Trade policy, openness, institutions.
Mamoon, Dawood ; Murshed, S. Mansoob
This paper examines the importance of institutions vis-a-vis
openness and trade policies in determining per capita income differences
across countries. Recent literature has tried to demonstrate that more
open economies grow faster. On the other hand, it has also been asserted
that it is not openness per se but institutions and good governance that
matter in promoting growth. This paper attempts to test this hypothesis
across a cross-section of nations. Unlike other papers in the field, we
have tested not only for the degree of openness but also for trade
policy indicators, as well as a fuller set of six institutional
variables. Our broad finding is that although institutions matter, trade
policies are also relevant to promoting growth, whereas openness per se
has little impact on growth.
JEL Classification: F 15; 010.
Keywords: International Integration; Economic Development.
1. INTRODUCTION
In poor low-income nations economic growth constitutes the
principal avenue for poverty reduction. Redistribution, even when
feasible, can never be enough on its own to substantially reduce
poverty. Despite the fact that there may be a close link between growth
and poverty reduction; growth may result not just from policies that
foster it like trade policy reforms, but because certain nations have
superior institutions within which the policy framework is determined
and executed. This also raises the issue of reverse causality. Higher
incomes that are the result of growth in the context of well-functioning
institutions, in turn also produce superior institutions that are a
function of increased per-capita income. By institutions we have in mind
factors that result in good governance: political stability, voice and
accountability, the rule of law, the regulatory framework, bureaucratic
quality and the control of corruption [see Kaufmann, Kraay, and
Zoido-Lobaton (2002) for example]. At present, there is little
controversy over the crucial role played by both international trade as
an engine of growth, and institutional quality in fostering growth in
the longer term [see, Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005) on the
latter point].
With regard to international trade and growth, it has to be
remembered that the quantum of trade can increase or decrease in the
absence of any changes to the trade policy stance (tariffs, non-tariff
barriers, export subsidies etc.). (1) Globalisation and factors that are
external to an individual nation may facilitate trade. Technological
changes and a decline in transportation costs may make certain goods
cheaper despite trade restrictions. Trade may promote growth, but
changes in trade policies may not increase international trade and hence
not contribute to growth or poverty reduction.
The purpose of this paper is to empirically examine the role of
trade policy in explaining differences in per-capita income levels
across countries. We live in an era of globalisation which makes greater
openness imperative. In addition we also analyse the relative
contribution of institutions to prosperity compared to trade
liberalisation. The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2
contains a review of the literature covering the debate regarding the
alternative impact of trade policy or openness on growth, with some
authors establishing a direct link between openness and growth, while
others emphasise the role of good institutions. Sections 3 (data and
methodology) and 4 (regressions) contain our contribution to the debate.
We go well beyond the comparable analysis of Rodrik, et al. (2004) by
including more institutional measures, openness indicators, as well as
trade policy variables. Finally, Section 5 briefly concludes.
2. TRADE POLICY, OPENNESS AND INSTITUTIONS
Apart from the effort required in generating savings leading to
capital accumulation, do the fundamental determinants of growth lie in
policies such as trade policy or human capital accumulation or is growth
fostered by good institutions? In an influential paper, Sachs and Warner
(1995) argued that countries that were more open (based upon a number of
openness indicators) grew faster than countries that were not open.
