Inflation in Pakistan.
Khan, Mohsin S. ; Schimmelpfennig, Axel
This paper examines the factors that explain and help forecast
inflation in Pakistan. A simple inflation model is specified that
includes standard monetary variables (money supply, credit to the
private sector), an activity variable, the interest and the exchange
rates, as well as the wheat support price as a supply-side factor. The
model is estimated for the period January 1998 to June 2005 on a monthly
basis. The results indicate that monetary factors have played a dominant
role in recent inflation, affecting inflation with a lag of about one
year. Private sector credit growth and broad money growth are also good
leading indicators of inflation which can be used to forecast future
inflation developments.
JEL classification: E31, C22, C32
Keywords: Inflation, Pakistan, Leading Indicators, Forecasting,
Monetary Policy
I. INTRODUCTION
After remaining relatively low for quite a long time, the inflation
rate accelerated in Pakistan starting in late 2003. Following the
1998-99 crisis, inflation was reduced to below 5 percent by 2000 and
remained stable through 2003. Tight monetary policy combined with fiscal
consolidation appears to have contributed to this low-inflation
environment. (1) Figure 1 shows that inflation follows broad money
growth and private sector credit growth closely with a lag of about 12
months. With monetary growth picking up, inflation followed and
increased sharply in late 2003, peaking at 11 percent year-on-year in
April 2005. Average annual inflation stabilised around 8 to 9 percent by
September 2005, and has receded somewhat since then.
Controlling inflation is a high priority for policy-makers. High
and persistent inflation is a regressive tax and adversely impacts the
poor and economic development. The poor have little options to protect
themselves against inflation. They hold few real assets or equity, and
their savings are typically in the form of cash or low-interest bearing
deposits. Thus, this group is most vulnerable to inflation as it erodes
its savings. Moreover, high and volatile inflation has been found to be
detrimental to growth [e.g., Khan and Senhadji (2001)] and financial
sector development [e.g., Khan, Senhadji, and Smith (2006)]. High
inflation obscures the role of relative price changes and thus inhibits
optimal resource allocation.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Understanding the factors that drive inflation is fundamental to
designing monetary policy. Certainly in the long run, inflation is
considered to be--as Friedman (1963) stated--always and everywhere a
monetary phenomenon. Workhorse models of inflation typically include
monetary variables, such as money growth, real GDP, the interest rate,
and the exchange rate as explanatory variables. Some authors have also
pointed to supply side developments in explaining inflation. This
structuralist school of thought holds that supply constraints that drive
up prices of specific goods can have wider repercussions on the overall
price level. For example, in Pakistan, increases in the wheat support
price have frequently been blamed for inflation. (2)
This paper finds that monetary factors are the main drivers of
inflation in Pakistan, while other typical explanatory variables play
less of a role. We specify a simple inflation model that includes
standard monetary variables (money supply and credit to the private
sector), the interest rate, the exchange rate, an activity variable, as
well as the wheat support price as a supply-side factor. The model is
estimated with monthly data for the period January 1998 to June 2005.
The results indicate that monetary factors have played a dominant role
in recent inflation, affecting inflation with a lag of about one year.
Monetary factors are also well-suited to forecast inflation in a
leading-indicator type model.
The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section II
reviews the relevant literature and introduces a stylised model to
structure the analysis. Section Ill estimates the model and assesses the
roles for explaining inflation played by monetary factors and other
variables. Section IV presents a leading indicators model to forecast
inflation, and Section V provides some conclusions.
II. BASIC ELEMENTS OF THE MODEL
Several studies highlight the role of monetary factors for
inflation in Pakistan. (3) For example, Khan and Qasim (1996) find that
overall inflation is only determined by money supply, import prices, and
real GDP. The empirical evidence is inconclusive regarding the role of
the exchange rate. Choudhri and Khan (2002) do not find evidence of
exchange rate pass-through in a small VAR analysis, while Hyder and Shah
(2004) find some evidence of exchange rate pass-through using a larger
VAR. Some authors have emphasised structuralist factors in explaining
inflation in Pakistan. (4) Khan and Qasim (1996) find food inflation to
be driven by money supply, value-added in manufacturing, and the wheat
support price. (5) Non-food inflation is determined by money supply,
real GDP, import prices, and electricity prices. Sherani (2005),
referring to this work, finds that increases in the wheat support price
raise the CPI index (but not necessarily inflation). He also argues that
the high levels of inflation in 2005 largely resulted from a monetary
overhang that was built up by loose monetary conditions.
We start our stylised model from a monetarist perspective. Agents
hold money for transaction purposes, as a store of value, and for
speculative purposes. For a constant velocity (v), inflation ([??])
results if money growth ([??]) exceeds real GDP growth ([??]). The
opportunity cost of holding money, that is the interest rate r, reduces
money demand and thus inflation. Moreover, financial deepening and
innovations enable agents to use alternative monetary instruments in
lieu of cash. Thus, the velocity of a particular monetary aggregate, say
M2, changes if agents switch from cash or demand deposits to instruments
included only in M3. In an open economy, headline inflation can also be
affected by movements of the exchange rate (e). (6) We also allow for
the wheat support price (w) as a structuralist factor to drive
inflation. The general open-economy monetary model (incorporating a
supply-side variable) is then given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
where lower case letters denote the natural logarithm of a variable
and a dot over a variable denotes the first derivative with respect to
time.
