with the demand of its product will
uniquely determine the number of techniques in use. Consequently the
price structure will be such that all those techniques required to
produce will be economically feasible. An increase in the demand might
induce some obsolete techniques to be brought back into production by
suitably adjusting the price structure and vice versa.
Collecting Equation (5) for each industry, viz. the marginal or
zero residual units, we derive the price determining equation for the
system as
P = P[bar.A] + [sup.w][bar.L] + rP [sup.w][bar.B] (6)
where [bar.A], [bar.L] and [sup.w][bar.B] denote the sets of input,
labour and working capital stock requirements respectively for the
marginal techniques which are on the verge of obsolescence.
As we can see that the current price structure is related to the
current wage and interest rates as well as to the least efficient
technique and not to the average or the best practice technique.
Besides, the profit rate and the value of fixed capital do not play any
role in the determination of price structure.
If the production of the marginal technique units is represented by
the vector X, then the net output available for use is given by
P (I - [bar.A])[bar.X] (7)
out of this, rP [sup.w][bar.B][bar.X] is the income of the interest
receivers, and the rest the wage incomes of those working with the
marginal units. Hence the wage rate is given by
P(I - [bar.A] - r [sup.w][bar.B])[bar.X]/[bar.L][bar.X] (8)
which implies that given the interest rate, the marginal technique
determines both the price structure and the real wage rate. Similarly
given the real wage rate, the marginal technique determines the price
structure as well as the interest rate. There is one degree of freedom.
Either the interest rate or the wage rate can be determined.
The marginal technique itself will be determined in such a way that
total savings in the economy are equal to the total investment and other
autonomous demand. As less and less efficient techniques, in the sense
of having lesser values of residual, are brought into production, both
employment and savings will increase. The saving rate is likely to be
higher from the residual income than that from the income from wages or
interest. Therefore, such a redistribution of income in favor of the
residual income earners will increase the total savings even from the
old techniques. Over and above there will be some savings by the income
receivers from the increased production. Thus bringing more and more
marginal techniques into production will increase the total savings in
the economy. In the opposite case of taking more and more marginal firms
out of production will decrease the total savings. Therefore, the number
of firms in operation depends on the savings out of their production
matching the investment and other autonomous demand.
2. HIGH NOMINAL INTEREST RATES AND COST-PUSH INFLATION
From Equation 6 we have seen that price structure or fix price
system is given by
P = P[bar.A] + w[bar.L] + rP [sup.w][bar.B]
Let W be represented in terms of commodity or as a vector of
commodities C then
P = PC[bar.L] + P[bar.A] + rP [sup.w][bar.B] (9)
It may be noted that as C is a column vecter and [bar.L] a row
vector C[bar.L] is a (n x n) matrix. So
P(I - [bar.A] - C[bar.L] - r [sup.w][bar.B]) = 0 (10)
As shown elsewhere Mathur (1963) there will be only one value of r
which will be associated with positive P vector and it will be given by
the reciprocal of the largest Eigen value of the matrix
[sup.w][bar.B][(I - [bar.A] - C[bar.L]).sup.-1]. This shows that for
every real wage, the equilibrium rate of interest is determined by the
technology on the verge of obsolescence (no profit technology). It is
obvious that as we move to more and more efficient technologies, the
equilibrium rate of interest will be progressively higher and higher for
a given wage rate. Alternatively, for a given interest rate real wage
rate will be greater.
If nominal interest rate P is greater than equilibrium interest
rate r, Equation (9) becomes
P = P(C[bar.L] + [bar.A]) + [rho]P [sup.w][bar.B]
P = P(C[bar.L] + [bar.A]) + rP [sup.w][bar.B] + ([rho] - r)P
[sup.w][bar.B]
P = P + ([rho] - r)[rho]P [sup.w][bar.B]
This is impossible since ([rho] -r), P, as well as [sup.w][bar.B]
are positive. The only way to have a feasible solution is for input
prices to be different form output prices viz.
[P.sup.t] = [P.sup.t-1](C[bar.L] + [bar.A]) +
r[P.sup.t-1][sup.w][bar.B] + ([rho] - r)[P.sup.t-1][sup.w] [bar.B] (11)
If we assume that in period t-1 the equilbrium interest rate
prevails then
[P.sup.t] = [P.sup.t-1] + ([rho] - r)[P.sup.t-1][sup.w][bar.B] (12)
from the above equation it is clear that with fix price system a
higher nimonal interst rate than the equilibrium one will lead to
increases in prices. Not only that, the increases will be different for
different conmmodities depending on their working capital requirements per unit of output. Thus we have a cost push inflation and inflation is
not neutral.
In a flexible price monopolistic case also, the higher nominal
interst rate will lead to higher marginal cost, and as marginal revenue would tend to be equal to this, the price of the commodity will
increase. It may be noted that in this case the capital at change will
be total capital rather than working capital only.
