The fiscal reaction function and the transmission mechanism for Pakistan.
Khalid, Mahmood ; Malik, Wasim Shahid ; Sattar, Abdul 等
In developing economies such as Pakistan the fiscal transmission
mechanism needs to he identified, as active fiscal policy is practised
and large seigniorage revenues exist. In this context, the present study
aims at estimating the fiscal policy reaction function and identifying
the fiscal policy transmission mechanism. More specifically, the Vector
Autoregression (VAR) model, containing three variables (output gap and
inflation as policy objectives and fiscal deficit as a percentage of
GDP), has been estimated as a fiscal instrument. We find evidence of
fiscal policy in Pakistan being endogenous over the period 1965 to 2006.
Although the response to both the variables is significant, we find only
pro-cyclical response of fiscal policy to the business cycle
fluctuations specifically in the periods of boom. The effect of fiscal
policy changes on output and inflation is not significant. We also find
the evidence of contemporaneous response of policy to the state of the
economy, but the policy is not forward-looking at all.
JEL classification: H11, H30
Keywords: Fiscal Reaction Function, Fiscal Transmission Mechanism,
VAR
1. INTRODUCTION
Modern macroeconomics literature emphasises both the short run and
long run objectives of fiscal policy [Romer (2006)]. In the short run it
can be used to counter output cyclicality and/or stabilise volatility in
macro variables, which is descriptively same as of effects of the short
run monetary policy. Further for the long-run, fiscal policy can also
affect both "the demand and supply side of the economy. But in most
traditional analyses it is assumed that fiscal policy would adjust to
ensure the intertemporal budget constraint to be satisfied, while
monetary policy is free to adjust its instruments ['Ricardian
Regime' by Sargent (1982)] such as stock of money supply or the
nominal interest rate [Walsh (2003)]. The debt financing methods,
expenditure and tax powers of fiscal authorities i.e. the fiscal policy
has also been seen as to affect both the supply and demand side of the
economy. As noted by Baxter and King (1993), the initial Real Business
Cycle models had only the supply side effects of the fiscal policy,
where these were transmitted through the wealth effect and
labour-leisure choices of the household. Recently also New-Keynesian
type models with micro-foundations and sticky prices argue that still
through the supply side fiscal policy management could be accorded for
stabilisation [Linnemann and Schabert (2003)]. The demand side effects
of the fiscal policy could also be found only with more imperfections
such as 'Rule of Thumb' consumers or those with liquidity
constraints, which lead to exclusion of Ricardian equivalence [Gali, et
al. (2005)]. But all that depends on the structure of the economy, as
Blanchard and Perotti (2002) stated:
"The evidence from large-scale econometric models has been
largely dismissed on the grounds that, because of their Keynesian
structure, these models assume rather then document a positive effect of
positive fiscal expansion on output".
In order to gauge the effects of shocks in fiscal policy or its
responsiveness to various macro variables (i.e. the automatic
stabilisers property of fiscal instruments) one has to see the stance by
composition of budget from both the share of components and their
classifications. Normally macroeconomics 'fiscal stance' is
assessed by looking at the consolidated scale of public deficit. But the
dynamic effects of the shocks in government spending, taxes and the
consolidated budget deficit (thereby implying the composition of
inter-temporal budget constraint) can be altogether different in
magnitude and lags in implementation. For example, Blanchard and Perotti
(2002) noted, there is persistent affect of government spending on
private consumption, which is consistent with the Keynesian models but
opposite in the neoclassical approach. Further, there is new literature
on the theory of 'expansionary fiscal contraction', in which
the reduction in provision of those public goods which are in the
utility function of households (by virtue of reduction in government
expenditures) leads to increased spending by households to meet that gap
and thus components of aggregate demand increases.
On the other hand, government expenditures (GE) can be of permanent
and transitory nature. Both have different direct multiplier (Keynesian)
affects towards aggregate demand (AD) components, e.g. C & I. For
instance it could lead to increased AD directly in a standard IS-LM
framework, hence activating the idle production factors in the economy
and creating more employment and output growth. Moreover in recessionary
phases, when economy is in a liquidity trap (e.g. Japan), where private
investment demand becomes inelastic, fiscal policy (FP) can provide the
necessary stimulus to the economy for coming out of that trap. (1)
Further, in developing economies, GE also plays a complimentary role for
private investment.