For non-stationary time series, Equation (1) only reflects
short-run relationships as the variables are in (log) first differences,
and the equation does not include a cointegrating relationship. However,
the aspects of the model that reflect monetarist thinking will tend to
be long-run relationships, and the model can be easily be rewritten in
levels and in an error correction representation to differentiate
between short-run and long-run relationships.
III. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
We estimate the basic model in growth rates as well as in log
levels. Since our sample extends over a crisis period and subsequent
wide ranging economic reforms as well as a growth take-off, it may be
difficult to discern long-run relationships from the data due to
structural changes and non-constant parameters. However, we would still
expect short-run relationships to reflect our proposed model structure.
Therefore, as a first step, we estimate Equation (1) to gain an
understanding of some basic relationships and short-run dynamics. (7) In
the second step, we estimate the model as a vector error correction
model (VECM) in log-levels to investigate whether we can find a
cointegrating vector that would provide information about long-run
behaviour.
(a) Data and Sample
Our database covers the period January 1998 to June 2005 on a
monthly basis. The choice of sample reflects a trade-off between having
sufficient observations and avoiding structural breaks that would
complicate the empirical analysis. Banking sector reforms were initiated
in 1997 and pursued vigorously after 1999, leading to increased
intermediation. Financial deepening also occurred as confidence returned
in the aftermath of the 1998-99 crisis and with the new government
restoring macroeconomic stability. Taken together, this implies that the
monetary transmission mechanism has evolved and money demand has
possibly shifted over the sample period which may lead to nonconstant
parameters, in particular with respect to long-run parameters.
The definitions of the data utilised are:
* CPI: overall consumer price index--the percentage change of which
is also termed "headline inflation".
* Monetary variables: Broad money; private sector credit; and the
6-month treasury bill (T-bill) rate (the SBP's key policy rate).
* Activity variables: interpolated real and nominal GDP (12-month
moving average of the fiscal year GDP data); (8) and the large scale
manufacturing index (LSM).
* Exchange rate: nominal effective exchange rate (NEER).
* Wheat support price: guaranteed minimum government purchase
price.
The basic correlations between the variables are shown in Table 1.
The log levels of all variables are non-stationary. Most variables
are integrated of order one (Table 2). However, somewhat surprisingly,
our interpolated real and nominal GDP series are integrated of order
two. This would suggest that our GDP series cannot be part of a long-run
cointegrating relationship with other variables that are only integrated
of order one. Alternatively, the LSM may be a meaningful proxy for the
activity variable. (9)
Data for Pakistan is subject to overlapping seasonality stemming
from Gregorian calendar effects (including agricultural seasonality) and
Islamic calendar effects. Riazuddin and Khan (2005) construct variables
to address Islamic seasonality. For regressions based on growth rates,
we control for seasonality by using 12-month moving averages. In Bokil
and Schimmelpfennig (2005), we show that this is sufficient to take
account of both sources of seasonality. The approach has the advantage
of requiring no additional regressors. However, for regressions based on
log levels, we include monthly dummies and the Islamic calendar control
variables used in Riazuddin and Khan (2005). (10)
(b) CPI Inflation
We first analyse the impact of changes in the explanatory variables
on headline inflation. We estimate two variants of our stylised model
using either broad money or private sector credit to capture the impact
of monetary policy. The models are estimated using the PcGets routine in
PcGive which automatically tests down a general model. (11) In our case,
we include 12 lags of all variables in the general model. In principle,
the resulting specific model can then include individual lags of the
variables from the general model, or exclude variables altogether.
We focus on summary coefficients that give the direction of
influence of a particular regressor after all dynamics have played out.
The estimated specification is an autoregressive distributed lag model
(ADL) that can be written as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
where x is the vector of independent variables. A(L) and B(L) are
lag polynomials that take the form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The ADL can be re-written as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
The coefficient [beta] that describes the impact of changes in the
independent variables on inflation after all dynamics have played out is
then given by:
[beta] = B(1)/A(1). ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (4)
The empirical results are broadly consistent with our stylised
model. Models M1 and M2 in Table 3 are based on the general
specification in Equation (1). In M1, we use broad money, and in M2, we
use private sector credit to measure monetary policy. In both cases, no
regressor is completely dropped from the model. PcGets only eliminates
some individual lags. However, in M1, the T-bill rate, and in M2, the
NEER, the T-bill rate, and the wheat support price carry the wrong sign.