Rodriguez and Rodrik (2000), however, convincingly demonstrate that the
Sachs and Warner (1995) study suffers from sample selection bias and
that some openness indicators could be highly correlated to other
indicators of good governance or institutional quality. Most damaging of
the Rodriguez and Rodrik (2000) critique of Sachs and Warner's
assertion that openness promotes growth lies in the fact that an Africa
dummy variable capturing the special effect of Africa on cross-national
growth could be substituted for two crucial openness indicators that
contributed significantly to growth. Rodriguez and Rodrik (2000) went on
to review some of the key cross-national empirical literature on the
relationship between trade policy and economic growth and conclude that
there is little evidence that open trade policies, in the sense of lower
tariff and non-tariff barriers to trade, are significantly associated
with economic growth. The theory on this relationship, in the case of a
small economy that takes world prices of tradable goods as given, would
predict that: (1) in static models with no market imperfections and
other pre-existing distortions, the effect of a trade restriction is to
reduce the level of real GDP at world prices. In the presence of market
failures such as externalities, trade restrictions may increase real GDP
(although they are hardly ever the first-best means of doing so); (2) in
standard models with exogenous technological change and diminishing
returns to reproducible factors of production, a trade restriction has
no effect on the long-run (steady-state)
Dollar and Kraay (2002) evaluated the role of institutions and
international trade in economic development. They provide evidence that
countries with better institutions and countries that trade more grow
faster. However, they conclude that it is trade which matters more in
this nexus as a short-term pro-growth strategy. Institutions matter only
in the long-run. But this conclusion is rejected by Rodrik, et al.
(2004), who find that the quality of institutions 'trumps every
thing else'. They conclude that when institutions are controlled
for, the measures of integration have at best insignificant effects on
the level of per-capita income. Similarly, Acemoglu, Johnson, and
Robinson (2005) argue that the most important determinant of long-term
growth is economic institutional functioning, specifically secure
property rights. But there is a potential reverse causality between
per-capita income levels or growth and institutions. For example richer
and more developed countries have better institutions and they are more
liberalised than more underdeveloped nations. So a question can be
raised as to whether rich countries are affluent because they have
superior institutions, or does this relationship work in reverse? There
is also a debate as to whether better institutions encourage trade; or
is it openness and liberalisation which eventually bring about
improvements to institutions? There is some evidence to suggest that
both possibilities exist [see for example: Anderson and Mercuiller
(1999) and Wei (2000)].
Figure 1 below elaborates how the inter-relationship between
growth, institutions and trade works. Any analysis which attempts to
capture the effects of institutions and openness on growth is
potentially loaded with endogeneity problems.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Additionally, not all institutions may matter equally. Democracy
and voice and accountability may not always contribute to growth, as has
been the case in rapidly growing nations such as China and Singapore,
see Barro (1996). There is also the issue of human capital and its place
in fostering growth, and even aiding the formation of superior
institutions. Glaeser, et al. (2004) introduce an important missing link
in the debate by suggesting that human capital is more important for
growth than are institutions. They actually go a step further by
suggesting that human capital actually contributes towards institutional
improvement.
On the importance of human capital vis-a-vis growth, Schiff (1999),
after reviewing recent empirical studies on the subject concludes that
poor countries can only grow faster than rich countries if their initial
stock of human capital exceeds the average level among other poor
nations. For example, when East Asian and South Asian economies are
compared, differences in human capital and differences in convergence
levels seem to move together. For instance, East Asian Developing
countries witnessed unprecedented increases in GNP per capita over the
last three decades: 10 times for Malaysia, 65 times for Republic of
Korea and 13 times for Thailand. During the same period in Asian least
developed countries (Bhutan, Cambodia and Lao People's Democratic
Republic) and South Asian developing countries (Bangladesh, India and
Pakistan) only a meagre increase of 2 to a little over 5 times took
place.
It is interesting to note that in 1960s when most of these
countries were at similar stages of economic development, East Asian
developing countries were far ahead of both Asian least developed
countries and South Asia in human capital endowments. In fact, the total
literacy rates for East Asian developing countries in the 1960s were as
high as 71 percent for the Republic of Korea, 68 percent for Thailand
and even Malaysia had a rate of over 50 percent. On the other hand, in
case of all Asian least developed countries and South Asian developing
countries, the total literacy rates were as low as only 9 percent for
Nepal and 15 percent for Pakistan with Cambodia having 38 percent
literacy. After three decades of development effort, the total literacy
rates are still far below 50 percent in the cases of Bangladesh, Nepal
and Pakistan. Economic progress in East Asia during the 1980s may have
occurred because of policies aimed at augmenting their human capital
endowment, which gathered momentum in the 1960s or earlier.
