Is trade good for environment? A unit root cointegration analysis.
Khalil, Samina ; Inam, Zeeshan
I. INTRODUCTION
One of the most debatable issues surrounding globalisation is the
concern that trade hurts the environment, both locally and globally.
Economists argue that expanding trade from domestic market to
international market not only increases market share of each country but
also rising competition among the nations and improve efficiency of
utilising scarce resources because each country produces those goods in
which she has comparative advantages. But on the other hand,
environmental economists have opposed global trade and argue that the
costs of spreading trade to international markets are depleting natural
resources and rising pollution emissions that ultimately deteriorates
environmental quality. [Copeland and Taylor (2001), Antweiler, Copeland
and Taylor (2001), Chaudhuri and Pfaff (2002), Schmalensee, Stoker and
Judson (1996).]
There is a conflict among economists as environmental economists
argue that pollution control and natural resource management issues are
neglected in trade policy. Further, new scenario of economics raises
competition among the nations and they encourage export led growth,
privatisation, deregulation and free trade. All these factors have
severe effect on social structure. It has led to the collapse of social
systems; increased social inequities resulting in conflicts; displaced
populations; and increased migration. It has shaped a development model
of production and consumption with far reaching impacts on the physical
environment worldwide [Bhagwati (1999)]. On the other hand, some
economists claim that trade is beneficial for environment because trade
raises competition by reducing trade barriers, improved quality of
product and implementation of environmental regulations. Further, trade
led growth improves standard of living of the developing countries as
well as environmental quality. [Runge (1994); Helpman (1998); Daniel and
Giradina (1998)].
One of the well-known environmental arguments against foreign trade
is that it allows dirty industries (1) to be shifted from developed
nations to developing nations. There are three reasons for such an
action. First, firms that face regulations at home will use the threat
of relocation to successfully lobby for special relieves from
regulations at home. Second it is inappropriate to export our dirty
industries to developing countries, and finally there is concern about
pollution produced in less developed countries which carries back to
developed nations.
There is much more empirical work to find out relationship between
GDP growth and environmental degradation, which is known as
environmental Kuznets curve (EKC). But still environmental Kuznets curve
is a controversial issue in literature. Many believe that environment
and per capital income hold same relationship as relationship between
per capita income and income distribution which was found by Simon
Kuznet in 1955. (2) They stated that at initial level of growth,
environmental quality is worsen, while at later stage of growth it
improves because people desire for better environment. [Grossman and
Krueger (1991, 1995), Selden and Song (1994), Shafik and Bandyopadyay
(1992), Stern, Common and Barbier (1996), Panaotou (1993) Antle and
Heidebrink (1995), Dasgupta, Laplante, and Wheeler (2002), Eakin and
Seldon (1995), Hettige, Mani and Wheeler (2000), Kuznet (1955)]. On the
other hand, some economists have empirically proved that such
relationship close not hold between per capita income and environmental
quality [Koop and Tole (1999), Dietz (2000)].
But there is not enough research work that has evaluated the
impacts of global trade on environment. Therefore, the purpose of this
study is to find out how trade deteriorates environmental quality and
deplete natural resources. A unit root cointegration technique has been
used for it. The sources of data are World Bank/World Development
Indicators/Economic Survey of Pakistan.
The paper is organised in Section 1I and III which discuss
methodological issue and procedure, Section IV provides empirical
results and finally Section V presents concluding remarks.
II. DATA SOURCE AND METHODOLOGY
This study is designed to analyse impacts of foreign trade on
domestic environmental quality. Recent empirical work suggests that
there is either not enough research work to find out relationship
between trade and environmental quality or if there is any study then it
consists of cross sectional data. This study analyses if there is any
long run relationship between trade and environmental quality. (3) The
relationship between trade and environmental quality is simple;
therefore, study explores the impact of trade indicators on the
environment in Pakistan. As a beginning of empirical framework, two
different indicators of environmental quality are used to examine impact
of trade on environmental quality. (4) We estimate the following
linear-trade environmental model for our study.
[CO.sub.2] = [[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2]EX +
[[alpha].sub.3]PD + [[alpha].sub.4]FDI + [[alpha].sub.5]Y + [mu] ... (1)
LA = [[beta].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.2]EX + [[beta].sub.3]PD +
[[beta].sub.4]FDI + [[beta].sub.5]Y[mu] ... (2)
These two models consist of six variables, Arable Land (hectares in
thousand) (AL), Carbon Dioxide Emissions (kt in thousand) [CO.sub.2],
Exports (EX), Population Density (PD), GDP per capita (Y), and Foreign
Direct Investment (FDI). The data is obtained from the World Development
Series and Economic Survey of Pakistan.