We therefore drop these regressors (except for the wheat support price)
to arrive at our two preferred specifications M3 and M4. M3 explains CPI
inflation as a function of broad money growth, real GDP growth, NEER
appreciation, and the average annual wheat support price change. M4
explains CPI inflation as a function of private sector credit growth,
real GDP growth, and the average annual wheat support price change.
These results illustrate that monetary factors are determinants of
inflation, at least in the short run. Likewise, real GDP growth and the
wheat support price matter, and to some extent, there is an impact from
NEER appreciation. Monetary growth affects inflation with a lag of
around 12 months. (12)
(c) A Vector-Error Correction Model
Based on the above results, we specify a VECM to identify long-run
relationships between our variables. To limit the size of the VECM, we
start with the preferred specifications M3 for a VECM including broad
money and M4 for a VECM including private sector credit. We find that a
meaningful cointegrating relationships exists only in the case of a VECM
including private sector credit.
CPI, Private Sector Credit, and Wheat Support Price VECM
The preferred VECM contains the CPI, private sector credit, and the
wheat support price. We estimate the system with monthly dummies and
Islamic calendar effect controls used in Riazuddin and Khan (2005). (13)
Based on the stylised model and the results for the inflation equation
above, we initially estimate a system including the CPI (cpi), private
sector credit (credit), real GDP, and the wheat support price (wheat).
However, no meaningful cointegrating relationship is found in this
system, and we estimate a reduced system without real GDP. (14) This
reduced system has a cointegrating rank of one (Table 5). The
cointegrating vector is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
The t-statistics in parentheses suggest that the wheat support
price is not part of the long-run relationship. We can also drop the
seasonal controls, without affecting the white-noise characteristics of
the residuals, which gives us additional degrees of freedom. This
yields:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
Based on these results, the CPI is affected only by private sector
credit in the long-run. The estimated cointegrating vector describes
recent inflation developments well. Starting in early 2003, monetary
conditions were very accommodating, private sector credit growth picked
up, and a disequilibrium in the CPI-private sector credit relationship
emerged (Figure 2). As inflation picked up as well, the disequilibrium
has been reduced, but not yet been eliminated through June 2005. The
loading coefficient in the equation for the CPI indicates that 23
percent of a deviation from the long-run relationship is adjusted in the
next period.
The CPI increases after shocks in the private sector credit
equation. We calculate an impulse response function based on generalised 1-standard deviation impulses [Pesaran and Shin (1998)]. In response to
an innovation in private sector credit, the CPI initially falls (akin to
the price puzzle), but after 4 months steadily increases (Figure 3).
(15)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
CPI, Broad Money, and Wheat Support Price
No meaningful VECM that contains broad money could be identified in
the sample. Based on the stylised model and the findings in the
inflation regressions above, we started with a system including the CPI,
broad money, NEER, real GDP, and the wheat support price. (16) The
system also included controls for Gregorian and Islamic calendar effects
and in some specifications deterministic components. We set the lag
length to 6 to maintain sufficient degrees of freedom; the optimum lag
length for this system is 12, but our sample is not large enough to
allow this number of parameters (Table 4). We experimented with
different specifications for the deterministic component, and dropped or
retained any of the endogenous variables. Nonetheless, no cointegrating
relationship emerged that would be broadly consistent with our model or
would yield sensible impulse response functions.
The failure to find cointegration most likely stems from ongoing
changes to fundamental relationships, in particular money demand, during
the sample. As we show in Bokil and Schimmelpfennig (2005), a money
demand equation for Pakistan suffers from nonconstant coefficients when
estimated with either annual or monthly data. For annual data, recursive coefficient estimates diverge significantly after 1998 from the
coefficient estimated in the 1978-2004 sample. With monthly data, the
recursive coefficients fluctuate throughout the 1995-2004 sample, in the
case of real GDP even switching signs. These findings are likely to
reflect the impact of the 1998-99 debt crisis on the Pakistani economy
and the reforms that followed. Macroeconomic stabilisation and financial
sector reforms, can be expected to have affected estimated parameters.
Moreover, De Grauwe and Polan (2005) show that standard quantity theory
of money relationships are hard to identify in countries with inflation
of less than 10 percent.
IV. FORECASTING INFLATIONARY TRENDS
Inflation forecasts are an important input into monetary policy
formation. Given typical time lags, monetary policy needs to be
concerned with future inflation. Current inflation levels, which are
themselves the result of past policies, may provide only insufficient
information. Inflation forecasts that link future inflation to current
developments can bridge this gap. Some central banks have even adopted
an inflation forecast target. However, this assumes that inflation
forecasts are very reliable. Still, even in situations where structural
relationships are less stable and data quality is evolving, quantitative
inflation forecasts can provide useful information on future
developments, though this needs to be combined with additional analysis
going beyond econometric relationships. Leading indicators can be used
to generate forecasts, in particular in situations where time series are
short and structural relationships are not stable enough to allow for an
economic model-based inflation forecast.
The leading indicators approach searches for variables that co-move
with the variable to be forecasted without imposing a model structure.
