Did they do it differently? Capital structure choices of public and private sectors in Pakistan.
Qureshi, Muhammad Azeem ; Azid, Toseef
1. INTRODUCTION
Capital structure is one of the most complex areas of strategic
financial decision making due to its interrelationship with other
financial decision variables. For more than four decades discussion in
corporate finance concerns the question of optimal capital structure:
Given a level of total capital necessary for supporting firm's
activities, is there a way of dividing this capital into debt and equity
which maximises firm value? And, if so, what are the critical factors in
setting the leverage ratio for a given firm? Corporate finance
literature is overwhelmed by this hot debate, which is still going on,
about firm value triggered by the two conflicting conclusions of
Modigliani and Miller (1958, 1963). For a comprehensive review of this
literature, see Harris and Raviv (1991).
The theoretical and empirical research about the optimal capital
structure has so far been inconclusive and conflicting. However, the
capital structure approach to firm value has been successful to replace
heuristics with more methodical approach to define capital structure of
the firm. The researchers have theoretically as well as empirically
identified many endogenous and exogenous factors affecting the
firm's leverage. They have theoretically and empirically identified
agency costs, information asymmetry, taxes, non-debt tax shields,
growth, firm size, assets' collateral value and tangibility,
profitability and liquidity, earnings variability, expected costs of
financial distress, industry classification, country factor, and
firm's international activities as the determinants of firm's
debt-equity choices.
The listed firms in Pakistan operate in public as well as private
sector. Public sector is perceived to be inefficient in operating and
investment decisions due to low managerial effort, a popular argument
given in favour of privatisation. They were also believed to have
privileged access to public sector dominated debt market. Based on
perceived different management practices and environment we hypothesise that the firms in public sector may also have different determinants of
debt-equity choices.
This is an empirical study that covers private as well as public
sector manufacturing firms listed at Karachi Stock Exchange. The data
for this research has been adopted from 'Balance Sheet Analysis of
Joint Stock Companies Listed on the Karachi Stock Exchange' and
published by State Bank of Pakistan. This data is based upon published
accounts of the listed companies.
This study covers twenty nine years' period, 1976-2004, to
identify various determinants of financing choices of manufacturing
firms listed on KSE and to see if type of ownership, i.e. private sector
or public sector, has an impact on these decisions. There is no other
comprehensive data source that may provide firm level financial data in
a standardised format over a longer time frame. The limitation of this
study is that some of the determinants found in literature may not be
calculable from the available data.
2. ANALYSIS
It is a common practice in social sciences that the experts are
using proxies and dummies for their empirical analysis. The same can be
observed in the different studies for the leverage. However, three
proxies for leverage are used in different empirical studies. For
example, Gaver and Gaver (1993) have used Debt/Equity Ratio (Long-term
Liabilities/Common Equity), Remmers, et al. (1974), and Rahman (1990)
have used Debt/Total Assets Ratio (Long-term Liabilities/Total Assets),
and Bradley, et al. (1984) and Wald (1999) have used Total Debt/Total
Assets Ratio [(Short-term Liabilities + Long-term Liabilities)/Total
Assets] as a proxy for capital structure respectively. In most of the
empirical literature these proxies or their combinations are often used
for leverage. Various studies have used book and/or market value of debt
and equity to calculate these proxies. However, the listed firms
included in this database did not raise debt from market in dominant
majority of the cases. Therefore, the book values are the only relevant
values. Moreover, the market values for equity are not available in this
data base. Owing to the data limitation only the book values for equity
will be used wherever needed. No bias because of this misspecification
is expected as observed by Titman and Wessels (1988).
For testing the hypotheses, a number of equations for the three
proxies of leverage, with and without log, linear and non-linear, are
estimated. However, the results of estimated equations indicate that
TL/TA is the best proxy for leverage. The main reason for this
phenomenon may be that the firms in Pakistan are generally observed to
use current liabilities as their regular source for all types of their
financing needs. The structure of capital market in Pakistan suggests
that TL/TA (proportion of total assets being financed through total
liabilities) would better reflect the picture of leverage. Table 1
narrates the proxies of all the variables included in this study.