3. DATA AND METHODOLOGY
In the light of the debate above our equation for per capita income
differences across countries (2) comprises all the core determinants of
growth, namely international economic integration (including measures of
openness and trade policy), institutions and also human capital. We also
include physical capital:
log [y.sub.i] = [alpha] + [beta][N.sub.i] + [chi][TP.sub.i] +
[gamma][HK.sub.i] + [eta][PK.sub.i] + p[epsilon].sub.i] ... ... ... (1)
In many ways, the equation above is an augmented neo-classical
growth model. The variable [y.sub.i] is income per capita in country i,
[N.sub.i], [TP.sub.i], [HK.sub.i], and [PK.sub.i] are respectively
measures for institutions, integration, human capital and physical
capital and [[epsilon].sub.i] is the random error term. Human Capital is
represented by average years of schooling. In order to have an in-depth
insight into how institutions or increased integration affects growth
potential we employ several concepts of institutions and trade
policy/openness variables following various definitions prevalent in the
literature. For example, we take into account the six different
classifications of institutions identified by Kaufman, et al. (2002),
namely rule of law (rl), political stability (ps), regulatory quality
(rq), government effectiveness (ge), voice and accountability (va) and
control of corruption (ctc). (3) On the integration front, we have
carefully chosen three specific measures of openness. For example, ratio
of nominal imports plus exports to GDP (lcopen) is the conventional
openness indicator [see Frankel and Romer (1999); Alcala and Ciccone
(2002); Rose (2002); Dollar and Kraay (2002); Rodrik, et al. (2004)].
Two other measures of openness are overall trade penetration (tarshov)
derived from World Bank's TARS system and overall import
penetration (Impnov) respectively [see Rose (2002)]. Neither of these
measures are direct indicators of trade policy of a country, pointing
only towards the level of its participation in international trade.
There are indicators of trade restrictiveness acting as measures of
trade policy [Edwards (1998); Greenaway, et al. (2001); Rose (2002)].
Import tariffs as percentage of imports (Tariffs), tariffs on
intermediate inputs and capital goods (Owti), and total import charges
(Totimpov) can all be considered as good proxies of trade
restrictiveness and have also been employed in this study. Other
measures which capture restrictions in overall trade are nontariff
barriers. Moreover, there is also a trend in the trade literature to use
composite measures of trade policy. Edwards (1998) advocates the Sachs
and Warner (1995) openness index (open80) and Learner's Openness
indicator (learner 82) as being apposite proxies for openness. We have
also used these composite measures to examine in detail how openness
influences growth rate. In short this study has employed 6 institutional
and 8 openness/trade policy variables in an attempt to undertake a
comprehensive analysis of how institutional quality and exposure to
increased international trade affects the economic performance of a
country.
Note that unlike in the comparable study by Rodrik, et al. (2004)
we have (a) included a role for human capital, (b) employed six
institutional variables compared to one only in Rodrik, et al. (rule of
law), (c) included trade policy variables and not just openness
indicators and (d) expanded the set of openness measures employed.
As indicated earlier, there are potential endogeneity problems
between growth and institutions, as well as between openness (or trade
policy) and growth. One way of cleansing our empirical analysis from
endogeneity in explanatory variables and the reverse causality between
dependent and independent variables is to adopt an Instrumental Variable
(IV) regression analysis. As a first step to run IV regressions we have
to find appropriate instruments for our 8-openness/trade policy
variables and 6 institutional concepts. The first stage estimation
includes instruments for the two explanatory variables with potential
endogeneity problems. The estimate in the next stage utilises the
predicted variables of these variables for institutions and trade
policy/openness in a standard growth regression as in (1).
We follow previous studies, which have not only identified
instruments for openness and institutions, but they have also run
several robustness checks to validate the power of these instruments.
The literature clearly establishes that predicted trade shares following
Frankel and Romer (FR) (1999) from a gravity equation is the most
appropriate instrument for openness/trade policy. On the other hand, the
most compelling institutional instrument has been the measure of settler
mortality suggested by Acemolgu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001). (4) But
the data is only available for 64 countries. Though Rodrik, et al.