3. UNEMPLOYMENT OF THE RESOURCES AND OBSOLESCENCE
Let in matrix algebra notation, [A.bar], [L.bar], [sup.f][B.bar]
and [sup.w][B.bar] stand for the input, labour, fixed and working
capital stock requirements respectively per unit of production of the
best practice technique in the economy, which is formed by collecting
the technique with the largest residual for each industry, and let
[F.bar] denote the column vector of the extra final demand to be
satisfied by the best practice technique, then the balanced capacity
creation will be given by (13) becomes
[C.bar] = [(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1][F.bar] (13)
the requirements of the extra capital goods and the extra working
capital stocks to achieve [C.bar] by
[sup.f][B.bar][C.bar] = [sup.f] [B.bar][(I -
[A.bar]).sup.-1][F.bar] (14)
and
[sup.w][B.bar][C.bar] = [sup.w] [B.bar][(I -
[A.bar]).sup.-1][F.bar] (15)
whereas the extra employment will be
[L.bar][C.bar] = [L.bar][(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1][F.bar] (16)
If the increase in the final demand is lesser than the extra demand
to be satisfied by the best practice technique, [DELTA]F < [F.bar],
then capacity of the least efficient technique will be unutilised. Using
the notation of Equation (6), the unutilised capacity of the least
efficient technique will be equal to
U = [(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1]([F.bar] - [DELTA]F) (17)
and the newly created unemployment equal to
[bar.L]U = [bar.L][(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1]([F.bar] - [DELTA]F) (18)
Hence, the net employment will be given by the subtraction of
Equation (16) from Equation (18)
[bar.L]U - [L.bar][C.bar] = [bar.L][(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1]([F.bar] -
[DELTA]F) - [L.bar] [(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1][F.bar] (19)
or
[bar.L]U - [L.bar][C.bar] = [[bar.L][(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1] -
[L.bar][(I - [A.bar]).sup.-1]][F.bar] - [bar.L][(I -
[A.bar]).sup.-1][bar.F] (20)
where the first term of the right hand side is positive, since the
productivity of the best practice technique is greater than that of the
least efficient technique.
Therefore, it is evident that in translating the extra final demand
of macro-models, the best practice coefficients will be more useful than
the average ones, while in assessing the incidence of obsolescence,
unemployment, etc. the least efficient coefficients will be the more
appropriate ones. Moreover, if the extra final demand to be satisfied by
the best practice technique is larger than the change in the final
demand of the economy, there will be a rise in the unemployment. The net
employment will take its highest value when there is no change in the
final demand of the economy. Thus the present level of employment will
be maintained when the change in the final demand of the economy is such
that Equation (20) will become equal to zero.
4. DATA REQUIREMENT
The preceding analysis points out that the knowledge of both best
practice and least efficient coefficient is more essential than the
knowledge of average coefficients for disaggregating planning and
forecasting as well as for exercising a suitable economic policy.
Therefore, the analysis underlines the need for compiling input-output
tables referring to the best practice and the least efficient
techniques, rather than to the average technique, in order to improve
the reliability of input-output estimates.
The data were tabulated by the US Census Bureau from its
Longitudinal Research Database (LRD). This research is based on data
from the 1982 (1) Census of Manufacturers. Individual establishment data
in the LRD file were sorted at three digit level according to the
following scheme. First the cost per unit of output for every
establishment in every industry was computed. Output was defined as
shipment plus the changes in the finished goods and half of
goods-in-progress inventories between 1981 and 1982. Total variable cost
was defined as the sum of the purchased materials, fuels, electricity,
communication services, and building and machinery repairs plus worker
payroll and supplementary labour cost. Thus the information gathered at
this stage pertained to the average variable cost (AVC) of each
establishment. Disclosure rules prevent the Census of Bureau from
releasing information on any single establishment. Therefore, the unit
of observation had to be changed from an establishment to a group of
establishments. This was done by first arranging all establishments in
order of rising unit variable cost within each three digit industry as a
whole. Then groups of establishments were formed in such a way that unit
cost of each establishment within a group was less than that of any
establishments in the subsequent group. The number of establishments
that fell within a group was determined in such a way that this number
be equal for all groups within an industry.
Once these groups were formed information was collected for
variables like output, employment, material and energy inputs, wages,
etc. In fact most of the data available on the short file of the Census
were collected. We did not collect the data regarding individual
material input as that would have led to tabulating data from the
comprehensive files themselves. This would have been not only very
time-consuming but also quite costly in term of resources. Further, it
would have been much beyond our aim to have a preliminary understanding
of the dimensions and hence practical importance of the problem of
layers of techniques in US manufacturing industry.
For empirical testing we select the following eight US three digit
chemical industries to measure the effects of technological change under
the state of flux. These three digit industries areas: Industrial
Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281), Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC
282), Drugs (SIC 283), Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 284), Paints
and Allied Products (SIC 285), Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 286),
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287) and Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 289).
Among the eight US three-digit chemical industries, Industrial Chemicals
(SIC 281), Drugs (SIC 283), and Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287) have 25
groups of establishments and the other five industries consist of 50
groups. List of variables used in this analysis is as below:
Variable Description
AVC Variable Cost Per Dollar Worth of Output
EF Fuel Cost Per Dollar Worth of Output
EE Electricity Purchased Per Dollar Worth of Output
Energy Total Energy Cost Per Dollar Worth of Output
5. MARGINAL INPUT-OUTPUT COEFFICIENTS OF U. S. 3-DIGIT CHEMICAL
INDUSTRY
For the empirical analysis the required data (as mentioned above)
for the U.S. 3-digit chemical industry is available and also fulfill the
requirement for the construction of best-practice and least efficient
coefficients.