2.1. Agency Costs
High expense rates and low asset turnover can result from excessive
perquisites and inefficiency in operating and investment decisions due
to low managerial effort resulting into managerial agency costs. The
literature has considered such agency costs and observed that debt
restrains agency costs [Jensen and Meckling 0976) and Thies and Klock
(1992)]. Moreover, managers can readily hide their perks consumption in
operating expenses, while assets purchased for managerial consumption
purposes will tend to reduce asset turnover [Ang, et al. (2000), Singh
and Davidson (2003)]. This study uses expense ratio being the direct
proxy and asset turnover being an inverse measure of agency costs due to
poor investment decisions and insufficient effort by management which
result in lower sales or large amount of assets with low productivity
purchased by the management for excessive perk consumption.
The managements of public sector are perceived to be relatively
inefficient, the argument generally advanced for privatisation of such
firms. Based on this, it is our hypothesis that higher agency costs may
prevail in public sector as compared to private sector. However, the
mean expense ratio (expenses/sales) is 11 percent for public sector and
34 percent for private sector negates the common perception of
inefficiency to show that public sector has been relatively
operationally efficient. While, public sector has been relatively
inefficient in its investment decisions with a mean assets'
utilisation ratio (sale/total assets) of 1.13 as compared to 1.38 of
private sector, in line with common perception. Moreover, to observe
impact of agency costs on leverage regressions were run and regression
results of the leverage with these two proxies of agency costs are shown
in Table 2.
The Table 2 indicates that the increase in operations related
agency costs of public sector firms due to increased management
inefficiency in operating decisions (increased expenses) decreases
leverage. This finding is in line with corporate finance literature that
agency costs are inversely related with leverage. However, management
inefficiency in investment decisions due to poor utilisation of assets
or non-business assets i.e. that may not be used to generate sales like
luxury vehicles, office furniture etc. increases leverage of public
sector firms. It is probably possible due to their privileged access to
financing sources and lesser accountability of their managerial
performance. Such a myopic approach to raise debt for non-business
assets may entangle these firms in 'debt trap'. Conversely,
the private sector shows a strong conformity to the observations found
in literature that agency costs are inversely related to leverage or
increased operational and investment efficiency decreases reliance on
debt.
2.2. Taxes
Researchers have been discussing the question, "Do the tax
benefits of debt affect corporate financing decisions?" Modigliani
and Miller (1963), Scholes and Wolfson (1992), Schulman, et al. (1996)
and many others have presented theoretical as well as empirical
arguments that the tax benefits of debt lead the firms to issue more
debt so as to maximise the firm value. However, Miller (1977), Chen and
Kim (1979), and Fama and French (1998) found no evidence in support of
tax benefit of debt. Some of the researchers like Barclay and Smith
(1995) and Graham (2000) found a mixed support of the tax benefit of
debt.
We will try to answer this question with a little modification,
"Do the tax benefits of debt affect corporate financing decisions
differently in public and private sectors?" Public sectors firms
have got favourable tax treatment during the period under study with the
mean tax rate (taxes/net profit before taxes) of 34 percent as compared
to 53 percent of private sector. However, contrary to the findings of
the literature the Table 3 depicts that the public sector shows a mild
inverse response to decrease leverage if tax rate is increased. This
could be explained by the privileged tax treatment they get. On the
other hand, private sector tends to increase their leverage with the
increase in taxes. This finding is in line with the observations found
in literature; see for example Modigliani and Miller (1963),
MacKie-Mason (1996), Rajan and Zingales (1995), Givoly, et al. (1992),
Barclay and Smith (1995) and Walsh and Ryan (1997).
2.3. Non-debt Tax Shield
Non-debt tax shield Non-debt tax shield may affect financing policy
of the firms. Theoretical models like trade-off [e.g. Scott (1972), and
DeAngelo and Masulis (1980)] and observations by researchers [e.g.