(2004) have extended it to 80 countries; it still covers a relatively
low number when compared to another widely used institutional instrument
namely 'fractions of the population speaking English and Western
European languages as the first language' which covers as many as
140 countries. Thus following Dollar and Kraay (2002) and Hall and Jones
(1999), we use this instrument for our institutional proxies. Following
Rodrik, et al. (2004), we employed 'distance from the equator'
as a third instrument (proxy for geography); this is a purely exogenous
concept.
Our IV regression model has two equations, where in the first stage
we generate predicted values of openness/trade policy and institutions
by regressing them on a set of instruments.
Ni = [[lambda].sub.i] + [phi][ENG.sub.i] + v[EUR.sub.i] +
[tau][FR.sub.i] + [theta][GEO.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.Ni] ... ... (2)
[TP.sub.i] = [[pi].sub.i] + [omega][FR.sub.i] + [zeta][ENG.sub.i] +
[rho][EUR.sub.i] + [upsilon][GEO.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.Ni] ... ... (3)
where [ENG.sub.i] and [EUR.sub.i] are our instruments for
institutions referring to fractions of population speaking English and
European languages respectively. [FR.sub.i] is instrument for trade
policy and [GEO.sub.i] is proxy for geography showing distance from the
equator.
At the second stage the predicted values of respective
institutional and openness variables are employed in growth equation
(Equation 1) along with concepts of human capital and physical capital.
4. REGRESSION RESULTS
It would be interesting to ascertain what information our first
stage results give us regarding the quality of instruments. Table 1
suggests that for nearly all specifications of openness and
institutional quality, the respective instruments carry the right signs.
In some cases where the instruments carry wrong signs, they are also
insignificant. Before proceeding to our second stage regressions, we
tried to see how predicted values of our openness and institutional
variables relate to economic growth in a linear framework. It is
interesting to note that the use of instrumental variables provides a
much clearer picture of openness/trade policy and institutions with
regard to economic growth and establishes the robustness of our
instruments.
Moving on to the second stage regression analysis, Table 2a, 2b and
2c (Appendix I) provides the results of growth equation with
combinations of our 3 openness variables with all the institutional
concepts under various specifications. The results are very similar to
the ones obtained by Rodrik, et al. (2004). Institutions clearly
dominate openness because in most cases it is noted that the latter
variable enters into the growth equation with the wrong sign. The
insignificance of our openness proxies capturing the extent of trade or
movements in terms of trade in explaining long term growth rate of a
country comes as no surprise. These findings are in accordance with
Dollar and Kraay (2002) and Rodrik (1998), who suggest that the
correlation of trade levels and growth performance is at best weak in
the long run. Our results reinforce this fact in a more comprehensive
manner, as we have provided additional specifications to the growth
equation by including human capital and physical capital. Especially,
the inclusion of human capital has improved the explanatory power of our
model as it is evident from higher [R.sup.2] values and it has helped to
anchor the influence of institutions in explaining growth.
In Tables 2d, 2e and 2f (Appendix 1), we have regressed various
measurements of tariff and non-tariff barriers along with institutions
under different specifications of Equation 1 Interestingly, we now find
that the superiority of institutions vis-a-vis trade policy has
diminished. In some instances, institutions enter the growth equation
insignificantly. The frequency of such cases increases when human
capital is present in Equation 1. For example, Tables 2d and 2e shows
that rule of law enters into the growth equation with a negative sign
nearly under all specifications. This is an interesting finding in the
light of the Rodrik, et al. (2004) paper, who employed the rule of law
as the one and only proxy for institutions, going on to claim the
superiority of institutions over any other process of growth, as they
find that the rule of law is always significant and carries the right
sign as opposed to their different openness proxies which sometimes
enters with the wrong sign. Though we also find that institutional
superiority is unquestionable in regressions with openness proxies, but
when trade policy variables are introduced the superiority of
institutions diminishes, especially for the rule of law which appears
with the wrong sign in some cases. Additionally, we observe from Table
2d that voice and accountability and control for corruption carry
negative signs under specification 4 of the growth equation when they
are paired with tariffs.