On the financing side of GE such as tax, or inflation-seigniorage
(money printing) have different implications. Where as creating a debt
against the same would have yet another set of dynamic affects on the
macroeconomic variables. In case of money printing (fiscal dominance)
there are changes in price levels, hence controlling them by monetary
policy (MP) alone could be miss-targeted. If the increased GE is
supported by deficit which is financed by issuing bonds through banking
system, then it could lead to a crowding out of private investment if
the interest rate rises in the loan able funds market. Where as in
presence of a lose MP (passive FP) the interest rate would decrease and
output increase. So domestic debt raising cost would decline, but if
this is done through increase in Money supply (MS), exchange rate would
appreciate and there could be indirect impact on the foreign debt
servicing of the country.
On the other hand a Fiscal Policy (FP) stance through the tax
structure can affect the supply side of the economy by affecting the
household labour supply decisions or the firm's business financing
decisions etc. Direct and Indirect tax levels have different
transmission mechanism on economic agent's decision makings. For
instance as taxes would change the disposable incomes of household hence
affecting the household's consumption, investment, labour supply
and savings decisions. Further, by taxing the interest earnings, the
same would also change at dynamic levels as well.
Deficit levels, financing patterns and sources have altogether
different' implications for the macroeconomic variables. Domestic
versus external borrowing, multilateral and others, banking versus
non-banking and short-term versus long-term borrowing all have different
dynamic affects on the economy. There has been a large of literature
exploring these issues, for example Barro (1989) explored whether bonds
are net wealth or not. So Ricardian Equivalence (RE) can hold or may be
challenged, depending on the types of consumers and policy environments
such as imperfect loans market, timing of taxes, uncertainty of incomes
etc. [Barro (1989)].
Once the issue of fiscal stance is settled, yet another issue
arises, i.e. the fiscal policy transmission mechanism. FP is considered
to have dynamic transmission mechanism, as it carries longer policy lags
for different macro variables. In this case (FP) the private agents have
formed anticipations about the fiscal policy; hence it is not unexpected
[Blanchard and Perotti (2002)]. Further, with interaction to different
monetary policy stances considering its solvency constraint, it has
different impacts on key macro variables. In a standard case MP can
react to inflation and FP could to output and distribution. However MP
stabilisation policies have often fallen short of results as earlier
inflation biased policies, i.e. targeting potential output ([??]) above
the natural ([bar.Y]) rate were adopted. (2) Especially in developing
economies case, where private sector lacks the capacity to keep output
at the potential level and provide for all welfare maximising goods
through market mechanism. (3) Further new evidence show that fiscal
stance can also impact the prices in an economy [e.g. see Leeper (1991)
and Woodford (2001)].
Hence FP can affect the economy dynamically with different
theoretical assumptions about the structure of the economy differently.
It can have direct or indirect effects on levels and growth rates of
demand and supply side variables such as output, prices, exchange rate,
interest rate, balance of payment, debt, consumption, investment, labour
supply and its (FP) own future variables.
Once the transmission mechanism is identified then we can look for
the optimal reaction functions of the FP for policy consistency. As
policy makers have a certain loss function (assigned to them by society,
or in a public choice model the voters loss function which is dictated
to the policy maker in a public-agent model setting, which is to be
minimised with certain constraints). So there could be certain short-run
(output gap, inflation etc) objectives and long-run goals such as debt
sustainability. The constraints for a fiscal policy reaction function
(FPRF) would be the debt sustainability and stance of MP. The parameter
stability and symmetry in response (automatic stabilisers) for these
FPRF in the presence of business cycles, solvency conditions, debt
financing patterns, FP institutional regimes, society's objectives
and political regimes could be different in a developed and a developing
economy. (4) Further the issue of spend-tax or tax-spend, debt to
tax-revenue capacity and the inter-temporal budget constraint
consideration i.e. the causality debate for long-run fiscal
sustainability is yet inconclusive for developing economies.
