Corrupt clubs and the convergence hypothesis.
Ahmad, Naved
1. INTRODUCTION
Convergence is defined as the decreasing gap of GDP growth rates between leading and lagging countries. This thesis is based on the
Veblen's idea of "Advantages of Backwardness". It states
that a less developed country tends to grow, at a rate which is
inversely proportional to its initial GDP per capita; that is, faster
than more advanced countries. There are several reasons for this
convergence across different countries. First, there is a scope for poor
nations to absorb existing technology and to catch up advanced countries
if the gap between country's technologies is larger. Second, the
development process is often characterised by a shift of resources from
low productivity agriculture sector to high productivity industrial
sector. The process certainly benefits more the poor nations because the
capacity for such shift is more in poor countries than in rich
countries. (1)
Empirical work in a cross section framework demonstrates little or
no support for absolute convergence in per capita GDP. The literature,
however, supports this hypothesis for homogenous group of countries
[Dowrick and Nguyen (1989), Ben-David (1993, 1996)]. Alam (1992)
empirically identifies factors that influence the rate of convergence across countries. These factors include size of the domestic market,
trade intensity, Heitger index, initial enrollments in higher education
expressed as a percentage of the population in a relevant age cohort,
and a Harbison-Myers index of human capital. Abramovitz (1986, 1990)
argues that the advantage of the backwardness primarily depends on the
nation's willingness to realise the potential rapid growth: what he
calls Social Capability. The pace at which the potentiality is realised
depends on factors that limit diffusion of knowledge, the rate of
structural change, the accumulation of capital, and the expansion of
demand. However, the empirical literature fails to recognise that the
social capability is seriously undermined due to pervasive corruption.
Chowdhury (2004) argues that corruption is one of the reasons for
non-convergence across SAARC countries. He did not provide any empirical
support for his argument, however.
In this paper I attempt to demonstrate that persistent corruption
influences the social capabilities and thus impedes the rate of
convergence in per capita income across countries. I approach this task
by following the same methodology used in convergence literature. I
hypothesise that lagging countries do not grow faster than leading
countries simply because lagging countries are unable to break the
shackle of high level of corruption. Thus, this divergence in corruption
rankings, which I call C-divergence, explains the non-convergence of GDP
per capita between lagging and leading economies. In other words, these
corrupt countries will form a "corrupt club" making corruption
more persistent. This is because an already corrupt society is likely to
create an environment where newcomers are also treated as corrupt. There
is pressure on honest officials to be corrupt. Thus, the poor collective
reputation of the previous corrupt government partly determines future
corruption. There may be a demonstration effect across club members such
that officials of one nation perceive the gains of corruption and mimic
the behavior of their peers. Also, multi national corporations (MNCs)
and foreign investors may help create a culture of corruption across a
subset of poor nations with weak statutory and legal protections,
thereby spreading the "disease" more widely.
The literature on convergence often describes two seemingly similar
concepts of convergence. First, [beta] convergence shows the tendency of
poor countries to grow faster than rich countries. Second, [sigma]
convergence indicates a declining dispersion in per capital income for a
group of countries over time. An index of rank concordance (7
convergence) is another measure of convergence used in Boyle and
McCarthy (1997). I borrow the above measures from the convergence
literature and show that countries are C-diverging in corruption
ranking.
The study is organised as follows. Section 2 describes the data and
explains the methodology of this empirical investigation. Section 3
presents the empirical results and final section concludes the study.
2. DATA AND METHOD
The basic theme of this paper is to show that C-divergence process
in corruption across a diverse group of countries influences the
convergence process in per capita GDP. The empirical analysis of
corruption for a large sample of countries has been constrained for
almost two decades by lack of data. There are two reasons for this gap.
First, it is difficult to define corruption in a way that is valid
across countries. A transaction that is considered corrupt in one
culture may be regarded as benign in another. Second, corrupt
transactions are kept secret because they are illegal, so counting and
estimating is hard.
The paucity of data on corruption was solved by some business firms
who conducted questionnaire-based surveys to measure the perception of
corruption. These surveys ask firms' correspondents to rank
countries on the basis of their perceptions. Almost all of these sources
define corruption as the misuse of public power for private benefits
such as the bribes to public officials or kickbacks on government
contracts.
I have used Transparency International Corruption Perceptions
Indices (CPI) that are now available for almost ten years from 1996 to
2005 for forty economies including both developed and developing world.
The index ranges from 0 (corrupt) to 10 (clean). The Transparency
International Corruption Perceptions Indices are available
electronically at http://www.transparency.org. The categorisation of
countries is given in Table 1.