As far as our trade policy variables are concerned, they also can
have wrong signs. But unlike Rodrik, et al. (2004), where in many
instances openness variables carry wrong signs and are also significant,
our trade policy variables which carry wrong signs are generally
insignificant. For example, our proxies for import taxes, tariffs
(import duties as percentage of imports) in 2d and totimpov (overall
weighted average total import charges) in 2f are the trade policy
variables which carry incorrect signs most frequently but are
insignificant under all specifications.
There are many studies which have tried to capture the effects of
trade policy on economic development, i.e., Sachs and Warner (1995),
Edwards (1998) and Greenaway, Morgan, and Wright (2002) are among the
prominent studies which have employed direct proxies of trade policies.
They confirm that the countries with policy-induced barriers to
international trade grow at a slower pace. Notwithstanding the important
role of these studies in giving a useful insight into the 'trade
and growth' debate vis-a-vis trade policy, they have two
shortcomings: first, in the light of recent evidence provided by Rodrik,
et al. (2004) and Dollar and Kraay (2002), their studies are likely to
suffer from a misspecification bias as they have not taken account of
institutions in their growth equations. Secondly, they have assumed
trade policy to be a purely exogenous concept. Wood (2004) points out
that no particular trade policy can be carried out without taking second
best effects into account, as trade policies crucially depend on the
functioning of domestic markets of any particular country.
To this effect we have somewhat addressed the endogeneity of trade
policy variables by regressing them on a set of instruments. Though the
instruments remain very general in nature, they do capture certain
country specific characteristics. And as our dependent variable is
regressed on institutional proxies and human capital along with trade
policy variables, our analysis goes beyond previous cross sectional
studies on the effects of trade policy on economic development.
Table 2g and 2h (Appendix 1) shows the results of composite
measures of openness and measures based on residuals, when they are
regressed with various institutional concepts. Again we find that
institutions, though significant in most instances, are not the most
important factor in determining economic growth as was the case in
Tables 2a, 2b and 2c. By contrast, these results go on to suggest that
trade liberalisation does matter as open80s in 2g (the Sachs-Warner
openness measures) is significant when it enters the equation for
regulatory quality and rule of law, and leamer82 in 2h (Leamer's
measure of trade restrictiveness based on residuals) is highly
significant for regulatory quality.
Here the significance of open80s reinforces the importance of the
trade policy stance, and gives us important insights into the debate.
For example, the variable defines a country as open if (i) non-tariff
barriers cover less than 40 percent of trade, (ii) average tariff rates
are less than 40 percent, (iii) the black market premium was less than
20 percent during the 1980s, (iv) the economy is not socialist, and (v)
the government does not control major exports through marketing boards.
The rationale for combining these indicators into a single dichotomous variable is that they represent different ways in which policy makers
can close their economy to international trade. However, according to the evidence provided by Rodriguez and Rodrik (2000), the Sachs-Warner
composite measure mainly derives its strength from the combination of
black market premium and the state monopoly of exports. The state
monopoly on major exports captures cases where governments tax major
exports and therefore reduce the level of trade (exports and imports),
and the black market premium measures foreign exchange restrictions as a
trade barrier. Although Rodriguez and Rodrik (2000) accept the state
monopoly of exports as an appropriate proxy of trade restrictiveness,
they point out that the black market premia may not be such a good
choice as it is highly correlated with inflation, the debt/export ratio,
wars, institutional quality and may simply capture the effect of
widespread macroeconomic and political crisis. To this effect, our IV
regression analysis may solve the problem of endogeneity of black market
premia as we have regressed open80s with a set of institutional and
openness instruments. This may make both the government monopoly over
major exports and the black market premia robust proxies of trade
restrictiveness.