Cordes and Sheffrin (1983), Shenoy and Koch (1996)] suggest that there
exists substitutability between non-debt and debt tax shields. They
observe that the firms with more depreciation allowances may not enjoy
the full tax benefits from leverage. The non-debt tax shields may
eliminate the need for debt-generated tax shields and such firms may
therefore tend to have lower leverage. However, Bradley, et al. (1984)
have found a significant positive association between debt and the
non-debt tax shields.
The Table 4 indicates that public sector seems to take more
advantage of internally generated cash flow by depreciation to reduce
its leverage. Such a behaviour is in conformity with the trade-off model
i.e. the depreciation substitutes the debt tax shield. The private
sector, however, nominally reduces leverage in response to increase in
nondebt tax shield.
2.4. Growth
Toy, et al. (1974), Stonehill, et al. (1975), and Chaplinsky and
Niehaus (1990) have presented evidence to support the view that growth
rate is a determinant of capital structure. Gupta (1969) and Higgins
(1977) have shown that the firms having more investment opportunities
use more debt to maximise the firm's value. While, others found
inverse of this, see for example, Myers (1977), Anderson and Makhija
(1999), Lang, et al. (1996), and Barclay and Smith (1995).
The firm's growth rate is a determinant of capital structure
[Toy, et al. (1974), Stonehill, et al. (1975)]. The results of estimated
equations for both the sectors, depicted in Table 5, indicate that
growth has positive impact on the debt level with public sector
responding more strongly. Privileged access to the debt sources, as
explained in section 2.1, may be a valid reason for this phenomenon.
Moreover, this sector may be growing faster than internally sustainable
and the retained earnings might not be sufficient to finance their
growth needs. While choosing external financing sources, external equity
is generally last resort for such firms as it dilutes earnings leading
them to choose debt. Similar observations are made by Gupta (1969),
Higgins (1977) and Ellsworth (1983).
2.5. Firm Size
A number of studies have suggested that the leverage ratios might
be, directly or inversely, associated with the firm size, for example,
Archer and Faerber (1966), Gupta (1969), Scott and Martin (1975), Titman
and Wesels (1988), and Anderson and Makhija (1999). The estimations for
the present study, presented in Table 6, also suggest that firm size is
inversely associated leverage for both the sectors. Larger firms may
have better access to equity market, or may have low transaction costs,
or may wish to avoid restrictive covenants of debt to maintain their
managerial flexibility.
2.6. Collateral Value of Assets and Tangibility
The firms with assets that could be used as collateral may be
expected to issue more debt to take advantage of this opportunity.
Moreover, higher fraction of tangible assets in assets base of a firm
makes the debt choice more likely [Myers and Majluf (1984), MacKie-Mason
(1990)]. Walsh and Ryan (1997) observe that the firm's debt is an
increasing function of its tangible assets. If the firms do not have
assets to be collateralised the creditors may impose stringent
conditions leading the firms to opt for equity [Jensen and Meckling
(1976), Myers and Majluf (1984)]. However, contrary to the noted
literature, both the assets' collateral value as well as their
tangibility has a negative association with the leverage of public as
well as private sector firms in Pakistan, as depicted in Table 7.
The above results suggest that the firms with higher collateral
value and higher level of tangible assets prefer equity over debt in
their capital structure choices. A possible explanation could be that in
Pakistani credit market the firms might have some other
tools/securities/collaterals/options other than collateral value of
their assets to be able to access the credit market to get debt for the
firm. Moreover, it is felt that these firms take tangible assets as
their productive base for revenue generation that may enable them to
have better returns, more non-debt tax shieldsthe depreciation, and
possibly improved operational cash flows. Better returns and cash flows
may have been used to expand if they have rich perceived investment
opportunity sets. However, if they use these for debt reduction this
indicates that these firms have limited growth options.
2.7. Profitability, Cash Flows, and Liquidity
Profitable and liquid firms could absorb more debt [Brennan and
Schwartz (1984)]. Ross (1977) and Harris and Raviv (1991) suggest that
higher leverage should be associated with higher cash flow in the same
period. Such an explanation is labeled as 'Signaling Theory of
Capital Structure'. On the other hand, Opler and Titman (1994)
observe "A number of authors have noted that the negative
correlation between profits and leverage is consistent with
Donaldson's (1961) POT". Similarly, Titman and Wessels (1988)
and Baskin (1989) suggest that profitable and liquid firms prefer
internally generated funds.