One usually tests the unconditional or absolute convergence by
running the Barro (1991) type regressions, which involve regressing the
growth in GDP per capita on its initial level for a given cross-section
of countries. This methodology however, produces biased estimate of
[beta] convergence [Friedman (1992) and Quah (1993)]. Moreover, in my
case corruption indices are merely perceptions about corruption and are
used to rank countries without attaching any significance to their
absolute values. A country with CPI of 2.8 and 2.9 are both corrupt.
I have used two seemingly different methods. First, I attempt to
show that the average corruption over a ten-year period (1996-2005) is
directly related to the initial value of the corruption index. A
positive relationship suggests that initially corrupt countries are on
average corrupt over the ten year time period. I also check this
relationship by introducing a dummy variable for corrupt countries whose
index is less than 3. I ran the following regression:
Average CPI (1996-2005) = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] * Initial
CPI (1996) + [[beta].sub.2] * D ... (1)
Where CPI is corruption perceptions index and D = 1 if CPI is less
than 3 and D = 0 otherwise.
Second, I have categorised, using average CPI (1996-2005),
countries into four groups: namely corrupt (0 to less than 3), partly
corrupt (3 to less than 5), partly clean (5 to less than 7), and clean
(7 to less than 10). I then show that there is absence of marked
improvement in the corruption indices of corrupt countries for the whole
period.
To support my results, I follow Sala-I-Martin's (1996)
methodology and estimate the dispersion in corruption indices and
coefficient of variation of corruption indices; I call C-[sigma]
convergence across countries. To further strengthen my analysis and
recognising the fact that corruption indices are primarily for ranking
countries, I follow Boyle and McCarthy's (1999) procedure. I
estimate the rank correlation coefficient (rank concordance); I call it
C-[gamma] convergence. C-[sigma] and C-[gamma] coefficients are
estimated as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
C - [gamma] Var([RCPI.sub.ti] + [RCPI.sub.to])/Var([RCPI.sub.to] x
2) ... (3)
Where CPI is corruption perceptions index, Var (CPI) is the
variance of corruption perceptions index for a group of heterogeneous
countries. Var (RCPI) is the corresponding variance of rank of CPI. ti
refers to 1996 to 2005 and to is the initial year 1996.
3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
To understand the trend in corruption I have categorised countries
into four groups: namely corrupt (0 to less than 3), partly corrupt (3
to less than 5), partly clean (5 to less than 7), and clean (7 to less
than 10). I have used average corruption index (1996-2005) for this
categorisation. Table 1 shows the categorisation
Out of 40 countries for which data are available from 1996 to 2005,
7 countries (on average) are corrupt, 8 countries are partly corrupt, 7
countries are partly clean and 18 countries are clean.
The trend in CPI is reported in Table 2 and Table 3. It is evident
from Table 2 and 3 that very few countries have succeeded in moving from
one category to another. The results do confirm the formation of corrupt
clubs that slow down the convergence in per capita GDP process.
Very similar results were found for Partly Corrupt and Partly Clean
countries. The results are reported in Tables 4 and 5.
When I regress average of CPI on initial value of CPI and a dummy for corrupt countries, following results were obtained using ordinary
least square method.
Table 6 shows that countries with high CPI in 1996 have also high
average value of CPI and vise versa suggesting that corrupt countries in
1996 are corrupt on average over the whole period. The negative
coefficient of a dummy variable suggests that corrupt countries have low
value of average CPI, which means more corruption over the whole period.
To further strengthen my analysis, I have calculated C-[sigma] for
the full sample and for the sample of corrupt and clean countries for
the last ten years for which the data are available. The sample of
corrupt and clean countries slightly deviates from the above definition
that I have used in Table 1. To have enough observations, I have ranked
countries as corrupt if the CPI is less than 5 and clean if CPI is
greater than 5. The results are presented in Table 7.
Looking at these standard deviations in Table 7, it is evident that
standard deviation is not changing drastically suggesting that the
relative position of each country over the years is same. However, for
corrupt countries the standard deviation up until 1998 decreases showing
C-convergence and after 2000 it appears that they are C-diverging but
again in 2004 and 2005 S.D decreases suggesting C-convergence. One must
notice here that the values for S.D are very close to each other but
this temporary increase in S.D might be due to sudden changes in
government policies. For clean countries I observe C-convergence between
2000-200 land 2002-2003. After 2003 it shows C-divergence. Nevertheless,
the values are very close to each other suggesting that there is no
drastic change in their status over time. The C-[sigma] coefficient also
demonstrates that the relative position of each country in the
corruption ladder is almost the same with few transitory ups and downs that may be due to government policies that affect corruption
temporarily or changes in perceptions that might be associated with
highly visible news items such as corruption in a major weapons
procurement contract or the removal of a key cabinet official (e.g.
public works).
This issue is further explored by calculating C-[gamma] coefficient
for the same set of countries. The results are reported in Table 8.