In the context of developing economies, such as Pakistan, it
becomes more crucial to ascertain the fiscal transmission mechanism,
where active fiscal policy is practiced and large seigniorage revenues
exist. In this context, the present study aims at estimating fiscal
policy reaction function and identifying a fiscal policy transmission
mechanism. More specifically, Vector Autoregression (VAR) model
containing three variables, output gap and inflation as policy
objectives and fiscal deficit as percentage of GDP as fiscal instrument,
has been estimated. One of the three equations specifies fiscal policy
reaction function in which fiscal policy responds to state of the
economy. While the other two equations represent the transmission
mechanism of policy.
We find evidence of fiscal policy in Pakistan being endogenous over
the period 1965 to 2006. Though the response to both of the variables is
significant, we find only pro-cyclical response of fiscal policy to the
business cycle fluctuations. Also the procyclical response is seen more
in the periods of boom. On the other hand, we could not identify
transmission mechanism of fiscal policy with the help of model we have
estimated. We also find the evidence of contemporaneous response of
policy to state of the economy but the policy is not forward-looking at
all.
Rest of the study proceeds as follows. Section 2 deals with the
estimation methodology. It provides details regarding estimating fiscal
policy response function and transmission mechanism with the help of VAR
and estimating fiscal reaction function with contemporaneous variables
by Generalised Method of Moments (GMM). Detailed estimation results of
fiscal reaction function and transmission mechanism are given in Section
3. Finally Section 4 concludes the paper.
2. ESTIMATION METHODOLOGY
We have used three equation Vector Autoregression (VAR) technique
to estimate state-contingent fiscal reaction function as well as the
effect of fiscal policy changes on economic indicators--output gap and
inflation. (5) To find the direction of effect of different shocks on
the three variables. Further impulse response functions have also been
estimated. To overcome the issue of over parameterisation in the VAR, a
near-VAR model could be used. The paper also focuses on the response of
fiscal authority to changes in economic indicators over the business
cycle, as the government may react differently in recessions and booms.
To deal with the fact that standard reduced form VAR contains only
lagged values of all variables as regressors, fiscal reaction function
with contemporaneous variables could be used. But in this case the
problem arises that information on contemporaneous variables may not be
available to policy maker at the time of decision. The problem could be
solved by estimating the model by instrumental variables technique,
where past information set could be used as instruments. Detailed
discussion regarding estimation techniques is given below.
Consider the following three variables structural VAR,
[BX.sub.t] = [B.sub.0] + [[summation].sup.p.sub.i=1] [C.sup.i]
[X.sub.t-i] + [[xi].sub.t] (1)
Where [X.sub.t] is a vector given by,
[X.sub.t] = [[p.sub.t][y.sub.t][FD.sub.t]]
Where [FD.sub.t] is real fiscal deficit as percentage of real GDP,
[y.sub.t] is real GDP gap and [p.sub.t] is annualised inflation
calculated by GDP deflator. B is a matrix of coefficients with one on
the diagonal and off diagonal terms captures the contemporaneous effects
of variables on each other. [B.sub.0] is a vector of constant terms.
[C.sup.i] are the matrices of coefficients measuring the lagged effects
of variables on each other. [[xi].sub.t] is a vector of error terms that
contains zero mean, constant variance and serially as well as cross
uncorrelated innovations, i.e. these elements represent pure structural
shocks. Equation 1 can be converted into standard reduced form VAR with
only lagged variables on the right hand side.
[X.sub.t] = [A.sub.0] +
[[summation].sup.p.sub.i=1][A.sub.i][X.sub.t-i] + [e.sub.t] (2)
Where, [A.sub.0] = [B.sup.-1][B.sub.0]
[A.sub.i] = [B.sup.-1][C.sup.i] and [e.sub.t] = [B.sup.-1]
[[xi].sub.t]
Here [e.sub.t] contains the elements that have zero mean, constant
variance and are serially uncorrelated. However, these errors might be
contemporaneously correlated, i.e.
E([e.sub.jt])= 0,
Var([e.sub.jt)]= [[sigma].sup.2.sub.j],
Cov([e.sub.jt],[e.sub.jt-1])=0,
but Cov ([e.sub.jt], [e.sub.kt]) may or may not be equal to zero.
