Province-wise growth patterns in human capital accumulation.
Sabir, Muhammad ; Aftab, Zehra
I. INTRODUCTION
It is apparent from various labour force surveys that during the
past 20 years Pakistan's employed labour force has become more
"educated". For instance, according to the Labour Force Survey
1982-83, 28 percent of the employed labour force had attained formal
education). (1) In comparison, the literate employed labour force in
1999-2000 is estimated at 46 percent, while the formally educated is 43
percent. However, the pattern of growth in educated labour force is not
uniform in all four provinces of the country. A closer look at
disaggregated provincial level data reflects the disparity in employed
labour force in the four provinces: Punjab, Sind, NWFP, and Baluchistan.
Regional decomposition of the labour force data shows that Sindh
has consistently demonstrated the highest level of literacy among the
four provinces over the past 20 years; Balochistan, in contrast, has
demonstrated the lowest level of educational attainment for its employed
labour force. However, the gap between the literacy level of Sindh as
compared to the provinces of both Punjab and NWFP has gradually
narrowed. This is because although Sindh started out with the highest
base, in terms of growth of its educated work force, since Sindh's
educated have grown at a decreasing rate, Punjab and NWFP have caught up
because of much higher rates of growth in their respective literate
employed labour force. In 1999-2000, 43 percent of Punjab's and 39
percent of NWFP's labour force is categorised as formally educated,
as compared to 49 percent for Sindh.
Despite the convincing evidence of regional disparities no
satisfactory measure of human capital stock at the provincial level
presently exists for Pakistan. (2) This paper is motivated to fill the
above gap in policy analysis by estimating the human capital index (HCI)
at the provincial level from 1982-83 to 2003-04. This index is based on
two main components: completion of education levels and age (as a proxy
for experience). The index is computed for the three sectors of the
economy: Agriculture, Manufacturing, and Services, by using published
and micro data from the respective Labour Force Surveys. Given the
recent initiative vis-a-vis the devolution of power to the local level
this exercise becomes all the more relevant. Moreover, given its rapidly
advancing population, Pakistan needs to count on an improvement in the
quality of its labour force to compensate for the increasing pressures
on its limited resources. A suitable measure of human capital per worker
can be used to assess correctly the evolution of the effective labour
force.
The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 provides an overview
of the different approaches associated with HCI computation elaborated
in the economic literature. Section 3 provides details of the
methodology adopted for the subject analysis, while estimation results
are presented in section 4. Finally, Section 5 offers concluding
remarks.
2. METHODOLOGICAL REVIEW
This section reviews the different approaches employed to measure
human capital. Broadly speaking there are three main approaches to
compute human capital: the cost-based approach, output approach, and
labour-income based approach. Following is a brief review of all three
(for a detailed account see Laroche and Merette, Measuring Human Capital
in Canada 2000-05).
2.1. Cost-based Approach
As the name reflects, this input-based approach estimates the stock
of human capital by aggregating the depreciated value of cumulative
total investment towards human capital formation, including investment
in education and health; the opportunity cost of attending school is
also accounted for. It must be noted however that this approach is
particularly sensitive to the rate of depreciation used. Moreover, the
distinction between consumption and investment also adds an element of
subjectivity to the estimation.
2.2. Output-based Approach
This approach uses outcome indicators relevant to human capital
formation. The most common measures used in the literature are adult
literacy, school enrollment rates, and average years of formal
schooling. Although these measures are based on easily available data,
thereby making cross-country comparisons possible, these indicators
emphasize quantity rather than the quality of education. In fact the
quality of education is assumed to be constant across regions and over
time.
2.3. Labour-income-based Approach
In order to duly address the quality issue Mulligan and
Sala-i-Martin (1997) developed a labour-income-based measure of human
capital. The measure is based on the assumption that the aggregate level
of output is determined by an aggregate production function that depends
on two inputs: the total human capital H and total nonhuman capital K in
the economy.
[Q.sub.t] = F([v.sub.t] [K.sub.t], [u.sub.t] [H.sub.t]) ... ... ...