III. ECONOMETRIC PROCEDURE
There are three basic environmental issues; air pollution, water
pollution and land degradation. This paper is confined to two
environmental pollution areas, air and land. We analyse the impact of
trade variables on environmental quality indicators both carbon dioxide
emission ([CO.sub.2]) and arable land (AL) separately. First Augmented
Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test is used to examine whether the time series is
unit root. Second, Johansson's maximum likelihood multiple co-
integration test is used to find out long run relationship among the
variables. Further if there is existence of long run relationship among
variables then Error Correction test is applied to find out short-run
relationship because there is possibility of disequilibrium in the
short-run. Finally, Granger Causality Test is applied to investigate
that whether these variables have causality or not.
The co-integration technique pioneered by Granger (1986), and Engle
and Granger (1987) permit long-run components of variables to conform
long-run equilibrium relationships to the short-run components having a
flexible dynamic specification. In light of Shintani's (1994)
finding that the Johansson method is more powerful than the
Engle-Granger method, the multivariate co-integration framework that we
intend to use here has now come to be established as a standard one for
VAR systems. The procedure may be summarised as follows [see for
example, Johanson (1988); Johansen and Juselius (1990)]. Unlike the
Engle and Granger co-integration method, the Johanson procedure can find
multiple cointegration vectors. For this approach, one has to estimate
an unrestricted Vector Auto-Regression (VAR) of the following form:
Let Xt be an I(1) vector representing the n-series of interest. A
VAR of length p for Xt, would then be of the form.
Xt = [[rho].summation over (j=1)][[product].sub.j][X.sub.t-j] +
[mu] + [epsilon] t = 1, 2, 3, ... T
Where the [[product].sub.j] are matrices of constant coefficients,
[mu] is an intercept, [epsilon] is a Gaussian error term and T the total
number of observations.
The ECM corresponding to Equation (2) is
[DELTA]X = [p.summation over
(j=1)][[GAMMA].sub.j][DELTA][X.sub.t-1] + [product][X.sub.t-p] + [mu] +
[epsilon]
Where [DELTA] is the first-difference operator and the expression
for [GAMMA]j and [product] are as given in Johanson and Juselius (1990).
If Rank ([product]) = r(r<n) then co integration is indicated
(with r co- integrating vectors present) and further, in this case II
may be factored as [product]=[alpha][beta], with the matrix [beta]
comprising the r co-integrating vectors and ct can be interpreted as the
matrix of corresponding ECM weights. The matrix [product] contains the
information on long run relationship between variables, if the rank of
[product]=0, the variables are not co-integrated. On the other hand if
rank (usually denote by 'r') is equal to one, there exist one
co-integrating vector and finally if 1<r<n, there are multiple
co-integrating vectors.
[Johanson and Juselius (1990)] have derived two tests for
co-integration, namely trace test and the maximum eigenvalue test. The
first task in Johanson procedure is to choose an autoregressive order
(p). There are tests for the choice of this appropriate lag length. (5)
The ECM weights [alpha]i determine the short-run term error correction
responses of the variables to deviations from long-run equilibrium
values.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
There are two co-integration techniques to investigate long run
relationship among the variables but the Johanson co-integration and
error correction techniques are used to examine long run and short run
relationship respectively. (6)
But before applying co-integration technique to establish long run
relationship, it is imperative to make the series stationary and
establish order of integration among variables. That is why, Augmented
Dickey Fuller (ADF) method was carried out on the time series levels and
first difference form. The results are presented in Table 1 and show
that all variables are unit root (non-stationary) at levels and
stationary at first difference. Therefore all Variables ([CO.sub.2], PD,
EX, Y, FDI, AL) are integrated of order of one I(1).
[DELTA]X = [[gamma].sub.O] + [[gamma].sub.1][X.sub.t-1] +
[[summation].sub.p.sub.i=1][beta][DELTA][X.sub.t-i] + [[gamma].sub.3]T +
[u.sub.t]
To establish order of integration, in next step, Johansen maximum
likelihood co-integration method of E(1) and E(2) is used to investigate
the presence of long run relationship among environmental and trade
variables. Two separate environmental indicators are used to examine
possible effect of trade variables on environmental quality, Carbon
Dioxide ([CO.sub.2]) is an indicator of air pollution while arable land
(AL) measures quality of land. First, this study observes impact of
trade on air Quality. The results of co-integration among [CO.sub.2],
Ex, PD, Y and FDI are presented in Table 2.