The results shown in Table 8 suggest that the profitability
(NPBT/Sales) has significant inverse association with debt level in both
the sectors that can be explained in the light of POT of Donaldson
(1962) and observations of Titman and Wessels (1988), Baskin (1989) and
Opler and Titman (1994) that profitable firms prefer internal funds for
their investment needs.
Liquidity (Current Assets/Current Liabilities) has negative
association with the debt level of firms in both the sectors. The
probable explanation is 'Pecking Order' of firm's
financing choices, i.e. the liquid firms prefer internal equity and
lesser debt [Titman and Wessels (1988), Myers (1993)]. Also the firms
may have more growth options in their investment opportunity sets in
future. Myers (1977), Barclay and Smith (1995), Lang, et al. (1996) and
Anderson and Makhija (1999) observe that such firms prefer lesser debt.
3. CONCLUSIONS
The public sector firms have a different governance structure when
compared to that of private sector. Moreover, public sector may have
privileged access to financing sources, have got favourable tax
treatment during the period under study as against the private sector
and may have lesser accountability. Public sector seems to be preferring
debt due to its different governance structure and privileged position
they enjoy vis-a-vis their counterparts in private sector.
Inefficiencies coupled with high leverage may entangle these firms in
'debt trap'.
REFERENCES
Anderson, C. W., and A. K. Makhija (1999) Deregulation,
Disintermediation, and Agency Costs of Debt: Evidence from Japan.
Journal of Financial Economics 51, 309-399. Ang J. S., R. A. Cole, and
J. W. Lin (2000) Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of
Finance 55:1, 81-106.
Barclay, M., and C. Smith (1995) The Priority Structure of
Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Finance 40.
Baskin, J. (1989) Empirical Investigation of the Pecking Order Hypothesis. Financial Management 18, 26-33.
Bradley, M., G. A. Jarrell, and E. H. Kim (1984) On the Existence
of an Optimal Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Finance
39:3, 857-78.
Brennan, M. J., and E. S. Schwartz (1984) Optimal Financial Policy
and Firm Valuation. Journal of Finance, July.
Chaplinsky, S., and G. Niehaus (1990) The Tax and Distributional
Effects of Leveraged ESOPS. Financial Management 19:1.
Chen, A. H., and E. H. Kim (1979) Theories of Corporate Debt
Policy: A Synthesis. Journal of Finance, May.
Choate, G. Mare (1997) The Governance Problem, Asset Specificity and Corporate Financing Decisions. Journal of Economic Behaviour and
Organisation 33.
Cordes, J. J., and S. M. Sheffrin (1983) Estimating The Tax
Advantage of Corporate Debt. Journal of Finance, 95-105.
DeAngelo, Harry, and Ronald Masulis (1980) Optimal Capital
Structure Under Corporate and Personal Taxation. Journal of Financial
Economics 8:1, 3-29.
Donaldson, G. (1961) Corporate Debt Capacity." A Study of
Corporate Debt Policy and the Determination of Corporate Debt Capacity.
Boston: Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration
Harvard University.
Ellsworth, R. R. (1983) Subordinate Financial Policy to Corporate
Strategy. Harvard Business Review 61:6.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French (1998) Taxes, Financing Decision, and
Firm Value. Journal of Finance 53:3.
Gaver, J. J., and K. M. Gaver (1993) Additional Evidence on the
Association between the Investment Opportunity Set and Corporate
Financing, Dividend, and Compensation Policies. Journal of Accounting
and Economics 16:1-3.
Givoly, D., C. Hayan, A. R. Ofer, et al. (1992) Taxes and Capital
Structure--Evidence from Firms Response to the Tax Reform Act of 1986.
Review of Financial Studies 5:2, 331-355.
Graham, Jhon R. (1996) Debt and Marginal Tax Rate. Journal of
Financial Economics 41.