Table 1 shows the marginal input-output coefficients at different
level of capacity of 3-digit US chemical industry. Five levels of
capacity are assumed, i.e., 10 percent, 25 percent, 50 percent, 75
percent and 90 percent, which implies that five layers of techniques are
working simultaneously experiencing different cost per unit of output.
It is further assumed that 50 percent is the level for average
techniques. The next step is to convert these coefficients to
percentages of the average technique, and finally an index of
coefficients for alternative capacity level can be achieved.
5.1. Marginal Input-Output Coefficients of Variable Cost and Energy
Cost Per Dollar Worth of Output
The chemical industry modernised existing facilities by
retro-fitting with updated, largely computerised equipment and
instrumentation. Computers, programmable controls, computerised sensors for temperature, pressure, flow rate liquid levels, material analysers,
and other process equipments have been increasingly diffused. Pneumatic controls have been more and more replaced by electronic signals and
apparatus (except in the processing of flammable materials). (2) This
throws light on the idea that the chemical industry is in the process of
change. Analysis of this section is based on the marginal coefficients
of the above mentioned variables of different sectors of US 3-digit
chemical industry. At a particular time, there is an economy, where
simultaneously layers of techniques are working. After the construction
of marginal coefficients for variable cost per dollar worth of output,
forecast can be made on the basis of given information, of how much
variable cost can be saved after a particular elapse of time. Assuming
that the middle value is the average value, how much will be the
divergence from both sides of the practices, i.e., worst- and
best-practice?
Looking at the marginal coefficients of variable cost per dollar
worth of output, in all sectors of the US 3-digit chemical industry, a
gradual shift of the coefficient is observed, reflecting the continuous
introduction of new-practice technologies. The difference describes the
ability to produce output with different technologies.
Further, it is assumed that the replacement of all chemical sector
is 5 percent per annum, then our calculations at the 10 percent level of
capacity describes the marginal marginal coefficients of the previous
two years. At the 25 percent level of capacity level, it means the
coefficients of five years, and so on. The 50 percent level of capacity
represents the average technology. The ratio between the best practice
and least efficient will be clarified by examining Table 2.
It is clear that the ratio between the best- and worst-practice 90
percent and 10 percent of capacity (in terms of percentage) is maximum
(1.67) in Drugs (SIC 283) and minimum (1.15) in Paints and Allied
Products (SIC 285). If there is continuous change in technology,
establishments can save more. On the basis of this information,
forecasts can be made and much variable cost can be saved in the future.
When large ratios are observed, it means that the rate of obsolescence
is very fast, however, when the ratio is small it means that rate of
obsolescence is not very fast.
5.2. Marginal Coefficients for Energy
Information on the quantities of energy required per unit of output
is interesting for two reasons. First, such information will indicate
how the industrial demand for energy changes with the mix of output.
Second, it will indicate how the pattern of commodity prices will,
initially, respond to change in energy prices.
Since the early 1970s when it was realised that energy prices might
be below their true scarcity value, various methods of analysing energy
use and energy substitution possibilities have been developed and
refined. Among the methods used for determining levels of energy content
in producing goods is "energy input-output analysis" which
recognises the interdependence of all sectors of the economy and their
contribution to the energy embodied in specific goods and services.
All the work on these lines is based on average input-output
analysis, which is based on the average technique, so it is not very
helpful in forecasting of demand. For accurate forecasting it is better
to construct the marginal input-output coefficients, which are based on
different layers of techniques.
Table 3 indicates the ratio of marginal coefficients for energy of
best and least efficient practices. We construct the marginal
coefficients for three energy variables of US 3-digit chemical industry.
Drugs (SIC 283), Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 286) and
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287) are saving more energy than other
sectors due to technology. Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 284) and
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 285) are the lowest savers of energy
among the eight sectors US chemical industry. Fuel is saved more by
Drugs (SIC 283) and more electricity is saved by Industrial Organic
Chemicals (SIC 286). The variation in ratios is from 1.14 (Soap,
Cleaners and Toilet Goods) to 2.16 (Drugs). Whereas the variations in
fuel is from 1.10 (Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods) to 5.40 (Drugs) and
in electricity it is from 1.46 (Paints and Allied Products) to 3.56
(Industrial Organic Chemicals). For electricity three groups can be
distinguished, one is 1.46 to 1.65 (Plastics Materials and Synthetics;
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods; and Paints and Allied Products),
another is from 1.65 to 2.00 (Agricultural Chemicals, Industrial
Inorganic Chemicals, and Miscellaneous Chemicals) and the third is above
2.00 (Drugs, and Industrial Organic Chemicals), but under the column of
fuel (EF) more variations can be observed than in the case of
electricity; this effect is also reflected under the column of energy.