Starting with null hypothesis of no co-integration(r=0) among the
variables, the trace statistic is 92.71 which exceeds the 99 percent
critical value of the [lambda]trace statistic (critical value is 84.45),
it is possible to reject the null hypothesis (r=0) of no cointegration
vector, in favour of the general alternative r[greater than or equal
to]1. As evident in Table 2, the null hypothesis of r[less than or equal
to]1 r[less than or equal to]2 cannot be rejected at 5 percent level of
significance. Consequently, we conclude that there is one cointegration
relationship involving variables [CO.sub.2], EX, Y, FDI and PD.
On the other hand, [lambda]max statistic reject the null hypothesis
of no cointegration vector(r=0) against the alternative (r=1) as the
calculated value [lambda]max(0,1)-40.92 exceeds the 99 percent critical
value(30.34). Thus, on the basis of [lambda]max statistic there are also
only one co-integration vector. The presence of cointegration vector
shows that there exists a long run relationship among the variables. The
long run elasticities of PD, Y, EX and FDI are 1.13, 0.68, 0.09 and 0.06
respectively.
Similarly, Johansen co-integration test is applied to check the
long run relationship among arable land and trade variables (AL, PD, EX,
Y and FDI). The results are presented in Table 3.
Table 3 shows that null-hypothesis of no cointegration(r=0) among
the variables is rejected because the trace statistic 86.05 exceeds the
99 percent critical value of the [lambda]trace statistic (critical value
is 84.45), therefore, present study rejects the null hypothesis (r=0) of
no cointegration vector, in favor of the general alternative r[greater
than or equal to]1. As evident in Table 3, the null hypothesis of r[less
than or equal to]1 r[less than or equal to]2 cannot be rejected at 5
percent level of significance. Consequently, we conclude that there is
one cointegration relationship involving variables AL, EX, Y, FDI and
PD.
On the other hand, [lambda]max statistic reject the null hypothesis
of no cointegration vector(r=0) against the alternative (r=1) as the
calculated value [lambda]max (0,1)=40.25 exceeds the 99 percent critical
value(30.34). Thus, on the basis of [lambda]max statistic there are also
only one co-integration vector. The presence of cointegration vector
shows that there exists a long run relationship among the variables.
Johansen maximum likelihood co-integrated vector techniques
indicate that there is a long run relationship among variables. Once
long run relation is established, Error correction model can be used to
examine short run distortion (shocks) in the model. Our study consists
of two separate environmental problems, that is why we estimate two
separate error correction model (ECM) for response of [CO.sub.2] and AL
to determine short run dynamics of the system. To estimate the short run
error correction model, we used general to specific approach [Hendry
(1979)].
Using Hendry general to specific approach, initially, two lags of
the explanatory variables and one lag of the error correction term are
incorporated. Later, insignificant variables are gradually eliminated.
The estimated results of Error Correction Model (ECM) are presented in
Table 4 and Table 5.
The coefficients of error correction model (ECM) have correct
negative sign and statistically significant at 5 percent level. (7) It
suggests the validity of long-run equilibrium relationship among the
variables in Table 2 and Table 3. Thus, ECM is not only valid but also
there is significant conservative force tendency to bring the model back
into equilibrium whenever it strays too far. The results of diagnostic
test indicate that both equations passes the test of serial correlation,
functional form, normality and heterodasticity. The small sizes of
coefficient of error-correction terms indicate that speed of adjustment
is rather slow for equation to return to their equilibrium level once it
has been shocked.
Since all variables are measured in logarithms, therefore, the
regression coefficients can be directly interpreted as elasticities.
Estimated results of error correction model of response variable
[CO.sub.2] is presented in Table 4 and indicate that except export both
GDP per capita (y) and foreign direct investment (FDI) have significant
positive impact on environment quality. For example long run elasticity
of Y is 0.68 which indicates that a one percent increase in Y result in
0.68 percent increase in [CO.sub.2] emission in the air while long run
elasticity of FDI is 0.06 which indicates that a one percent increase in
FDI would raise [CO.sub.2] emission by 0.06 percent. On the other hand,
in Table 5 none of the trade variable has significant impact on
environment while, population density has significant positive impact on
environment as it is expected. It suggests that a one percent increase
in PD raises AL by 0.74 percent.
V. CONCLUSION
During the last few decades, trade led growth is supposed to be
prerequisite for economic development. Economists argue that expanding
trade from domestic market to international market not only increases
market share of each country but also raise competition among the
nations and improve efficiency of utilising scarce resources. On the
other hand, environmental economists are opposed to such argument and
they claim that real cost of spreading trade among the nations is
depleting natural resources and deteriorate environmental quality.