Leading indicators do not necessarily need to be causal factors of the
target variable as part of an economic model, though this would
presumably strengthen one's confidence in a forecasting model
[e.g., Marcellino (2004) and Stock and Watson (1989, 1999)]. We again
use the general-to-specific algorithm in PcGets to narrow down the set
of possible leading indicators from our full dataset. In addition, we
look at information criteria, root mean square error and similar
statistics to optimise the forecast accuracy and arrive at a final
specification. We require indicators to lead inflation by at least 6
months and allow for leads of up to 12 months.
Private sector credit growth and broad money growth are leading
indicators of inflation (Table 6). We extend the list of possible
variables beyond that of our stylised model above to also include
variables which have proven to be good leading indicators in other
countries. The general model, thus, contains the following variables
that could be leading indicators for inflation: wholesale-price index
inflation, time-varying intercept, and slope coefficient for the yield
curve, the spread between 12-month and 3-month T-bill rates, large-scale
manufacturing index growth, broad money growth, reserve money growth,
private sector credit growth, change in the nominal effective exchange
rate, tax revenue growth, and the 6-month T-bill rate. Of these, only
private sector credit growth and lags of inflation remain in the reduced
specification (M5). (17) We also show specifications that include broad
money growth as one might expect a relationship between broad money
growth and inflation. The best specification here is M7 which includes
lags of broad money growth and private sector credit growth in addition
to lags of inflation. Both specifications are consistent with a monetary
transmission mechanism that works through the credit channel, and also
reflect the findings for our stylised model.
The LIMs exhibits a good ex-post forecast quality. Re-estimating
the LIMs through May 2004 and forecasting the remainder of 2004 allows a
comparison of the models' forecast with actual developments (Figure
4). The ex-post forecast based on M5 (private sector credit growth)
seems a bit closer to actual developments than the ex-post forecast
based on M7 (private sector credit growth and broad money growth).
However, the ex-post forecast based on M7 has a lower standard error.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The LIMs yield a fairly accurate forecast, and are consistent with
our stylised model. By construction, the approach picks leading
indicators that yield a high forecast accuracy at the current juncture.
And, higher broad money growth and higher private sector credit growth
being associated with higher inflation seems plausible from an economic
point of view. However, the choice of leading indicators may change over
time, so that the forecasting model may not be stable. As such, periodic
re-specification and re-estimating will be required.
V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The empirical results presented in this paper show that monetary
factors determine inflation in Pakistan, and are good leading indicators
for future inflation. Broad money growth and private sector credit
growth are the key variables that explain inflation developments with a
lag of around 12 months. A long-run relationship exists between the CPI
and private sector credit.
Pakistan's growth record since the 1970s underscores that high
and persistent inflation is harmful to growth. Periods of high inflation
have coincided with low growth spells, while high growth episodes tend
to be associated with a low inflation environment. Between 1978 and
1991, inflation was 8 percent on average and real per capita growth
averaged 3 percent. Between 1992 and 1997, inflation increased on
average to I I percent, while real per capita growth fell substantially
and averaged only I percent. Finally, between 1998 and 2003, inflation
was reduced again to an average of 5 percent, and real per capita growth
displayed a dramatic recovery. Of course, there are other factors that
determine growth in the short run and in the long run [e.g., van Rooden
(2005)]. Nonetheless, in light of Pakistan's growth performance and
the empirical thresholds beyond which inflation harms growth and
financial development, an appropriate inflation target for Pakistan is 5
percent. The S BP's inflation target of 5 percent is, therefore,
appropriate. (18)
The overarching objective of the SBP should be price stability. We
believe the SBP should first and foremost focus its attention and
policies to keep inflation close to its target of 5 percent. In
principle, the SBP could also target an exchange rate level as a nominal
anchor to achieve macroeconomic stability. However, this implies
adopting the anchor country's monetary policy and may yield a
suboptimal rate of inflation. In addition, the exchange rate would no
longer be available to offset the impact of external shocks on the
domestic economy. The SBP is fully capable of implementing its own
independent monetary policy consistent with the needs of the domestic
economy. Maintaining price stability will ultimately be the best policy
contribution to sustained growth that the SBP can make. While there may
not be a trade-off between inflation and growth in the short run, it
certainly exists in the medium- and long-run.
Price stability can be approximated by different metrics. While
headline inflation is better understood by the public, it is often
argued that monetary policy should be more concerned with core
inflation. Given the volatility of some components of the CPI, in
particular food prices and energy prices, core inflation (approximated
as non-food, non-energy or the SBP's trimmed mean definition) is a
better measure of underlying inflation trends than headline inflation.
Nonetheless, headline inflation is better understood by the public and
affects households immediately. Taken together, core inflation is the
right target for monetary policy, in particular over the medium term,
but the SBP also needs to keep a watchful eye on headline inflation.