Now the problem is to estimate Equation 2 and then using these
estimated parameters identify the structural parameters and to recover
structural shocks from Equation 1 by imposing appropriate restrictions
on structural parameters. Equation 2 can be estimated by OLS because
right hand side variables of all equations are same. However if we allow
different lag length in different equations then the system has to be
estimated as seemingly unrelated (SUR) model, [Enders (2004)]. To
identify the shocks a reasonable assumption is that fiscal authority
responds the shocks in the economy only with one period lag but fiscal
policy changes contemporaneously affect output gap that further affect
inflation with a one period lag. (6) The appropriate number of
restrictions to make model exactly identified is ([n.sup.2] - n / 2),
where n is the number of variables in the VAR, [Enders (2004)]. Here the
fiscal policy shocks are estimated residuals from the first equation in
the system of Equations 1.
It is note worthy that VAR model deals with estimating fiscal
reaction function only with lagged variables as economic indicators. But
this may not be the case, however in reality. Fiscal authority may
respond to contemporaneous values of economic indicators, provided that,
the authority has the information on the state of the economy without
any lag. If this is not the case, the reaction function could be
estimated by GMM, i.e. an instrumental variable technique. Now, the
fiscal reaction function with contemporaneous variables can be written
as
[FD.sub.t] = [alpha] + [beta][Gap.sub.t] + [gamma][Inf.sub.t] (3)
This can be written as an orthoganality condition;
[([FD.sub.t] - [alpha] - [beta][Gap.sub.t] -
[gamma][Inf.sub.t])[Z.sub.t-1]] = 0 (4)
Where [Z.sub.t-1] contains information set available to the policy
maker at time period t. The above orthogonality condition provides the
basis for estimating reaction function with GMM.
3. DATA AND ESTIMATION RESULTS
We have estimated a fiscal reaction function and fiscal
transmission mechanism for Pakistan over the period 1965-2006. All the
data are taken from International Financial Statistics of International
Monetary Fund. Output gap has been estimated as percentage deviation of
real GDP from its quadratic trend values] Three different instruments of
fiscal policy; government expenditure, government revenues and fiscal
deficit, are taken, in real terms, as percentage of real GDP. Where as
the inflation is taken as growth rate of GDP deflator.
To model the three variables, VAR in levels has been used. OLS
gives efficient parameter estimates as long as the right hand side
variables are same in all equations. At the same time over
parameterisation in VAR can be avoided by allowing different lags in
different equations. But in that case the so called Near-VAR is
estimated as a SUR model. In the present study we have focused on
estimating the transmission mechanism by VAR. however-to get efficient
results in a model without over parameterisation, the Near-VAR technique
has also been used, in which only significant lagged variables are
included.
We start with estimating fiscal reaction function and fiscal
transmission mechanism, using the Fiscal deficit as the fiscal policy
instrument. The lags in the VAR are selected on the basis of Akaike
Information Criteria as well as the LM test for serial correlation. Two
lags were found to be appropriate on both these criteria. There are some
strong conclusions coming out from these results. The results are given
in Table 1 and Figure 1.
First the Fiscal policy stance taken from the fiscal deficit
perspective is not exogenous. Our results show that the policy changes
can be predicted by economic indicators, here output gap and inflation.
Secondly the results in table below show pro-cyclical response of
Fiscal authority to the state of the economy. Both output gap and
inflation predict positive changes in fiscal deficit in one period
ahead. This shows that in setting the Fiscal Deficit as a fiscal policy
instrument the fiscal authority is taking leverage from the fiscal space
generated by the boom of the economy. But this is only for one period
and does not take into account further lags.
Thirdly the pro-cyclical response of fiscal policy shows that on
average the stabilisation objective is not considered while conducting
the policy. Therefore the automatic-stabilisation role of the fiscal
instruments does not seem to hold for Pakistan. This defies the
Keynesian stance of fiscal policy where Fiscal authority would expand in
those time when private agents are not willing to invest (Liquidity
Trap) and government being a non-profit oriented entity would increase
its expenditures. As interest rate channel does not work in Liquidity
Trap hence monetary policy is ineffective, and increased government
expenditure could positively affect the Aggregate demand, thereby pull
the economy out of recession.