5. CONCLUSIONS
Institutions, particularly economic institutions such as property
rights and the rule of law are important determinants of long-term
economic development, as emphasised by Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson
(2001, 2005). This was also the view taken by Rodrik, et al. (2004) who
attempted to demonstrate the superiority of one institution (the rule of
law) over the degree of exposure to international trade (openness). It
has to be reiterated that their measure of openness is an outcome
variable, and not a good proxy for the policy stance regarding
international trade. The work of Glaeser, et al. (2004) dampens the
enthusiasm for institutional quality as the ultimate determinant of
economic prosperity by arguing that it is investment in human capital
that is more relevant. After all, many of today's prosperous
nations were once ruled by dictators who may have pursued enlightened
policies in their own interests, leading to economic growth and a demand
for democracy that eventually led to their removal. Other countries,
that are growth failures, were (and are still) ruled, more often than
not by unenlightened dictators. The fact remains that institutional
quality and institutional development is mainly a long term phenomenon,
and may not be amenable to change via short-term policies. This
reservation was expressed by Rodrik, et al. (2004), despite their
finding that institutions rule over integration. More recently, Rodrik
(2006) has distanced himself further from the primacy of institutions,
but his disenchantment is more with lessons learned from cross-country
studies, and the 'one size fits all' type of general policy
advice. Our paper, by adopting a more fully specified form of the
Rodrik, et al. (2004) model, suggests that trade policies do matter and
substantiates the earlier studies regarding the importance of trade
policy in determining economic growth. Trade policies are far less
systematic than other policies, such as those with regard to the
domestic industrial structure (subsidies to state owned enterprises,
say), and less subject to the Rodrik (2005) critique about the
insignificance of the study of rules based policies across a
cross-section of countries.
[TABLE 2a OMITTED]
[TABLE 2b OMITTED]
[TABLE 2c OMITTED]
[TABLE 2d OMITTED]
[TABLE 2e OMITTED]
[TABLE 2f OMITTED]
[TABLE 2g OMITTED]
[TABLE 2h OMITTED]
APPENDIX 2
DATA AND SOURCES
Ctc: Control of Corruption, Year: 1997-98.
Source: Kaufman, et al.
Disteq: Distance from Equator of capital city measured as abs
(Latitude)/90.
Source: Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2002).
Engfrac: Fraction of the population speaking English.
Source: Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2002).
Eurfrac: Fraction of the population speaking one of the major
languages of Western
Europe: English, French, German, Portuguese, or Spanish.
Source: Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2002).
Ge: Government Effectiveness, Year: 1997-98.
Source: Kaufman, et al.
Hk: Average Schooling Years in the total population at 25,Year,
1999.
Source: Barro and Lee,
http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/data.html.
Impnov: Import Penetration Overall, 1985.
Source: Rose (2002).
Lcopen: Natural logarithm of openness. Openness is given by the
ratio of (nominal) imports plus exports to GDP (in nominal US dollars),
Year: 1985.
Source: Penn World Tables, Mark 6.
Leamer82: Learner's Measure of Openness based on Residuals,
Year: 1982.
Source: Rose (2002).
Logfrankrom: Natural logarithm of predicted trade shares computed
following Frankel and Romer (1999) from a bilateral trade equation with
'pure geography' variables.
Source: Frankel and Romer (1999).
LnY: Natural logarithm of Per Capita Income at purchasing Power Prices (PPP), Year: 2000.
Source: World Development Indicators (WDI), 2002.
Open80: Sachs and Warners (1995) composite openness index.
Source: Rose (2002).
Owti: Tariffs on intermediate inputs and Capital Goods, Year: 1985.
Source: Barro and Lee
Pk: Gross Capital Formation as a percentage of GDP, Year: 2000.
Source: World Development Indicators (WDI), 2002.
Ps: Political Stability, Year: 1997/98.
Source: Kaufman et al.
RI: Rule of Law, Year: 1997/98.
Source: Kaufman et al.
Rq: Regulatory Quality, Year: 1997/98.
Source: Kaufman et al.
Tariffs: Import Duties as percentage imports, Year: 1985.
Source: World Development Indicators (WDI), 2002.
Tarshov: TARS trade Penetration Overall, Year: 1985,
Source: Rose (2002).