Table 8 shows that the value of rank correlation (or C-[gamma]) is
very high and also significant at 1 percent level of significance. The
high positive value of rank correlation among corrupt countries suggests
that they form a corrupt club and do not realise the potentiality of
high growth rate.
4. CONCLUSION
The basic theme of this paper is to demonstrate that persistent
corruption is one important factor explaining the non-convergence
hypothesis across heterogeneous group of countries. This paper using
methodology of the convergence literature attempts to show a
C-convergence for a group of corrupt countries that impedes the
convergence process in per capital GDP. Using Transparency International
(TI) corruption perceptions index, I calculate C-[sigma], and C-[gamma]
coefficients for both corrupt and less corrupt economies to explore
C-divergence. I find that corrupt and less corrupt countries are
C-diverging in corruption rankings, which reduces the speed of
convergence process in per capita GDP. My results suggest that corrupt
countries are indeed C-converging forming a "corrupt club".
The study concludes that countries with pervasive corruption cannot
exploit the benefits of backwardness because of the adverse effects of
corruption on social capability. This analysis explains why backward
nations remain backward. The results must be considered with caution,
however. This is a preliminary exercise to shed some light on the
importance of abating corruption in order to realise the potential for
high economic growth in lagging countries.
REFERENCES
Abler, D. G. and Das J. (1998) The Determinants of the Speed of
Convergence: The Case of India. Applied Economics 30, 1595-1602.
Abramovitz, M. (1986) Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling
Behind. Journal of Economic History 46:2, 385-406.
Abramovitz, M. (1990) The Catch-up Factor in Postwar Economic
Growth. Economic Enquiry 28, 1-18.
Ahmed E. and Amber N. (2000) An Empirical Analysis of Convergence
Hypothesis. Comments. The Pakistan Development Review 39:4, 739-740.
Alam, M. S. (1992) Convergence in Developed Countries: An Empirical
Investigation. Review of World Economics 128, 189-201.
Barro, R. J. (1990) Economic Growth in a Cross-section of
Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 407-443.
Boyle, G. E. and T. G. McCarthy (1997) Simple Measures of
Convergence in Per Capita GDP: A Note on Some Further International
Evidence. Applied Economics Letters 6, 343-347.
Chowdhury, K. (2004) Convergence of Per Capita GDP Across SAARC
Countries. University of Wollongong, Australia. (Economic Working Paper
Series.)
Dowrick, S. and D. T. Nguyen (1989) OECD Comparative Economic
Growth 1950-85: Catch-up and Convergence. American Economic Review 79.
1010-1030.
Friedman, M. (1992) Do Old Fallacies Ever Die? Journal of Economic
Literature 30, 2129-2132.
Quah, D. T. (1993) Galton's Fallacy and Tests for the
Convergence Hypothesis. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95,
427-443.
Sale-i-Martin, X. (1996) The Classical Approach to Convergence
Analysis. The Economic Journal 106, 1019-1036.
Veblen, T. (1915) Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution.
New York: Macmillan.
(1) The discussant, Dr Adeel Malik, explained the convergence
hypothesis that was laid down in the neoclassical growth model of
Solow/Swan. The Solow/Swan model, however, does not seem to be correct
in the context of inter-country convergence, which is the subject matter
of my paper. M. Shaukat Ali, while making a theoretical comment on Dr
Eatzaz Ahmed's paper titled "An Empirical Analysis of
Convergence Hypothesis", clearly distinguished between the concepts
of convergence developed in the Solow/Swan model and the inter-country
convergence based on Veblen's idea of Advantages of Backwardness.
For details, see Ahmed and Naz (2000).
Naved Ahmad is Associate Professor of Economics, Institute of
Business Administration (IBA), Karachi, Pakistan.
Author's Note: The author sincerely thanks Professor John Q.
Adams and Dr Adeel Malik for their helpful comments and suggestions.
However, the author is responsible for the views expressed in this paper
and all remaining errors.
Table 1
Categorisation of Countries
Partly Partly
Corrupt Corrupt Clean Clean
Argentina Brazil Belgium Australia, Austria,
Bolivia Colombia France Canada, Chile,
India Greece Japan Denmark, Finland,
Indonesia Italy Malaysia Germany, Honk Kong
Nigeria Mexico Portugal Ireland, Israel,
Philippines South Korea Spain Netherlands, New Zealand
Venezuela Thailand Taiwan Norway, Singapore,
Turkey Sweden, Switzerland,
United Kingdom, and USA
Table 2
Trend in Corruption (for Corrupt Countries)
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Argentina CR CR CR CR PCR
Bolivia CR CR CR CR CR
India CR CR CR CR CR
Indonesia CR CR CR CR CR
Nigeria CR CR CR CR CR
Philippines CR PCR PCR PCR CR
Venezuela CR CR CR CR CR
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Argentina PCR CR CR CR CR
Bolivia CR CR CR CR CR
India CR CR CR CR CR
Indonesia CR CR CR CR CR
Nigeria CR CR CR CR CR
Philippines CR CR CR CR CR
Venezuela CR CR CR CR CR
CR = Corrupt; PCR = Partly Corrupt.