In this study, we used Johansen-Juselius co-integration technique
for valid long run relationship among the variables and error correction
models to determine the short run dynamics of system to time series data
for Pakistan's economy, over the period 1972-2002.
A valid long run relationship was found among the variables
indicating that spreading trade on global level is harmful for
environmental quality for developing countries because developed
countries transfer their worse technology to the developing nations.
Both [CO.sub.2] emission and arable land (AL) have significant long run
relationship, but we could not find any significant relationship among
arable land (AL) and trade variables. On the other hand, there is a
significant short run relationship among [CO.sub.2] emission, per capita
income and foreign direct investment (FDI).
The results indicate that we need to design appropriate economic
policies to protect environment. These policies are to be based on sound
macro-and micro economic management, couple with good governance aimed
at regulating laws to protect environment and promoting sustained
economic growth. Further, this study provide an idea for research in
determining the impacts of environmental laws on economic growth.
REFERENCES
Antic, J. M. and G. Heidbrink (1995) Environment and Development:
Theory and International Evidence. Economic Development and Cultural
Change 43: 3,603-625.
Antweiler, Werner, Brian Copeland, and M. Scott Taylor (2001) Is
Free Trade Good for the Environment? (NBER Working Paper No. 6707).
American Economic Review 91: 4, 877-908.
Bhagwati, J. M. (1999)Free Trade in the 21st Century: Managing
Viruses, Phobias, and Social Agendas.
Chaudhuri, Shubham, and Alexander Pfaff (2002) Economic Growth and
the Environment: What Can We Learn from Household Data? Columbia
University, February.
Copeland, Brian, and M. Scott Taylor (2001) International Trade and
the Environment: A Framework for Analysis. (NBER Working Paper No. 8540,
Oct.)
Dasgupta, Susmita, B. Laplante, H. Wang and Davi Wheeler (2002)
Confronting the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Journal of Economic
Perspective 16:1, 147-168.
Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1981) Likelihood Ratio Statistics
for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Econometrica 49,
1057-1072.
Dietz. S. (2000) Does an Environmental Kuznets Curve Exist for
Biodiversity?
Eakin, H. and S. T. Seldon (1995) Stoking the Fires? [CO.sub.2]
Emission and Economic Growth. Journal of Public Economic 57, 85-101.
Engle and C. Granger (1987) Cointegration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica 55, 251-276.
Esty, Daniel, and Damien Giradin (1998) Environmental Protection
and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework. Journal of
World Trade 32: 3, 5-46.
Grossman, G. and A. Krugger (1995) Economic Growth and Environment.
Quarterly Journal of Economic 60, 353-377.
Helpman, Eihanan (1988) Growth, Technological Progress, and Trade.
National Bureau of Economic Research (Reprint No. 1145.)
Hettige, Hemamala, M. Mani, and D. Wheeler (2000) Industrial
Pollution in Economic Development, the Environmental Kuznets Curve
Revisited. Journal of Economic Development 62, 445-476.
Johansen, S. and K. Juselius (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation
and Inference on Cointegration with Applications the Demand for Money.
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 52:2, 169-210.
Johansen (1988) Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating Vectors.
Journal of Economic' Dynamic' and Control 12, 231-254.
Koop, G. and L. Tole (1999) Is there Environmental Kuznets Curve
for Deforestation? Journal of Development Economic 58, 231-244.
Kuznets, S. (1995) Economic Growth and Income Inequality. American
Economic Review 45:1, 11-28.
Panayotou. T. (1993) Empirical Test and Policy Analysis of
Environmental Degradation at Different Stages of Economic Development.
(Working Paper, wp 238.)
Rodrik, D. (1994) Foreign Trade in Eastern Europe's
Transition: Early Results. In O. J. Blanchard et al. (eds.) The
Transition in Eastern Europe. Chicago and London: University of Chicago
Press.
Seldon, T. M., and D. Song (1994) Environmental Quality and
Development, is there a Kuznets Curve for Air Pollution Emission?
Journal of Environmental Economic and Management 27, 147-167.
Shafik, N. and S. Bandyopadhyay (1992) Economic Growth and
Environmental Quality: Time Series and Cross-country Evidence.
Background Paper for World Development Report. WPS, Washington, DC. The
World Bank
(1) "Dirty Industries" means transfer of bad technology.
(2) Kuznets (1955) in his article "Economic Growth and Income
Inequality" proposed inverted U-Shaped Curve for relationship
between Growth and Inequality.