Totimpov: Weighted Average Total Import Charges, Overall, Year:
1985.
Source: Rose (2002).
Va: Voice and Accountability, Year: 1997/98.
Source: Kaufman et al.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson (2001) The
Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.
American Economic Review 91: 5, 1369-1401.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson (2005)
Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. In Philippe
Aghion and Steven Durlauf (eds) Handbook of Economic Growth l(1).
Amsterdam: Elsevier, 385-472.
Alcala, Francisco, and Antonio Ciccone (2001) Trade and
Productivity. (CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3095.)
Anderson, James E., and D. Marcouiller (1999) Trade, Insecurity,
and Home Bias: An Empirical Investigation. (NBER Working Paper No.
7000).
Davidson, Russel, and James G MacKinnon G. (1993) Estimation and
Inference in Econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press.
Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay (2002) Institutions, Trade and
Growth. Paper prepared for the Carnegie Rochester Conference on Public
Policy.
Edwards, Sebastian (1998) Openness, Productivity and Growth: What
Do We Really Know? The Economic Journal 108, 383-398.
Frankel, Jaffery, and David Romer (1999) Does Trade Cause
Growth'? American Economic Review 89:3, 379-399.
Glaeser, Edward, L., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer
(2004) Explaining Growth: Institutions, Human Capital, and Leaders. (PD:
Preliminary Draft)
http://www.brook.edu/es/commentary/journals/bpea_macro/papers/
20040325_glaeser.pdf
Greenaway, D., W. Morgan, and P. Wright (2001) Trade Liberalisation
and Growth in Developing Countries. Journal of Development Economics 67,
229-224.
Hall, Robert E., and Charles Jones (1999) Why do Some Countries
Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others? Quarterly Journal of
Economics 114, 83-116.
Kaufman, Daniel, Aaart Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton (2002) Governance
Matters If: Updated Indicators for 2000-01. The World Bank (Policy
Research Working Paper 2772.).
http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pdf/govmatters2.pdf
Rodriguez, Francisco, and Dani Rodrik (2000) Trade Policy and
Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.
Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Ben Bernanke and Kenneth Rogoff(eds). MIT Press for NBER.
Rodrik, Dani (1998) Trade Policy and Economic Performance in
Sub-Saharan Africa. (NBER Working Paper 6562.)
Rodrik, Dani (2005) Why We Learn Nothing from Regressing Economic
Growth on Policies, www.ksg.harvard.edu/rodrik.
Rodrik, Dani (2006) Goodbye Washington Consensus: Hello Washington
Confusion, Journal of Economic Perspectives (Forthcoming).
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi (2004)
Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions Over Geography and
Integration in Economic Development. Journal of Economic Growth 9:2,
131-165.
Rose, K., and Andrew (2002) Do WTO Members Have a More Liberal
Trade Policy? (NBER Working Paper No. 9347).
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew Warner (1995) Economic Reform and
Process of Global Integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1,
1-118.
Schiff, Aaron (1999) The Connection between Education and Growth: A
Summary of Recent Cross-Country Empirical Evidence. Unpublished.
http://www.crnec_. auckland. ac.nz/crnec/aaron/edugrow.pdf
Wei, Shang-Jin (2000) Natural Openness and Good Government. (NBER
Working Paper No. W7765).
Wood, Christina (2004) The Empirics of Trade and Growth: Where are
the Policy Recommendations. (Forthcoming) International Economics and
Economic Policy. http://www.ires.ucl.ac.be/DP/IRES_DP/2004-13.pdf
Authors' Note: We are grateful to Andrew K. Rose (UCL,
Berkeley) and Francesco Trebbi (Harvard University) for sharing their
data with us, and Ms Rukhsana (PIDE) and an anonymous referee of this
journal for their valuable comments on earlier drafts.
(1) By trade policy we mean governmentally induced mechanisms that
restrict, relax or facilitate the international exchange of certain or
all goods and services.