Another way in which marginal input-output coefficients can be
estimated is based on the estimated values of coefficients corresponding
to percentages of total capacity, i.e., the last and first estimated
observation of each techniques represents the marginal coefficients of
worst and best practice technique respectively. So each and every
technique has two marginal coefficients, worst and best. Table 6 depicts
these coefficients. Table 4 shows that the coefficients of least
efficient side of every technique is higher than the coefficient of most
efficient side of the next new technique. Even best-practice has also
two coefficients, and the same is true for the worst practice groups of
firms.
6. FORECASTING IN AN ECONOMY WITH SEVERAL LAYERS OF TECHNIQUES
As already discussed in previous sections, new techniques are
producing output with less variable cost, labour cost, and energy cost
per dollar worth of output. At the same time if demand is not increasing
pari passu, the old vintage will fetch its scrap value. These are the
marginal input-output coefficients, de facto which explain the real
situation of the economy, when the economy is working under a spectrum
of techniques, having different productive efficiencies.
If it is assumed that new capacity is increasing 5 percent by the
installation of new technology, then 5 percent of old capacity which is
on the verge of obsolescence, will no longer be working. Table 5 shows
that how many groups of old vintages close down in each sector if
ceteris paribus, new capacity is created (5 percent) by the new
techniques. The same methodology can be used for the forecasting of
energy cost and labour cost per dollar worth of output in each sector of
US chemical industry. Table 5 analyses the effect on energy cost per
dollar worth of output in the US 3-digit chemical industry when 5
percent new capacity is created, assuming demand to be constant.
Suppose that autonomous demand is increased by 5 percent, in the
short run it is impossible for the producers to fill the gap between
demand and supply by installing new technology. The establishments will
try to use unutilised capacity. The minimum condition for restarting the
capacity is that the prevailing price must not be less than their
average variable cost. There are two possibilities, either variable cost
goes down or price will go up to cover their average variable cost. The
first is unlikely so normally price will go up, which is cost push
inflation; price is determined by cost instead of the market mechanism.
Table 6 shows the highest level of variable cost and energy cost per
dollar worth of output, if 5 percent new autonomous demand is fulfilled in the short run by using the old vintage.
Table 7 shows that when demand increases the utilisation of
resources will also increase, but without increase in the price levels
the supply will not increase. The same phenomenon will occur in the
labour market and here the relationship between cost-push inflation and
unemployment can be seen. New capacity increases the rate of
obsolescence, and non-profit firms on the verge of obsolescence cannot
bear the burden of a cut in prices due to increase in supply. Without an
increase in demand, they are not able to survive and disappear causing
unemployment, so the Phillips curve will be pushed horizontally
eastward. Section 7.1 discusses this relationship in detail.
6.1. Movement of Energy Cost in an Economy with Several Layers of
Techniques
As discussed above the economy has a spectrum of techniques working
simultaneously with different structures of average variable cost of
production, i.e., technological surplus. It is the technique with almost
zero surplus that determines the price structure.
All techniques which are better than these marginal ones would be
working at full capacity. New establishments will be using less energy
per dollar worth of output than the old establishments which will be
closing down, so there will be generation of surplus if demand does not
increase pari passu. If the strategy of a new establishment is to
increase the price of energy, the establishments on the verge of
obsolescence would try to recoup the higher energy-bill by increasing
prices. If simultaneously demand also increases, it will be able to save
itself. If not, its attempt to increase the price will be abortive and
it will have no alternative but to close down. This will create surplus
with price rises. At the other extreme there will be a rise in prices as
the increased rates of energy instigated by new establishments could
only be thus absorbed by the old establishments. In the real world, the
result will be somewhere in between. Thus it does not determine the
trade-off between inflation and surplus but is the result of the
introduction of energy-saving technological progress and the struggle of
firms becoming obsolete to remain in business. Thus when innovations are
being translated into new investment a rise in prices and energy cost
can be expected coupled with a decline in surplus.
When the burst of activity resulting from innovation is over,
surplus will be generated from the following sources:
(i) The extra activity generated in the capital goods sector will
taper off and together with it a lot of secondary production activity
generated as a consequence. This will of course, throw out energy used
in sub-marginal establishments that activated during this period.
(ii) The newly created capacity will make some old technology
redundant and obsolete, i.e., the new techniques of production are
likely to use less to produce the same amount of goods as the one on its
way out.
This will indicate not only a slowing down of price rises but even
its reversal. However, the energy cost of those remaining in use may
still increase. That may be the market signal to less efficient firms to
close down when their extra output is not required. So the phenomenon of
the co-existence of rising real energy cost and rising surplus is to be
expected.
After explaining the basic theory of this phenomenon, it is easy to
understand Table 9, which assumes that 5 percent of output is produced
by new capacity, implying that the price level will fall, and old
vintages which are on the verge of obsolescence are closing down,
creating unemployment. When autonomous demand rises, the price level
will increase due to increasing costs; however, employment level will
increase.
From Table 7 it is clear that when autonomous demand increases,
prices will also increase due to the cost-push phenomenon, and more
resources will be employed. The increase is likely to be different in
different sectors depending upon their input requirement per unit of
output.