(3) Jeffrey and Rose (2002) sort out causality between trade and
environmental quality. They Used [CO.sub.2] emission as air pollution
and as air quality indicators, Seldon and Song (1994) also used
[CO.sub.2], for air pollution.
(4) AL used for agriculture sector and [CO.sub.2], for industrial
sector.
(5) Akaike Information Criteria and Schwarz Criterion ets.
(6) The Johansen-Juselius (1990) can find multiple cointegrating
vectors; Engle-Granger approach has several limitations in the case of
more than one cointegration vector.
(7) The error-correction term was calculated from the Maximum
Likelihood Estimates of cointegrating vector.
Samina Khalil <skhalilpk@yahoo.com> is Senior Research
Economist at the Applied Economics Research Centre (AERC), University of
Karachi, Karachi. Zeeshan Inam <zeeshan_inam671@hotmail.com> is
Lecturer at the Mohammad Ali Jinnah University, Islamabad.
Table 1
Test of the Unit Root Hypothesis
Level First Difference
Variables t-statistics K t-statistics K
AL -3.01 4 -1.83 * 1
C[O.sub.2] -2.85 l -3.36 ** 1
PD -1.36 3 -4.81 * 2
FDI -0.2 4 -4.28 * 3
Y -2.61 3 -2.8 *** 1
EX 0.2 4 -2.68 *** 2
Note: The t-statistic reported in is the t-ratio on
[[gamma].sub.1] in the following regression.
The optimal lags (k) for conducting the ADF test were
determined by AIC (Akaike information criteria).
**, * and *** indicate significance at the 5 percent,
1 percent and 10 percent levels, respectively.
Table 2
Johansen's Test for Multiple Cointegration Vectors
Co-Integration Test Among [COZ Y, FDI, EX, PD]
95% 99%
Tests Critical Critical
H0: H1: Statistics values values
[lambda]trace [lambda]
trace
r = 0 r > 0 92.71 * 76.07 84.45
r [less than r > 1 51.79 53.12 60.16
or equal
to] 1
r [less than r > 2 26.79 34.91 41.07
or equal
to] 2
[lambda]max values [lambda]
max values
r = 0 r = 1 40.925 25.54 30.34
r = 1 r = 2 14.13 18.96 23.65
r = 2 r = 3 1.6 12.25 16.26
Cointegrating Vector C[O.sub.2] EX PD Y FDI
-1 0.09 1.13 0.68 0.06
* Indicates significance at the, 1 percent levels.
Table 3
Johansen's Test for Multiple Cointegration Vectors
Co-Integration Test Among [AL,Y FDI,EX,PD]
95% 99%
Tests Critical Critical
H0: H1: Statistics Values Values
[lambda]trace [lambda]
trace
r = 0 r > 0 86.05 76.07 84.45
r [less than r > 1 45.8 53.12 60.16
or equal
to] 1
r [less than r > 2 22.97 34.91 41.07
or equal
to] 2
[lambda]max values [lambda]
max values
r = 0 r = 1 40.25 25.54 30.34
r = 1 r = 2 17.28 18.96 23.65
r = 2 r = 3 6.88 12.25 16.26
Cointegrating Vector LA EX PD Y FDI
-1 0.027 0.74 0.20 0.029
* Indicates significance at the, 1 percent levels.
Table 4
Estimated Error Correction Model-I
Dependent Variable=[DELTA]AL
Regressors Estimated Coefficients
Constant 0.775 **
[DELTA]AL (-1) 3.63 **
[DELTA]P[??](-1) 3.330 *
[DELTA]FDI 0.006
[DELTA]Y 0.093
[DELTA]EX(-1) 0.029
RES(-1) -0.025 **
Diagnostic Tests
Serial Correlation 0.85
Heteroscedasticity 1.25
Functional Form 0.65
Normality 0.31
**, * and *** indicate significance at the 5 percent,
1 percent and 10 percent levels, respectively.
Table 5
Estimated Error Correction Model-II
Dependent Variable=[DELTA]C[O.sub.2] Estimated Coefficients
Regressors
Constant 0.044 **
[DELTA]C[O.sub.2] (-1) 0.003 **
[DELTA]PD(-1) 0.769
[DELTA]FDI(-2) 0.070 ***
[DELTA]Y(-1) 0.017 **
[DELTA]EX(-1) 0.030
RES(-1) -0.02 **
Diagnostic Tests
Serial Correlation 0.75
Heteroscedasticity 1.14
Functional Form 0.60
Normality 0.49
**, * and *** indicate significance at the 5 percent,
1 percent and 10 percent levels, respectively.