Finally, monetary policy has to be forward-looking to achieve its
inflation target. Current monetary conditions impact inflation with a
lag of around 12 months in Pakistan. There seems to be a fairly stable
relationship between private sector credit growth and inflation 12
months from now. In addition, there is also a relationship between broad
money growth and inflation 12 months from now. Therefore, the SBP should
set monetary policy today with a view to meeting its inflation target
around one year from now.
Author's Note: The views expressed in this paper are those of
the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the International
Monetary Fund or its policy. This paper draws on previous work by Khan
and Schimmelpfennig, "Inflation in Pakistan: Money or Wheat?",
published in the State Bank of Pakistan's Research Bulletin--Papers
and Proceedings Vol. 2, No. 1, available at
http://www.sbp.org.pk/research/bulletin/2006/ Inflation_in_Pakistan
Money_or_Wheat.pdf, and in Bokil and Schimmelpfennig "Three
Attempts at Inflation Forecasting," available as IMF Working Paper
05/105 at http://www.imf.org/ external/pubs/ft/wp/2005/wp05105.pdf.
REFERENCES
Balke, Nathan, and Kenneth Emery (1994) Understanding the Price
Puzzle. Economic and Financial Policy Review (Fourth Quarter). Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Bernanke, Ben S. (2005) Inflation in Latin America--A New Era?
Remarks at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Economic
Summit, February 11. Available via the Internet at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/20050211/
default.htm.
Bokil, Madhavi, and Axel Schimmelpfennig (2005) Three Attempts at
Inflation Forecasting in Pakistan. International Monetary Fund Working
Paper 05/105. Available via the Internet at:
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2005/wp05105.pdf.
Brissmiss, Sophocles, and Nicholas Magginas (2004) Forward-Looking
Information in VAR Models and the Price Puzzle. (February). (Bank of
Greece Working Paper No. 10.)
Choudhri, Ehsan U., and Mohsin S. Khan (2002) The Exchange Rate and
Consumer Prices in Pakistan: Is Rupee Devaluation Inflationary? The
Pakistan Development Review 41:2, 107-20.
De Grauwe, Paul, and Magdalena Polan (2005) Is Inflation Always and
Everywhere a Monetary Phenomenon? In Scandinavian Journal of Economics
107:2, 239-59.
Friedman, Milton (1963) Inflation: Causes and Consequences. New
York: Asia Publishing House.
Hendry, David F., and Hans-Martin Krolzig (2004) We Ran One
Regression. Oxford: Oxford University. Available via the Internet at
http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/economics/ papers/2004/w17/OneReg.pdf.
Hyder, Zulfiqar, and Sardar Shah (2004) Exchange Rate Pass-Through
to Domestic Prices in Pakistan. (State Bank of Pakistan Working Papers No. 5.) Available via the Internet at:
http://www.sbp.org.pk/publications/wpapers/wp05.pdf.
Khan, Ashfaque H., and Mohammad Ali Qasim (1996) Inflation in
Pakistan Revisited. In The Pakistan Development Review 35:4, 747-59.
Khan, Mohsin S., and Abdelhak S. Senhadji (2001) Threshold Effects
in the Relationship between Inflation and Growth. IMF Staff Papers 48:1,
1-21.
Khan, Mohsin S., Abdelhak S. Senhadji, and Bruce D. Smith (2006)
Inflation and Financial Depth. In Macroeconomic Dynamics 10:2, 165-82.
MacKinnon, James G. (1996) Numerical Distribution Functions for
United Root and Cointegration Tests. Journal of Applied Econometrics 11:6, 601-18.
MacKinnon, James G., Alfred A. Haug, and Leo Michelis (1999)
Numerical Distribution Functions of Likelihood Ratio Tests for
Cointegration. Journal of Applied Econometrics 14:5, 563-77.
Marcellino, Massimiliano (2004) Leading Indicators: What Have We
learned. In G. Elliot, C. W. J. Granger, and A. Timmermann (eds.)
Handbook of Economic Forecasting. North Holland: Elsevier.
Pesaran, Hashem M., and Yongcheoi Shin (1998) Generalised Impulse
Response Analysis in Linear Multivariate Models. Economic Letters 58:1,
17-29.
Riazuddin, Riaz, and Mahmood-ul-Hasan Khan (2005) Detection and
Forecasting of Islamic Calendar Effects in Time Series Data.
SBP-Research Bulletin 1:1, 25-34.
Sherani, Sakib (2005) The Dark Side of the Force. ABN-AMRO,
Economic Focus--Pakistan. Monday, May 30.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson (1989) New Indexes of
Coincident and Leading Economic Indicators. In Olivier Jean Blanchard
and Stanley Fischer (eds.) NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, pp. 351-394.
Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson (1999) Forecasting Inflation.
Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 293-335.
van Rooden, Ron (2005) is Pakistan's Growth Acceleration
Sustainable? international Monetary Fund. Pakistan-Selected Issues and
Statistical Appendix. IMF Country Report No. 05/408 Available via the
Internet at: http://www.imf.org/external/country/PAK/index.htm.