Fourthly there seems to be a policy coordination problem between
Monetary and Fiscal authorities. As claimed by the recent monetary
policy statement by Central Bank [State Bank of Pakistan (2008)] that
due to increasing and persistent inflation the monetary authority would
focus on the inflation targeting only, leaving aside the output
targeting. (8) So without clear cut objectives of stabilisation with
Fiscal authorities and over borrowing to meet pro-cyclical fiscal
expansion would directly affect the inflation and thereby monetary
authority has to take contractionary stance for keeping inflation at
limits. (9) Which would increase the cost of doing business and thus
create uncertainty for private investors in the economy.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Impact of inertia for Fiscal policy is only for one period, however
for shocks in output gap and inflation have long lasting effects on the
fiscal deficit. Fiscal deficit responds to output gap shocks after one
period and reaches the peak in the same and dies out to zero after 4th
year. Response to inflation shock is the same except that it reaches the
peak in 2nd year and dies out after five years.
Second and third column of Table 1 shows the transmission mechanism
for fiscal policy. Our results show that there is no significant impact
of fiscal policy changes on the economy. As coefficients of fiscal
deficit are insignificant in both the equations of output gap and
inflation. This raises two potential issues; one policy is ineffective
in changing the state of the economy, this could be attributed to the
policy non-coordination (monetary policy is offsetting the possible
impacts of fiscal expansion on out put and inflation thereby raising the
interest rates). Secondly this simple model might be incapable of
capturing the true dynamics of output gap and inflation observed in the
data and we need to specify an elaborate model for identifying the
fiscal transmission mechanism. So before concluding one has to see the
intermediate channels for different macro variables such as consumption,
investment, interest rates, reserve money, modes of debt financing etc.
For instance debt financing from the banking channel might crowd out
private investment through interest rate increase. But on the other hand
if deficit is financed from central bank borrowing that would lead to
reduce interest rate thereby boost economic activity.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
We estimated the impulse response functions for the output gap and
inflation with fiscal shocks. But the results were estimated with larger
standard errors therefore these are insignificant hence fiscal policy is
ineffective as described above as well.
To estimate the response of the fiscal authority over the business
cycle, we estimated the fiscal reaction function with boom and recession
dummies. Our results in Equation 5 suggest that the pro-cyclical
response is significant only in boom periods and the response is
insignificant in recessionary periods. Then we decomposed the fiscal
instruments in tax revenue and Government expenditures as percentage of
GDP. (10) Interestingly both instruments of fiscal policy showed quite
different response. Response of Government expenditures is the opposite
as that of the fiscal deficit, i.e. fiscal authority does take
expansionary a cyclical position in recessions but remains insignificant
in boom periods. Contrarily the tax policy is pro-cyclical in both boom
and recession which is quite opposite to the tax smoothing principle and
automatic stabilisation objective of the fiscal policy.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5) (11)
Adjusted R-Square = 0.297
S.E. of regression = 1.249 D.W. star = 1.242
Here FD is the real value of fiscal deficit as a percentage of real
GDP, GAP is the output gap from potential level of output, D1 is the
dummy for boom and D2 is the dummy for recessionary periods. Finally INF
is the inflation rate measured as the growth rate of GDP deflator. (12)
As policy has responded to lagged variables, there are two other
possibilities of policy reactions, i.e. fiscal authority could respond
to contemporaneous variables or it could be forward looking. Therefore
we have used the GMM estimation technique and the results are reported
in Equation 6 below. (13)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
The fiscal policy does respond to the contemporaneous variables but
it certainly does not have any forward looking policy setting behaviour.
(14)
Finally to complete our discussion, we estimated a near VAR model,
in which different lag length is allowed indifferent equations and
variables with significant effects are included. Estimating the system
of equations as a SUR model we find the same results as already noted
above for fiscal deficit as a fiscal policy instrument.
Fiscal policy is found to be endogenous and pro-cyclical, where as
changes in the policy does not affect any of the targeted variables.
Inflation turns out to be exogenous in the system, as there might be a
need to identify intermediate channels in the fiscal transmission
mechanism.
4. CONCLUSION
Structural developments in public finance leads to effect both the
demand and supply side of the economy in a dynamic manner. Modern
Macroeconomics literature identifies both the short-run (demand
management) and long-run (supply management) objectives of fiscal policy
[Romer (2006)].