The above approach gives the empirical evidence for the analysis of
the relationship between inflation and the uses of energy resources on
the basis of the structural requirement for the energy in the different
sectors in an economy with several existing layers of techniques with
different productive efficiencies.
Is there any theoretical explanation of the above phenomenon? High
nominal interest rate affects the economy in two ways. Firstly it
increases the rate of obsolescence. No-profit firms on the verge of
obsolescence cannot bear the burden of extra nominal interest rates at
current prices. There is only one way to escape. That is to increase
prices. If they are able to do so they survive creating inflation and
those which are not able to do so just disappear, creating surplus.
Recapitulation
Since the early days of input-output analysis, input-output
forecasts of total demand based on a given final bill of goods have been
made. Thus far, however, it seems that all studies have made use of what
we call "Average" input-output coefficients, i.e., those shown
in published input-output tables. Do these represent the real situation
of the economy? In fact an economy consists of several layers of
techniques, and these average coefficients are simply a weighted average
of them, and are therefore not suitable for many aspects of analysis and
policy.
An economy having continuous technical advance will embody a
portion of improving know-how in the new investment being undertaken.
Investment of different vintages will work with different productive
efficiencies, and may require different amounts of various inputs to
produce a unit of output. At a particular time, fixed capital equipment
of several vintages may be expected to be in place for production. When
investment involves equipment of the latest technique, the older
equipment may also continue in production, though by the very nature of
things it is likely to be earning lesser returns. The old equipment will
go on producing until enough capital of the newer vintages is
accumulated to satisfy total demand for that commodity.
However, after installation of fixed capital equipment, when it
eventually becomes not economically worthwhile to produce with, it may
only fetch its scrap value. Thus its opportunity cost is almost zero.
Therefore, in taking the decision whether to continue in production, the
unit will not consider whether it can get any return on fixed capital by
continuing production. It should continue production as long as it can
cover the average variable cost of production. In other words, a unit
will remain in production until its technological surplus is not
negative.
So, looking at the economy as consisting of several layers of
techniques gives a way to spell out the implications of macro economic
situations for micro levels. For instance, if macro economic
consideration points to reducing total use of the resources, a map of
the layers of the techniques of the economy should be able to pinpoint
the different regions or industries that are likely to be affected. In
such cases, to be able to delineate the effects of extra demand or of
new investment on the production or utilisation of the resources in the
economy, we require marginal input-output coefficients instead of the
weighted average that are at present computed worldwide. Similarly, for
capacities going out of production either because of lack of demand, or
obsolescence, knowledge of the least efficient techniques of production
is essential.
It is observed from the previous analysis that every best-practice
in US 3-digit chemical sector saves energy per dollar worth of output.
Interestingly, it is observed that it is the marginal coefficients,
which allow input-output analysis to meet the challenge of precision for
the fast-developing forecasting industry. And the technique developed by
P. N. Mathur, allows analysis of the effect of monetary and fiscal
policy down to the level of establishments, providing the detailed
effects of the policy or any economic activity, and giving a way to
spell out the implications of macro economic situation to micro economic
phenomena.
Comments
Tauseef Azid has written several articles on various economic
issues on the basis of his specialisation, the Layers of Techniques
approach. Although I had some idea about the working of this
methodology, this is the first time that I read the material seriously
and somewhat understood its working.
Before I comment on the paper itself I must mention that I find the
technique much more appealing that I had imagined. I do not hesitate in
making even a proposal that would certainly provoke all those critics
who think enough is enough and who find it difficult to absorb any more
layers. In my opinion, so far only one pile of layers has been analysed.
The framework can be extended to various other applications, for example
in models of consumer demands and household production.
Coming to the paper itself, apart from a few points relating to technical aspect and presentation, the paper makes an excellent
contribution to knowledge and it provides a practical framework for
exploring energy conservation in a growing industry. Within its given
framework the paper has no weakness worth mentioning and it is of high
academic standard.
Looking at other side of the picture, I would first like to seek a
few clarifications. First, in Equation (3) why there are exactly as many
labour inputs and capital inputs as the number of material inputs, n,
associated with any particular layer of technique, k, in each industry
j? Second, can the 'residual' S be interpreted as profit or
rent. Dose it measure the rent on superior techniques compared to the
marginal technique? Third, why in the equation for the least efficient
technique (5) we still have the term S present? Should it be dropped?
It also appears that Section 3 is not of much relevance in the
paper and it may better be dropped. It only attempts to explain business
cycle in the Layers of Techniques framework, while the paper at hand is
to do with energy consumption as an input.
Finally, a few questions that may be of interest to the authors are
as follows. First, according to Layers of Techniques framework efficient
techniques tend to drive out inefficient techniques. First, within the
given framework the energy coefficient of a more efficient technique is
necessarily smaller. In practice a more efficient technique with respect
to capital and labour may be more energy intensive. Can the framework be
suitably modified to allow this possibility? Second, can the assumption
of fixed input-output coefficient be completely done away, while still
keeping intact the concept of layers of techniques. Is it reasonable to
assume that in terms of relative efficiency two techniques may have
anyone of the following patterns? (a) Technique A is strictly more
efficient to technique B at all ranges of output; (b) Technique A is no
less efficient than technique B at all ranges of output and A is
strictly more efficient in a certain range of output; and (c) Technique
A is strictly more efficient than technique B in a certain range of
output, and less efficient in the remaining range of output.