Graham, Jhon R. (2000) How Big are the Tax Benefits of Debt'?
Journal of Finance 55:5.
Gupta, M. C. (1969) The Effect of Size, Growth, and Industry on the
Financial Structure of Manufacturing Companies. Journal of Finance 24,
517-29.
Harris, Milton, and Artur Raviv (1991) The Theory of Capital
Structure. The Journal of Finance 46:1.
Higgins, R. C. (1977) How Much Growth Can a Firm Afford? Financial
Management 6, 7-16.
Jensen, M. C., and W. H. Meckling (1976) Theory of Firm--Managerial
Behaviour, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial
Economics 3:4, 305-360.
Lang, L., Eli Ofek, and R. M. Stulz (1996) Leverage, Investment,
and Firm Growth. Journal of Financial Economics 40.
MacKie-Mason, J. K. (1996) Do Taxes Affect Corporate Financing
Decisions'? Journal of Finance 45:5, 1471-93. Also, NBER Working
Paper No. 2632.
Miller, M. H. (1977) Debt and Taxes. Journal of Finance, 261-273.
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller (1958) The Cost of
Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. The American
Economic Review.
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller (1963) Corporate Income
Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction. American Economic Review
53, 433-443.
Myers, S. C. (1977) Determinants of Corporate Borrowing. Journal of
Financial Economics 147-176.
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf (1984) Corporate
Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms have Information that
Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial Economics 13.
Opler, T. C., and S. Titman (1994) Financial Distress and Corporate
Performance. Journal of Finance.
Rahman, Faizanur (1990) Industry and Size as Determinants of
Capital Structure Decisions in Pakistan. Pakistan Management Review
(Fourth Quarter.)
Rajan, Raghuran G., and Luigi, Zingles (1995) What Do We Know about
Capital Structure'? Some Evidence from International Data. Journal
ofbTnance 50:5.
Remmers, L., A. Stonehill, R. Wright, and T. Beekhuisen (1974)
Industry and Size as Debt Ratio Determinants in Manufacturing
Internationally. Financial Management (Summer), 24-32.
Ross, Stephen (1977) The Determination of Financial Structure: The
Incentive Signaling Approach. Bell Journal of Economics 8, 23-40.
Scholes, Myron S., and Mark A. Wolfson (1992) Tares and Business
Strategy: A Global Planning Approach. Englewood Cliffs, N J:
Prentice-Hall.
Schulman, C. T., D. W. Thomas, K. F. Sellers, and D. B. Kennedy
(1996) Effects of Tax Integration and Capital Gains Tax on Corporate
Leverage. National Tar Journal 49:1.
Scott, D. F., Jr., and J. D. Martin (1975) Industry Influence on
Financial Structure. Financial Management 67-73.
Scott, David F. Jr. (1972) Evidence on the Importance of Financial
Structure. Financial Management, Summer.
Shenoy, Catherine, and P. D. Koch (1996) The Firm's
Leverage-cash Flow Relationship. Journal of Empirical Finance 2.
Sihler, William W. (1971) Framework for Financial Decisions.
Harvard Business Review 11-23.
Singh, M., and W. M. Davidson (2003) Agency Costs, Ownership
Structure and Corporate Governance Mechanisms. Journal of Banking and
Finance 27:5, 793-816.
State Bank of Pakistan (Various Issues) Balance Sheet Anah,sis of
Joint Stock Companies Listed on the Karachi Stock Exchange. Karachi:
State Bank of Pakistan.
Stonehill, A., T. Beekhuisen, R. Wright, L. Remmers, N. Toy, A.
Pares, A. Shapiro, D. Egan, and T. Bates (1975) Financial Goals and Debt
Ratio Determinants: A Survey of Practice in Five Countries. Financial
Management, Autumn, 27-40.
Thies, Cliff or F., and Mark S. Klock (1992) Determinants of
Capital Structure. Review of Financial Economics, Spring.
Titman, Sheridan, and Roberto Wessels (1988) The Determinants of
Capital Structure Choice. The Journal of Finance 43:1, 1-19.