We have estimated the fiscal transmission mechanism for Pakistan
for three leading indicators of Fiscal policy i.e. the budget deficit,
government expenditures and tax revenues. We also calculated the fiscal
policy reaction functions and analysed for its endogenity and
contemporaneous responses from other macro variables.
Fiscal policy is identified to be endogenous and pro-cyclical in
boom if fiscal deficit is taken as the fiscal instrument, but it is
insignificant in recessionary phase of the economy. However for
government expenditures, these are anti-cyclical in the recessionary
periods but have insignificant response in booms. Where as the Tax
policy is pro-cyclical for both boom and recessions. In our smaller
macro model for fiscal policy analysis, we could not identify any
transmission mechanism of the fiscal policy for output gap and
inflation. Further Fiscal policy is backward looking and contemporaneous
but not forward looking at all.
However there is a need to see the dynamic effects of shocks in
budgetary components to macro variable while adjusting for the
discretionary and cyclical responses of these components for gauging the
actual transmission mechanism.
APPENDIX
Table 3
Fiscal Reaction Function with Revenues
as Instrument
Dependent
Variable t-values
C 14.98170 34.14221
GAP*D 1 -0.139616 -2.144649
GAP*D2 0.361815 4.691610
INF_GDPD -0.058858 -1.496095
Adjusted R-square 0.412722
S.E. of Regression 1.124334
Table 4
Fiscal Reaction Function with Expenditures
as Instrument
Dependent
Variable t-values
C 9.803441 17.38278
GAP*D 1 -0.043591 -0.520989
GAP*D2 0.207516 2.093614
INF_GDPD 0.037023 0.732197
Adjusted R-square 0.046175
S.E. of Regression 1.445058
Authors' Note: We are thankful for the valuable comments of
our discussant Dr Fazal Hussain. We further acknowledge Muhammad Waheed,
Tasneem Alam, Zahid Asghar, Syed Nisar Hussain Shah, Syed Akhtar Hussain Shah, Ahsan-ul-Haq Satti, and Ghulam Saghir for their helpful comments
during our informal discussions. The paper represents our views and not
those of any organisations where we work.
REFERENCES
Alesina Alberto and Perotti Roberto (1995) The Political Economy of
Budget Deficits. Staff Papers--International Monetary Fund 42:1, 1-31.
Barro Robert J. (1974) Are Government Bonds Net Wealth. The Journal
of Political Economy 82: 6, 1095-1117.
Barro Robert J. (1989) The Ricardian Approach to Budget Deficits.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 3:2, 37-54.
Baxter M. and R. King (1993) Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium.
American Economic Review 83:3, 315-334.
Bernanke, Ben S. and A. S. Blinder (1992) The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission. American Economic Review
82:4, 901-921.
Bernanke, Ben S. and Ilian Mihov (1998) Measuring Monetary Policy.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 113: 3,869-902.
Blanchard Oliver and Roberto Perotti (2002) An Empirical
Characterisation of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government
Spending and Taxes on Output. The Quarterly Journal of Economics
November, 1329-1368.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin S. Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans
(2001) Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary
Policy. (NBER Working Paper No. 8403, July).
Fischer Stanley and William Easterly (1990) The Economics of the
Government Budget Constraint. The World Bank Research Observer 5:2,
127-142.
Gali J., Lopez-Salido D. and J. Valles (2005) Understanding the
Effects of Government Spending on Consumption. (NBER, Working Paper No.
11578).
Giannoni, M. P. and M. Woodford (2003) Optimal Inflation Targeting
Rules. (NBER Working Paper No. 9939).
Leeper, E. M. (1991) Equilibria under Active and Passive Monetary
and Fiscal Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 27:1, 129-147.
Linnemann, L. and A. Schabert (2003) Fiscal Policy in the New
Neoclassical Synthesis. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35: 6,
911-929.
Malik, W. Shahid (2006) Money, Output and Inflation; Evidence from
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 45: 4.
Romer, David (2006) Advanced Macroeconomics. New York: McGraw Hill
Irwin.
Sargent, T. J. (1982) Beyond Supply and Demand Curves in
Macroeconomics. American Economic Review 72:2, 382-389.
Walsh, C. E. (2003) Monetary Theory and Policy. (Second Edition).