Eatzaz Ahmad
Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Almon, Clopper Jr., et al. (1974) 1985: Interindustry Forecasts of
the American Economy. Lexington, Mass: Lexington Books.
Arrow, K. and M. Hoeffenberg (1959) A Time Series Analysis of
Inter-industry Demands. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Aujac, H. (1972) New Approaches in French National Economy:
Input-Output Tables and echnological Forecasting. In A. Brody and P.
Carter (ed.). Contributions to Input-Output Analysis. Amsterdam: North
Holland Publishing Company.
Azid, T. (1993) Layers of Techniques, Cost Variability,
Obsolescence, and Marginal Input-Output Coefficients: A Case Study of US
Chemical Industry. A PhD Thesis submitted to University of Wales,
Aberystwyth.
Azid, T. (2002) Layers of Techniques, Marginal Input-Output
Coefficients and Phillips Curve: A Case of US Chemical Industry. Paper
presented in the 14th International Conference of Input-Output
Techniques, held in University of Quebec, Montreal, Canada.
Azid, T. and Akbar Noor (1999) Investment, Hysteresis and Layers of
Techniques: A case study of Agricultural Manufacturing Machinery in
Multan. The Pakistan Development Review 38:4.
Azid, T. and David Law (1994) A Theoretical and Empirical
Development of Professor Mathur's Vintage Capital Approach (Part
A). Economic Affairs 39.
Azid, T. and David Law (1995) A Theoretical and Empirical
Development of Professor Mathur's Vintage Capital Approach (Part
B). Economic Affairs 40.
Azid, T. and Dipak Ghosh (1998) Economics of P N Mathur. Economic
and Political Weekly 33.
Azid, T. and O. Choudhary (2005) New International Economic Order
and Its Effects on the Development of Muslim Countries. In M. Iqbal and
H. Ahmad (ed.) Poverty in Muslim Countries and the New International
Economic Order. Macmillan: Pelgrave.
Buzunov, R. A. (1970) Technical Economic Projection of Coefficients
of Direct Material Inputs. In A. P. Carter and A. Brody (ed.)
Contributions to Input-Output Analysis. Amsterdam: North Holland
Publishing Company.
Carter, A. P. (1970a) A Linear Programming System Analysing
Embodied Technological Change. In A. P. Carter and A. Brody (eds.)
Contributions to Input-Output Analysis. Amsterdam: North Holland
Publishing Company.
Carter, A. P. (1970b) Structural Change in the American Economy.
Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.
Fontela, E., et al. (1970) Forecasting Technical Coefficients and
Changes in Relative Prices. In A. P. Carter and A. Brody (ed.).
Galbraith, J. K. (1952) American Capitalism: The Concept of
Countervailing Power. Boston: Hougton Mifflin.
Henry, E. W. (1974) Relative Efficiency of RAS versus Least Squares
Methods of Updating Input-Output Structure. Economic and Social Review
1:2.
Hicks, J. R. (1965) Capital and Growth. Oxford University Press.
Law, D. and T. Azid (1993) The Causes of Non-Abandonment: Layers of
Techniques or Hysteresis. Pakistan Economic and Social Review 31.
Leontief, W. W. (1968) An Open Dynamic System for Long Range
Projections of Economic Growth. In P. N. Mathur and R. Bharadwaj (eds.)
Economic Analysis in Input-Output Framework. Bombay: Input-Output
Association.
Leontief, W. W. (1970) The Dynamic Inverse. In A. P. Carter and A
Brody (eds.) Contributions to Input-Output Analysis. Amsterdam: North
Holland Publishing Company.
Leontief, W. W. (1982) Some Thoughts on the Directions of the
Methodological Development and the Widening Possibilities of Application
Fields in Input-Output Analysis. In Input-Output Techniques. Budapest.
Mathur, P. N. (1963) An Efficient Path for the Technological
Transformation of an Economy. In T. Barna (ed.) Structural Independence
and Economic Development. London: Macmillan.
Mathur, P. N. (1977) A Study of Sectoral Prices and their movements
in British Economy In an Input-Output Framework. In W. Leontief (ed.)
Structure, System and Economic Policy. Cambridge University Press.
Mathur, P. N. (1986a) Price Behaviour with Vintage Capital.
Economics Department, University College of London, London. (Discussion
Paper No.20.)
Mathur, P. N. (1986b) Technical Progress, Price Change in
Monopolistic and Competitive Industries, Phillips Curve and Its Shift
with High Interest Rate--USA. Economics Department, University College
of London, London. (Discussion Paper No. 08.)
Mathur, P. N. (1989) Cost variability within US Manufacturing
Industry, Return to Scale, Product Mix and Suitable Industry
Classification for Studying Technical Change. Paper presented at the 9th
International Conference on Input-Output Techniques, Keszthely, Hungary.