(1) According to the State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) a change in the
methodology of deriving the house rent index may also be partly
responsible for the observed slowdown in headline inflation.
(2) The acceleration of inflation in late 2003 coincided with two
increases in the wheat support price in September 2003 and in September
2004, which has re-opened the debate whether the wheat support price was
driving inflation in Pakistan [Khan and Qasim (1996) and Sherani
(2005)].
(3) For a comprehensive survey of empirical studies on Pakistan
[see Bokil and Schimmelpfennig (2005)].
(4) Structuralist models of inflation emphasise supply-side factors
as determinants of inflation. They emerged in the 1950s as part of the
structuralist theories of development promoted by Prebisch [see Bernanke
(2005)]. In these models, inflation is driven by developments and
bottlenecks on the real side of the economy. Food prices, administered
prices, wages, and import prices are considered sources of inflation.
Structuralist models assume that such factors have to be accommodated by
monetary policy-makers because they are determined outside the monetary
sphere. Monetary developments in themselves are given little importance
as independent determinants of inflation.
(5) It is hardly surprising that changes in the wheat support price
affect the food price index, given that wheat products account for 14
percent of the index. However, this does not automatically imply that
headline inflation is affected by changes in the price of one particular
item.
(6) Import prices could also play a role, in particular if the
exchange rate is pegged. Unfortunately, import prices are not available
at a monthly frequency, but since Pakistan had a flexible exchange rate
regime during our sample period, import prices should be less important
than in previous years.
(7) Note that this model may be mis-specified if we have
non-stationary data and there exists a cointegrating vector.
(8) GDP data is available only at annual frequency.
(9) The correlation coefficient between the annual LSM index and
annual real GDP is 0.97 which suggests that a 12-month moving average of
the LSM index is probably a reasonable proxy for monthly real GDP.
(10) We thank R. Riazuddin and M. Khan for kindly providing their
data to us. In some specifications, the control variables for calendar
effects can be dropped.
(11) The routine is described and illustrated in Hendry and Krolzig
(2004).
(12) M3 includes a 7 and a 11 month lag of broad money growth M4
includes a 1, 3, 5, 10, and 12 month lag for private sector credit
growth.
(13) The lag length is set at 6. Table 4 shows information criteria
for different specifications and lag lengths.
(14) This finding could reflect that real GDP may be integrated of
order two while all other variables are integrated of order one.
However, using the LSM instead of real GDP does not alter the result.
(15) The price puzzle is a fairly common empirical finding where an
unexpected tightening of monetary policy initially leads to an increase
rather than a decrease in the price level. This theoretical
inconsistency can be addressed by introducing forward-looking variables
[e.g., Brissimiss and Magginas (2004), and Balke and Ernery (1994)].
(16) Alternatively, we used the LSM instead of real GDP, but this
did not change the results.
(17) Detailed results are available from the authors upon request.
(18) Annual inflation targets can vary depending on where inflation
stands at the beginning.
Mohsin Khan <mkhan@imf.org> is Director of the Middle East
and Central Asia Department of the International Monetary Fund. Axel
Schimmelpfennig <aschimmelpfennig@imf.org> is an Economist in the
International Monetary Fund's Middle East and Central Asia
Department.
Table 1
Pakistan: Correlation between Main Variables in Log Levels
(Sample: January 1998 to June 2005)
Private
Broad Sector Real
CPI Money Credit GDP
CPI 1.00 0.98 0.97 0.99
Broad Money 0.98 1.00 0.97 0.99
Private Sector Credit 0.97 0.97 1.00 0.98
Real GDP 0.99 0.99 0.98 1.00
LSM Index 0.96 0.98 0.98 0.98
6-month t-bill -0.67 -0.76 -0.65 -0.73
NEER -0.95 -0.91 -0.91 -0.94
Wheat Support Price 0.94 0.89 0.92 0.93
Wheat
LSM 6-month Support
Index t-bill NEER Price
CPI 0.96 -0.67 -0.95 0.94
Broad Money 0.98 -0.76 -0.91 0.89
Private Sector Credit 0.98 -0.65 -0.91 0.92
Real GDP 0.98 -0.73 -0.94 0.93
LSM Index 1.00 -0.67 -0.90 0.89
6-month t-bill -0.67 1.00 0.67 -0.60
NEER -0.90 0.67 1.00 -0.88
Wheat Support Price 0.89 -0.60 -0.88 1.00
Source: National authorities, IMF staff calculations.