Table 3
Trend in Corruption (for Clean Countries)
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Australia C C C C C
Austria C C C C C
Canada C C C C C
Chile PC PC PC PC C
Denmark C C C C C
Finland C C C C C
Germany C C C C C
Hong Kong C C C C C
Ireland C C C C C
Israel C C C PC PC
Netherlands C C C C C
New Zealand C C C C C
Norway C C C C C
Singapore C C C C C
Sweden C C C C C
Switzerland C C C C C
United Kingdom C C C C C
USA C C C C C
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Australia C C C C C
Austria C C C C C
Canada C C C C C
Chile C C C C C
Denmark C C C C C
Finland C C C C C
Germany C C C C C
Hong Kong C C C C C
Ireland C PC C C C
Israel C C PC PC PC
Netherlands C C C C C
New Zealand C C C C C
Norway C C C C C
Singapore C C C C C
Sweden C C C C C
Switzerland C C C C C
United Kingdom C C C C C
USA C C C C C
C = Clean; PC = Partly Clean.
Table 4
Trend in Corruption (for Partly Corrupt Countries)
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Brazil CR PCR PCR PCR PCR
Colombia CR CR CR CR PCR
Greece PC PC PCR PCR PCR
Italy PCR PC PCR PCR PCR
Mexico PCR CR PCR PCR PCR
South Korea PC PCR PCR PCR PCR
Thailand PCR PCR CR PCR PCR
Turkey PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Brazil PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
Colombia PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
Greece PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
Italy PC PC PC PCR PCR
Mexico PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
South Korea PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
Thailand PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
Turkey PCR PCR PCR PCR PCR
CR = Corrupt; PCR = Partly Corrupt; PC = Partly Clean.
Table 5
Trend in Corruption (for Partly Clean Countries)
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Belgium PC PC PC PC PC
France PC PC PC PC PC
Japan C PC PC PC PC
Malaysia PC PC PC PC PCR
Portugal PC PC PC PC PC
Spain PCR PC PC PC PC
Taiwan PCR PC PC PC PC
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Belgium PC C C C C
France PC PC PC C C
Japan C C PC PC C
Malaysia PCR PCR PC PCR PC
Portugal PC PC PC PC PC
Spain PC C PC C PC
Taiwan PC PC PC PC PC
PCR = Partly Corrupt: PC = Partly Clean; C = Clean.
Table 6
Dependent Variables: Average Corruption Index between 1996 and 2005
Independent Variables
Constant 0.77
(1.97) ***
CPI 1996 0.91
(18.7) *
Dummy -0.65
(-2.03) **
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.95
D-W Statistic 2.2
Number of Countries 40
*** 10 percent level of significance,** 5 percent level of
significance, * 1 percent level of significance, Results are adjusted
for heteroskedasticity. Figures in parenthesis are t-values.
Table 7
C-[sigma] Coefficient and Standard Deviation (S.D)
Full Sample Corrupt Clean
S.D. C-[sigma] S.D. C-[sigma] S.D. C-[sigma]
1996 2.58 1.00 1.70 1.00 0.77 1.00
1997 2.61 1.02 1.62 0.90 0.93 1.50
1998 2.60 1.01 1.52 0.80 0.93 1.40
1999 2.58 0.99 1.56 0.80 0.96 1.60
2000 2.58 0.99 1.65 0.90 0.97 1.60
2001 2.53 0.95 1.78 1.00 0.78 1.00
2002 2.58 0.99 1.77 1.10 0.87 1.30
2003 2.68 1.01 1.89 1.20 0.84 1.20
2004 2.61 1.00 1.84 1.10 0.89 1.30
2005 2.56 0.95 1.85 I.10 0.90 1.40
Table 8
C-[gamma] Coefficient
Full Sample Corrupt Clean
C-[gamma] C-[gamma] C-[gamma]
1996 1.000 1.000 1.000
1997 0.968 * 0.843 * 0.960 *
1998 0.974 * 0.889 * 0.956 *
1999 0.965 * 0.849 * 0.935 *
2000 0.962 * 0.888 * 0.878 *
2001 0.961 * 0.86l * 0.863 *
2002 0.948 * 0.854 * 0.810 *
2003 0.954 * 0.848 * 0.850 *
2004 0.952 * 0.842 * 0.860 *
2005 0.952 * 0.883 * 0.803 *
* 1 percent level of significance.