Mathur, P. N. (1990) Why Developing Countries Fail to Develop.
Macmillan.
Middelhoek, A. J. (1970) Test of the Marginal Stability of
Input-Output Coefficients. In A. P. Carter and A. Brody (ed.)
Contributions to Input-Output Analysis. Amsterdam: North Holland
Publishing Company.
Ozaki, I. (1976) The Effects of Technological Change on Economic
Growth of Japan, 1950-70. In Polenkske and Skolka (ed.) Advances in
Input-Output Analysis. Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger.
Rashid, Z. (1989) Price Structure, Technological Obsolescence and
Labour Productivity--A Vintage Capital Approach. Singapore Economic
Review 34.
Salter, W. (1961) Productivity and Technical Change. (2nd ed).
London: Cambridge University Press.
Schumpeter, J. A. (t934) The Theory of Economic Development: An
inquiry into Profits, Credit, Interest and Business Cycle. Cambridge,
Mass: Harvard University Press.
Sevaldson, P. (1970) The Stability of Input-Output Coefficients. In
A. P. Carter and A. Brody (ed.) Contributions to Input-Output Analysis.
Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company.
Sevaldson, P. (1976) Price Changes as Causes of Variations
Input-Output Coefficients. In Polenkske and Skolka (ed.). Advances in
Input-Output Analysis. Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger.
Stone, R. (1962) Multiple Classification in Social Accounting.
Bulletin de L'Institute International de Statistique 3.
Tilanus, C. B. (1967) Marginal vs. Average Input-Output
Forecasting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 81.
You, J. (1976) Embodied and Disembodied Technical Progress in the
United States, 1929-68. Review of Economics and Statistics 58.
(1) However, it is not a recent data, but for the understanding of
the problem, detailed data of any other year is not available. We are
also thankful to US National Science Foundation for the provision of
this data.
(2) For the advancement of the chemical industry see the various
issues of Chemical Engineering News, Chemical Engineering, and Chemical
and Engineering News.
Toseef Azid <toseefazid@bzu.edu.pk> is Professor of
Economics, Bahauddin Zakariya University, Multan. Mumtaz Anwar
<mumtaz_anwar@yahoo.com> is Assistant Professor, Department of
Economics, Punjab University, Lahore. M. Junaid Khawaja
<mjunkh@hotmail.com> is Assistant Professor, Abu Dhabi University,
UAE.
Table 1
Index of Marginal Input-Output Coefficients for 3-Digit U.S. Chemical
Industries (Base = 50 percent)
Level of Industrial Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281)
Capacity [right arrow]
Variables
[down arrow] 10% 25% 50% 75% 90%
AVC 89.84 94.83 100.00 111.45 114.44
EF 78.13 88.87 100.00 124.63 135.37
EE 75.89 87.73 100.00 127.18 139.02
Energy 76.65 88.11 100.00 126.34 137.80
Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC 282)
AVC 89.30 93.35 100.00 106.84 110.88
EF 60.07 75.16 100.00 125.55 140.65
EE 81.15 88.29 100.00 112.07 119.21
Energy 69.15 80.81 100.00 119.70 132.37
Drugs (SIC 283)
AVC 75.29 84.76 100.00 116.38 125.85
EF 31.73 57.91 100.00 145.18 171.36
EE 50.64 69.57 100.00 132.65 151.58
Energy 41.51 63.95 100.00 138.78 161.22
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 284)
AVC 87.86 92.67 100.00 108.72 113.53
EF 95.45 97.23 100.00 103.16 105.04
EE 81.86 89.06 100.00 113.03 120.22
Energy 89.81 93.84 100.00 107.31 111.40
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 283)
AVC 93.42 96.05 100.00 104.82 107.46
EF 89.24 93.54 100.00 107.87 112.17
EE 82.20 89.31 100.00 113.06 120.19
CPC 59.55 75.73 100.00 129.69 145.45
Energy 85.44 91.26 100.00 110.68 116.50
Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 286)
AVC 86.75 91.87 100.00 108.92 114.03
EF 53.83 71.66 100.00 131.06 148.88
EE 44.58 65.99 100.00 137.32 158.50
Energy 50.65 69.71 100.00 133.21 152.25
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287)
AVC 91.12 94.53 100.00 105.91 109.33
EF 37.53 61.55 100.00 141.60 165.61
EE 75.57 84.97 100.00 116.29 125.66
Energy 49.83 69.12 100.00 133.41 152.71
Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 287)
EF 52.34 70.20 100.00 129.80 147.72
EE 67.81 80.47 100.00 122.70 135.36
Energy 61.42 76.58 100.00 127.20 142.39
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.
Table 2
Ratio of Marginal Coefficients (Best Practice to Least Efficient
Techniques) for Variable Cost Per Dollar Worth of Output
Name of Industry 90% / 10% 75% / 25%
Industrial Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281) 1.30 1.18
Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC 282) 1.24 1.14
Drugs (SIC 283) 1.67 1.37
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 284) 1.29 1.17
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 285) 1.15 1.09
Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 286) 1.31 1.19
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 286) 1.20 1.12
Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 287) 1.21 1.12
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.