Table 2
Pakistan: Test for Non-stationarity of Variables of Log-levels
(Sample: January 1998 to June 2005)
Log First Second Critical
Level Difference Difference Value 1/
Phillips Perron Test 2/
CPI 1.03 -8.00 -2.89
Broad Money 5.95 -9.21 -2.89
Private Sector
Credit 1.96 -6.26 -2.89
6-month t-bill -1.43 -6.32 -2.89
Real GDP 5.45 -0.84 -9.49 -2.89
LSM Index 4.63 -5.49 -2.89
NEER -1.57 -7.56 -2.89
Wheat Support Price -0.61 -9.59 -2.89
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test /2
CPI 1.13 -7.98 -2.89
Non-food
Broad Money 2.90 -1.84 -8.40 -2.89
Private Sector
Credit 1.51 -6.25 -2.89
6-month t-bill -1.90 -2.83 -12.12 -2.89
Real GDP 1.56 -0.85 -9.49 -2.89
LSM Index 2.87 -5.47 -2.89
NEER -1.53 -7.58 -2.89
Wheat Support Price -0.64 -9.59 -2.89
Source: National authorities, IMF staff calculations.
1/ Critical value at the 5 percent level based on MacKinnon (1996).
2/ Model includes intercept.
Table 3
Pakistan: Inflation Determinants--General-to-specific Modeling 1/
(Dependent Variable: Average Annual CPI Inflation in Percent;
Sample January 1998 to June 2005)
M1 M2 M3 M4
Broad Money 2/ 3.87 1.46
Private Sector Credit 2/ 0.65 0.28
Real GDP 2/ -4.52 -1.15 -2.32 -1.67
NEER 2/ -1.81 0.54 -0.50
6-month t-bill 3/ 0.06 0.01
Wheat Support Price 2/ 0.69 -0.17 0.21 0.26
Adjusted R^2 0.999 1.000 0.999 0.999
Degree of Freedom 60 35 54 58
Observations 78 78 78 78
Regressors 18 43 24 20
Source: Pakistani authorities and IMF data; own calculations.
1/ General-to-specific modeling based on the PcGets algorithm. Columns
show the coefficient [beta] that describes the joint impact of all
lags of the respective regressor: the individual lags are not shown,
but are mostly significant at the 5 percent level.
2/ Average annual change in percent.
3/ Absolute change over the last 12 months in basis points.
Table 4
Pakistan: Information Criteria to Determine Optimal Lag Length k
of VAR 1/ (Endogenous Variables: CPI, Private Sector Credit, Real
GDP, Wheat Support Price all in Log Levels)
k=2 k=3 k=4 k=5
(Endogenous variables: CPI, private
sector credit, real GDP, wheat
support price all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -30.358 -30.211 -30.238 -30.041
Schwarz Criterion -27.655 -27.036 -26.585 -25.903
(Endogenous variables: CPI, private
sector credit, wheat support price
all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -17.539 -17.511 -17.446 -17.289
Schwarz Criterion -15.681 -15.385 -15.049 -14.617
(Endogenous variables: CPI, broad money,
real GDP, NEER, wheat support
price all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -35.808 -35.645 -35.77 -35.646
Schwarz Criterion -32.148 -31.251 -30.633 -29.755
k=6 k=7 k=8 k=9
(Endogenous variables: CPI, private
sector credit, real GDP, wheat
support price all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -30.113 -30.154 -29.995 -30.268
Schwarz Criterion -25.483 -25.024 -24.359 -24.119
(Endogenous variables: CPI, private
sector credit, wheat support price
all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -17.22 -17.193 -17.036 -17.008
Schwarz Criterion -14.268 -13.958 -13.514 -13.195
(Endogenous variables: CPI, broad money,
real GDP, NEER, wheat support
price all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion 36.210 -36.184 -36.313 -36.489
Schwarz Criterion -29.554 -28.752 -28.095 -27.473
k=10 k=11 k=12
(Endogenous variables: CPI, private
sector credit, real GDP, wheat
support price all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -30.675 -31.198 -32.411
Schwarz Criterion -24.005 -24.000 -24.676
(Endogenous variables: CPI, private
sector credit, wheat support price
all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -16.851 -16.783 -16.673
Schwarz Criterion -12.742 -12.374 -11.960
(Endogenous variables: CPI, broad money,
real GDP, NEER, wheat support
price all in log levels)
Aikaiki Information
Criterion -37.234 -39.316 -98.016
Schwarz Criterion -27.408 -28.669 -86.535
Source: National authorities; and IMF staff calculations.
1/ VAR includes dummies to control for Islamic and Gregorian calendar
effects.
Table 5
Pakistan: Cointegration Test for the CPI, Private Sector Credit,
Wheat Support Price VECM 1/
Trace Test
Number of Coin- Statistic Critical
tegrating Vectors Eigenvalue Value 2/
None 0.329 49.901 42.915
At Most 1 0.109 16.773 25.872
At Most 2 0.083 7.179 12.518
Maximum Eigenvalue
Test
Number of Coin- Statistic Critical
tegrating Vectors Value 2/
None 33.128 25.823
At Most 1 9.594 19.387
At Most 2 7.179 12.518
Source: National authorities; and IMF staff calculations.
1/ VECM of lag length 6; include dummies For Islamic and Gregorian
calendar effects.
2/ Based on MacKinnon, Haug, Michaelis (1999) at the 5 percent level.
Critical values assume no exogenous series in the VECM.