Toy, Norman, A. Stonehill, L. Remmers, R. Wright, and T. Beekhuisen
(1974) A Comparative International Study of Growth, Profitability, and
Risk as Determinants of Corporate Debt Ratios in the Manufacturing
Sector. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.
Walsh, Eamonn J., and James Ryan(1997) Agency and Tax Explanations
of Security Issuance Decisions. Journal of Business Finance and
Accounting 24:7-8.
Muhammad Azeem Qureshi <Muhammad.Qureshi@studcnt.uib.no> is
Assistant Professor of Finance at the Institute of Management Sciences,
Bahauddin Zakariya University, Multan. and is enrolled for a PhD at the
University of Bergen, Norway. Toseef Azid <toseefazid@bzv.edu.pk>
is Professor, Economics Department, Bahauddin Zakariya University,
Multan.
Table 1 Variables and Their Proxies
Variable Proxy
Leverage TL/TA Ratio
Agency Costs Expense Ratio
Assets' Utilisation Ratio
Taxes Tax Rate
Non-debt Tax Shield Depreciation Rate
Growth Sales Growth Rate
Firm Size Ln (Total Assets)
Assets' Collateral Value Gross Fixed Assets' Ratio
Assets' Tangibility Net Fixed Assets' Ratio
Profitability Net Income Ratio
Liquidity Current Ratio
Earnings Variability Changes in Net Profit before
Taxes
Variable Definition
Leverage (Long-term Liabilities + Short-term
Liabilities)/Total Assets
Agency Costs Operating Expenses/Sales
Sales/Total Assets
Taxes Tax Provision/Net Profit Before Taxes
Non-debt Tax Shield Depreciation for the Year/Total Assets
Growth ([Sales.sub.1]-[Sales.sub.0])/[Sales.sub.0]
Firm Size Ln (Total Assets)
Assets' Collateral Value Fixed Assets' at Cost/Total Assets
Assets' Tangibility Net Fixed Assets/Total Assets
Profitability Net Income/Total Assets
Liquidity Current Assets/Current Liabilities
Earnings Variability {([NPBT.sub.1]-[NPBT.sub.0])/
[NPBT.sub.0]}/TA1
Table 2
Correlation of Agency Costs with Leverage
Correlation
Coefficient with
TL/TA
Proxy Ratio Public Private
Expense Ratio Operating -0.19 -0.73
Expenses/Sales
Assets Utilisation Sale/Total Assets -0.27 0.75
Ratio
Table 3
Relationship of Taxes with Leverage
Correlation
Coefficient with TL/LA
Proxy Ratio Public Private
Tax Rate Taxes/Net Profit Before Taxes -0.05 0.23
Table 4 Relationship of Non-debt Tax Shield with Leverage
Correlation Coefficient
with TL/TA
Proxy Ratio Public Private
Depreciation Rate Depreciation/Total -0.52 -0.03
Assets
Table 5 Relationshin of Groivth with Leverage
Correlation Coefficient
with TUTA
Proxy Ratio Public Private
Sales Growth Rate ([Sales.sub.1] - 0.21 0.12
[Sales.sub.0])/
[Sales.sub.0]
Table 6 Relationship of Growth with Leverage
Correlation Coefficient
Proxy Ratio with TL/TA
Public Private
Ln(Total Assets) Ln(Total Assets) -0.46 -0.77
Table 7
Relationship Of Collateral Value of Assets and
Tangibility with Leverage
Correlation
Coefficient with
TL/TA
Proxy Ratio Public Private
Gross Fixed Assets' Fixed Assets' at -0.65 -0.25
Ratio Cost/Total Assets
Net Fixed Assets' Net Fixed Assets/Total -0.21 -0.72
Ratio Assets
Table 8
Relationship of Profitability, Cash Flows, and Liquidity, with
Leverage
Correlation Coefficient
with TL/TA
Proxy Ratio Public Private
Net Profit Ratio NPBT/Sales -0.48 -0.38
Cash Flow Ratio Net Cash Flow/Sales -0.23 -0.56
Current Ratio Current Ratio/Current -0.09 -0.29
Liabilities