Massachusetts: The MIT Press.
Woodford, M. (1998) Doing Without Money: Controlling Inflation in a
Post Monetary World. Review of Economic Dynamics 1,173-219.
Woodford, M. (2001) Fiscal Requirements for Price Stability.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33:3,669-728.
(1) However, in the case of the RBC model, with Ricardian consumers
there could be a negative impact on consumption. While there is a
growing literature which identifies rule-of-thumb consumers, which
mainly are Non-Ricardian and base there decisions on their current wages
then the results could be standard. Similarly MP becomes ineffective in
RBC supply side theories, but fiscal policy is affective through the
investment demand channel and labour supply (with taxes).
(2) However now most studies take [bar.Y] to be equal to [??].
(3) As also seen by some empirical studies that private investments
are complementary to the government durable spending.
(4) In developing economies, going beyond the objective functions
of the society it can also be used to bridge the two gaps of saving
investment and current account balance.
(5) We have used VAR technique following Malik (2006). That study
specifies VAR representation of Pakistan's economy to identify
transmission mechanism of monetary policy.
(6) This assumption is opposite to what is taken by Bernanke and
Blinder (1992); Bernanke and Mihov (1998); Giannoni and Woodford (2003);
Christiano, et al. (2001) among others. However the assumption taken in
these studies is taken for monetary policy.
(7) Estimating output gap as percentage deviation from the
quadratic trend for Pakistan is consistent with Malik (2006).
(8) "Widening of fiscal and external current account
imbalances beyond targeted levels reflect high demand pressures in the
economy, and are aggravating pressure on already high inflation. In the
backdrop of domestic political noise and global developments, it seems
unlikely that these deficits and their financing requirements will come
close to the targets set at the beginning of current fiscal year."
Monetary policy statement for January-June 2008.
(9) "The main message that emerges from all this discussion
is: risks to inflation outweigh the risks to growth in the near future.
To address these risks and confront the emerging challenges, the SBP has
decided to tighten its monetary policy further." Monetary policy
statement for January-June 2008.
(10) Detailed results with the other two instruments are given in
Appendix Tables 3 and 4.
(11) t-values are in parenthesis.
(12) We have also estimated the response function with
Autoregressive terms to remove the autocorrelation from the residual
term but the results did not change significantly.
(13) t-values are in parenthesis.
(14) We also estimated a forward looking fiscal reaction function,
but its results were not significant and not reported in this paper.
Mahmood Khalid <mahmoodkhd@yahoo.com> and Wasim Shahid Malik <wmalik11@yahoo.com> are Research Economists at Pakistan Institute
of Development Economics, Islamabad. Abdul Sattar
<asattar.n@gmail.com> is Research Officer at the Ministry of
Finance, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad.
Table 1
Relationship between Fiscal Deficit, Output Gap, and Inflation
Fiscal Output
Deficit Gap Inflation
Fiscal Deficit (-1) 0.336 0.115 0.032
[2.009] [0.342] [0.052]
Fiscal Deficit (-2) 0.105 -0.106 -0.055
[0.673] [-0.336] [-0.094]
Output Gap (-1) 0.157 1.079 0.067
[1.889] [6.427] [0.215]
Output Gap (-2) -0.097 -0.224 -0.227
[-1.241] [-1.417] [-0.775]
Inflation (-1) 0.090 0.101 0.626
[1.936] [1.078] [3.607]
Inflation (-2) 0.062 -0.162 -0.135
[1.184] [-1.530] [-0.689]
Constant 1.827 0.346 4.526
[1.923] [0.181] [1.272]
Adjusted R-square 0.425 0.781 0.270
Inside the parentheses are t-values
Table 2
Results of Near VAR Model
Fiscal Output
Deficit Gap Inflation
Fiscal Deficit (-1) 0.718
[9.958]
Fiscal Deficit (-2)
Output Gap (-1) 0.084 1.121
[2.228] [8.129]
Output Gap (-2) -0.264
[-2.178]
Inflation (-1) 0.164 0.113 0.909
[3.765] [1.515] [13.358]
Inflation (-2) -0.131
[-1.74]
Adjusted R-square 0.215 0.799 0.170
Inside the parentheses are t-values.