Table 6
Pakistan: Leading Indicators Model Regression Results
M5
Observations 73
Adjusted R-squared 0.995
F-statistic 2,555.1
Akaike Information Criterion -1.935
Schwarz Information Criterion -1.716
Root Mean Squared Error 0.397
Mean Absolute Error 0.350
Mean Absolute Percentage Error 5.662
Coefficient t-statistic
Constant 0.111 2.813
Inflation
Lagged 1 Month 1.772 14.949
Lagged 2 Months -0.760 -4.629
Lagged 3 Months
Lagged 4 Months
Lagged 5 Months -0.194 -1.189
Lagged 6 Months 0.144 1.266
Private Sector Credit Growth
Lagged 6 Months
Lagged 7 Months
Lagged 8 Months
Lagged 9 Months
Lagged 10 Months
Lagged 11 Months 0.042 2.711
Lagged 12 Months -0.038 -2.444
Broad Money Growth
Lagged 6 Months
Lagged 7 Months
Lagged 8 Months
Lagged 9 Months
Lagged 10 Months
Lagged 11 Months
Lagged 12 Months
Long-run Coefficient 1/
Private Sector Credit Growth 10.00
Broad Money Growth
M6
Observations 72
Adjusted R-squared 0.996
F-statistic 881.6
Akaike Information Criterion -1.967
Schwarz Information Criterion -1.303
Root Mean Squared Error 0.358
Mean Absolute Error 0.280
Mean Absolute Percentage Error 4.300
Coefficient t-statistic
Constant -0.069 -0.585
Inflation
Lagged 1 Month 1.680 10.272
Lagged 2 Months -0.843 -2.876
Lagged 3 Months 0.111 0.346
Lagged 4 Months -0.231 -0.710
Lagged 5 Months 0.126 0.429
Lagged 6 Months 0.024 0.182
Private Sector Credit Growth
Lagged 6 Months 0.086 1.623
Lagged 7 Months -0.176 -1.507
Lagged 8 Months 0.087 0.689
Lagged 9 Months 0.052 0.412
Lagged 10 Months 0.068 -0.532
Lagged 11 Months 0.020 0.162
Lagged 12 Months 0.036 0.547
Broad Money Growth
Lagged 6 Months -0.157 -2.169
Lagged 7 Months 0.407 3.164
Lagged 8 Months -0.262 -1.847
Lagged 9 Months 0.028 0.188
Lagged 10 Months 0.074 0.522
Lagged 11 Months -0.072 -0.558
Lagged 12 Months 0.001 0.017
Long-run Coefficient 1/
Private Sector Credit Growth 3.53
Broad Money Growth 7.12
M7
Observations 72
Adjusted R-squared 0.996
F-statistic 3,560.4
Akaike Information Criterion -2.136
Schwarz Information Criterion -1.947
Root Mean Squared Error 0.388
Mean Absolute Error 0.358
Mean Absolute Percentage Error 5.834
Coefficient t-statistic
Constant -0.182 -2.638
Inflation
Lagged 1 Month 1.508 16.025
Lagged 2 Months -0.651 -8.471
Lagged 3 Months
Lagged 4 Months
Lagged 5 Months
Lagged 6 Months
Private Sector Credit Growth
Lagged 6 Months
Lagged 7 Months
Lagged 8 Months
Lagged 9 Months
Lagged 10 Months
Lagged 11 Months
Lagged 12 Months 0.041 4.991
Broad Money Growth
Lagged 6 Months
Lagged 7 Months 0.145 3.775
Lagged 8 Months -0.116 -3.392
Lagged 9 Months
Lagged 10 Months
Lagged 11 Months
Lagged 12 Months
Long-run Coefficient 1/
Private Sector Credit Growth 3.47
Broad Money Growth 4.85
M8
Observations 76
Adjusted R-squared 0.996
F-statistic 3,412.3
Akaike Information Criterion -1.913
Schwarz Information Criterion -1.729
Root Mean Squared Error 1.409
Mean Absolute Error 1.259
Mean Absolute Percentage Error 18.941
Coefficient t-statistic
Constant 0.086 2.082
Inflation
Lagged 1 Month 1.910 37.363
Lagged 2 Months -0.935 -18.128
Lagged 3 Months
Lagged 4 Months
Lagged 5 Months
Lagged 6 Months
Private Sector Credit Growth
Lagged 6 Months
Lagged 7 Months
Lagged 8 Months
Lagged 9 Months
Lagged 10 Months
Lagged 11 Months
Lagged 12 Months
Broad Money Growth
Lagged 6 Months -0.114 -2.270
Lagged 7 Months 0.210 2.211
Lagged 8 Months -0.094 -1.949
Lagged 9 Months
Lagged 10 Months
Lagged 11 Months
Lagged 12 Months
Long-run Coefficient 1/
Private Sector Credit Growth
Broad Money Growth 13.99
Source: Pakistani authorities; and own calculations.
1/ Calculated as (1- sum of coefficients on inflation) / (sum of
coefficients on repressor).