(2) We follow the practice in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson
(2001, 2005) and Rodrik, et al. (2004) by looking at per capita income
differences. The differences in average income are a consequence of
varying past growth rates. Rodrik (2006) has pointed out that the
adoption of growth rates may lower the explanatory of institutions.
(3) The value of these variables range from -2.5 (worst) to 2.5
(best) for every country in the sample.
(4) Although more recently it has been criticised by Glaeser, et
al. (2004).
Dawood Mamoon is based at the Institute of Social Studies (ISS),
The Hague, The Netherlands. S. Mansoob Murshed is associated with the
Institute of Social Studies (ISS), The Hague, The Netherlands, The
Birmingham Business School, University of Birmingham, Edgbaston,
Birmingham B15 2TT, UK, and the Centre for the Study of Civil War
(CSCW), PRIO, Oslo, Norway.
Table 1
First Stage Regression Results for Instrumental Variable
First Stage Results
Lcopen Impnov Tarshov
Lfrkrom 0.51 15.9 27.6
(12.7) * (7.5) * (7.2) *
Engfrac 0.37 16.3 25.4
(2.4) * (2.3) * (2.01) *
Eurfrac -0.12 -5.9 -5.5
(-1.2) (-1.6) (-0.6)
Disteq -0.77 0.05 0.1
(-0.1) -0.57 -0.54
F-test 43.9 * 17.4 * 15.8 *
[R.sup.2] 0.55 0.43 0.41
First Stage Results
Tariff Owti Txtrg
Lfrkrom -1.17 -0.07 0.004
(-1.07) (-3.7) * (0.75)
Engfrac -0.98 0.004 0.002
(-0.27) (0.07) (0.12)
Eurfrac -3.7 -0.06 -0.18
(-1.3) (-1.3) (-1.7) ***
Disteq -0.19 -0.002 -0.001
(-3.9) * (-2.3) * (-4.04) *
F-test 5.6 * 6.04 * 5.9 *
[R.sup.2] 0.19 0.21 0.32
First Stage Results
Totimpov Owqi Ntarfov
Lfrkrom -15.3 -0.04 -17.79
(-4.6) * (-1.19) (-3.01) *
Engfrac 11.28 -0.11 17.06
-0.99 (-0.98) (0.84)
Eurfrac -2.18 -0.001 -28.2
(-0.32) (-0.01) (-2.33) *
Disteq 0.18 -0.01 -0.27
-0.93 (-0.71) (-0.77)
F-test 6.1 * 1.04 3.88 *
[R.sup.2] 0.26 0.04 0.18
First Stage Results
Open80s Leamer82 VA
Lfrkrom 0.16 -0.07 0.86
(2.55) * (-0.48) (2.37) *
Engfrac -0.03 0.16 0.65
(-0.16) (0.70) (2.03) *
Eurfrac O.16 -0.15 0.88
(1.22) (-0.95) (4.47) *
Disteq 0.01 0.01 0.02
(4.03) * (3.99) * (7.09)
F-test 7.6 * 4.7 * 26.9 *
[R.sup.2] 0.31 0.31 0.43
First Stage Results
PS GE RQ
Lfrkrom 0.26 0.25 0.097
(2.88) * (3.31) * (1.20)
Engfrac 0.24 0.48 0.286
(0.70) (1.6) (0.88)
Eurfrac 0.64 0.62 0.82
(3.04) * (3.39) * (4.21) *
Disteq 0.02 0.02 0.01
(6.63) * (7.37) * (3.76) *
F-test 17.8 * 24.3 * 11.9 *
[R.sup.2] 0.35 0.42 0.25
First Stage Results
RL CTC
Lfrkrom 0.27 0.27
(3.42) * (3.53) *
Engfrac 0.502 0.73
(1.54) (2.43) *
Eurfrac 0.51 0.49
(2.63) * (2.73) *
Disteq 0.03 0.029
(8.14) * (8.08) *
F-test 25.2 * 28.2 *
[R.sup.2] 0.42 0.45
t-values in the parenthesis. *, **, *** Denotes significance at
1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent levels respectively.