Table 3
Marginal Coefficients for Energy: Ratio of the Best to the Worst
Practice
Name of Industry EF EE
Industrial Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281) 1.73 1.40 1.83 1.45
Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC 282) 2.34 1.67 1.47 1.27
Drugs (SIC 283) 5.40 2.51 2.99 1.91
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 285) 1.10 1.06 1.47 1.27
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 285) 1.26 1.15 1.46 1.27
Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 286) 2.77 1.83 3.56 2.08
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287) 4.41 2.30 1.66 1.37
Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 289) 2.54 1.75 2.00 1.52
Name of Industry Energy
Industrial Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281) 1.80 1.43
Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC 282) 1.90 1.40
Drugs (SIC 283) 3.88 2.16
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 285) 1.24 1.14
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 285) 1.36 1.21
Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 286) 3.01 1.91
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287) 3.06 1.93
Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 289) 2.32 l.66
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.
Note: For every variable, the left column is the ratio 90 percent to
10 percent, and the right column is ratio 75 percent to 25 percent.
Table 4
Marginal Coefficients of Energy for Each Technique: The Best
and the Least Efficient
Most Least
Name of Industry Efficient Efficient
Industrial Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281)
01 0.116 0.216
02 0.104 0.108
Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC 282)
01 0.169 0.171
02 0.151 0.162
03 0.076 0.173
Drugs (SIC 283)
01 0.349 0.352
02 0.103 0.149
03 0.099 0.160
04 0.034 0.102
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 285)
01 0.131 0.133
02 0.059 0.104
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 285)
01 0.124 0.131
02 0.151 0.153
03 0.120 0.132
04 0.097 0.121
05
Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 28G)
01 0.139 0.143
02 0.115 0.116
03 0.113 0.115
04 0.062 0.090
05 0.063 0.064
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287)
01 0.265 0.266
02 0.102 0.113
03 0.081 0.101
04 0.039 0.046
Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 289)
01 0.211 0.215
02 0.080 0.115
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.
Table 5
Forecasting the Obsolescence of the Groups
Variable Cost per
Dollar Worth of
Variable Cost per Output of Group, After
Dollar Worth of New Created Capacity
Output of New (5%)
Created Capacity (on the Verge of
Name of Industry (5%) Obsolescence)
Industrial Inorganic 0.572 0.973
Chemicals (SIC 281)
Plastics Materials 0.727 0.929
and Synthetics (SIC
282)
Drugs (SIC 283) 0.432 0.778
Soap, Cleaners and 0.610 0.820
Toilet Goods (SIC
284)
Paints and Allied 0.715 0.841
Products (SIC 285)
Industrial Organic 0.683 0.933
Chemicals (SIC 286)
Agricultural 0.782 0.963
Chemicals (SIC 287)
Miscellaneous 0.690 0.857
Chemicals (SIC 289)
Number of
Groups Closing
Down, after
New Created
Capacity
Name of Industry (5%)
Industrial Inorganic 1
Chemicals (SIC 281)
Plastics Materials 2
and Synthetics (SIC
282)
Drugs (SIC 283) 2
Soap, Cleaners and 6
Toilet Goods (SIC
284)
Paints and Allied 2
Products (SIC 285)
Industrial Organic 2
Chemicals (SIC 286)
Agricultural 3
Chemicals (SIC 287)
Miscellaneous 3
Chemicals (SIC 289)
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.
Table 6
Forecasting of the Energy Cost per Dollar Worth of Output after
5 Percent Capacity Created by New Technology
Name of Industry Energy Cost per Energy Cost per
Dollar Output of New Dollar Worth of
Created Capacity Output of the Group,
(5%) which is on the
Verge of
Obsolescence After
Created (5%)
Capacity
Industrial Inorganic 0.010 0.061
Chemicals (SIC 281)
Plastics Materials and 0.040 0.088
Synthetics (SIC 282)
Drugs (SIC 283) 0.010 0.038
Soap, Cleaners and 0.015 0.019
Toilet Goods (SIC 284)
Paints and Allied 0.010 0.014
Products (SIC 285)
Industrial Organic 0.038 0.140
Chemicals (SIC 286)
Agricultural 0.040 0.152
Chemicals (SIC 287)
Miscellaneous 0.018 0.048
Chemicals (SIC 289)
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.
Table 7
Variable Cost and Energy Cost per Dollar Worth of Output of That
Group, which is on the Verge of Obsolescence, after Generating
the Autonomous Demand (S Percent)
Name of Industry Variable Energy Cost
Cost per per Dollar
Dollar Worth of
Worth of Output
Output
Industrial Inorganic Chemicals (SIC 281) 0.805 0.062
Plastics Materials and Synthetics (SIC 282) 0.940 0.090
Drugs (SIC 283) 0.797 0.041
Soap, Cleaners and Toilet Goods (SIC 284) 0.832 0.020
Paints and Allied Products (SIC 285) 0.848 0.014
Industrial Organic Chemicals (SIC 28G) 0.947 0.143
Agricultural Chemicals (SIC 287) 0.973 0.159
Miscellaneous Chemicals (SIC 289) 0.866 0.050
Source: Calculated by authors themselves.