... ... ... (1)
v is the fraction of nonhuman capital devoted to productive
activities and u is the labour participation rate. Since the labour
force is heterogeneous and different people contribute to production in
different degrees based on their education and skills, the measure of
human capital gives a larger weight to those people who are more
productive. To capture this phenomenon the proposed measure of the
average stock of human capital in an economy is the quality-adjusted sum
of the labour of its citizens
[[bar.H].sub.ijt] [integral] [integral] [[theta].sub.ij] [(t, s,
a)[[eta].sub.ij] (t, s, a) da ds ... ... ... ... ... ... (2)
[where] [[eta].sub.ij](t, s, a) = [N.sub.ij](t, s, a)/[N.sub.ij](t)
indicates the proportion of individuals in sector i, and region j with
"s" years of schooling, and "a" years of age, and
[[theta].sub.t[psi]] (t. s. a) is an efficiency parameter, indicating
the contribution of each individual to the stock of human capital. The
real challenge is to determine an adequate measure of this efficiency
parameter. To determine the nature of the efficiency parameter, the
authors assume that individuals acquire human capital through the
combination of some aggregate inputs, such as the stock of physical and
human capital devoted to education, and their own time and skills. Since
the human and physical content of education may vary across economies
and over time, a given number of years of schooling may reflect
different amounts of human capital. The authors' intuition is that
the quality of an individual's human capital is related to the wage
rate received in the marketplace. If his/her education is particularly
useful, the market will reward him/her with a higher wage.
The authors also assume that the stock of human capital of an
individual with no schooling is identical always and everywhere. This
assumption does not imply, however, that the productivity of zero
schooling individuals is identical always and everywhere. Zero-schooling
individuals' income will vary according to an economy's
aggregate stock of physical and human capital as well as due to other
inputs. This assumption is used to define a numeraire that enables the
authors to express the human capital index in a unit that is homogenous across space and time. According to the authors, since any amount of
schooling introduces intertemporal and interregional differences in an
individual's level of skills, the only sensible numeraire is the
zero-schooling worker.
Under the assumption that a worker's marginal product is equal
to his wage, the human capital of a worker with "s" years of
schooling and "a" years of age can be inferred from the wage
ratio:
[[theta].sub.ij](t, s, a) = [w.sub.j] ([t.sub.0], s, a)
[w.sub.j](t, 0, [a.sub.0]) ... ... ... ... ... ... (3)
wj (t, 0, [a.sub.0]) = wage rate of a person with zero year of
schooling and 10-14 years of age.
wj (t.s,a) = wage rate of a person with s years of schooling and
age between 10-70 years.
The worker with zero schooling and 10-14 years of age is used as a
numeraire to allow the human capital index to be expressed in a unit
that is homogenous across "space and time". A major limitation
of the above efficiency measure, however, is that wages may change for
reasons other than changes in human capital.
If value of [theta] from (3) is substituted in (2) than the average
stock of human capital in a given economy is measured as:
[[bar.H].sub.ijt] = [integral] [integral] [W.sub.ij](t, s,
a)/[W.sub.ij](t, 0, [a.sub.0]) [[eta].sub.ij](t, s, a) da ds ... ... ...
... ... ... (4)
The above equation is similar to the Equation (ii), however the
only difference is the replacement of [theta] with relative wage rates.
The wage rate of a zero-skilled worker is estimated by taking the
exponential of the constant term from a Mincer wage regression.
Similarly, respective wage rates of other workers are estimated by
taking the exponential of the sum of the constant term and other
coefficients from a Mincer wage regression after multiplying with the
respective values of the variables.
Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin's (1997) measure of human capital
has the advantage of capturing the variation in quality and relevance of
schooling across regions and over time. This approach nets out the
effect of aggregate physical capital on labour income by dividing an
individual's wage rate by the wage of a zero-schooling worker.
Moreover, this approach allows the elasticity of substitution across
workers to vary. However, this measure also has some drawbacks. First,
zero-schooling individuals are assumed to be identical across regions
and over time and assume to be perfect substitutes for the remaining
workers in the labour force. Second, wages may vary for reasons other
than changes in the marginal value of human capital. For instance,
fiscal or monetary shocks may be the cause of changes in relative wages,
which are, although unrelated, interpreted as changes in the marginal
value of human capital.
As the objective of this paper is to better understand the unequal
formation of human capital in the four provinces in the context of their
consequences for regional development, there is a need to duly address
quality issues.
3. METHODOLOGY AND ESTIMATION
We estimate the accumulated human capital by improvising the
labour-income based methodology described in the section above. To take
into account provincial differences, and discrete data on education and
schooling, equation (1) is modified as follows:
[H.sub.ijt] = [SIGMA] [SIGMA] [W.sub.ij] ([t.sub.0], s,
a)/[W.sub.ij]([t.sub.0], 0, [a.sub.0]) [[eta].sub.ij](t, s, a) l da ds
... ... ... ... ... ... (5)
where,
H = Accumulated stock of human capital i = Provinces (i - Punjab; i
= 2 Sind; i = 3 NWFP; i = 4 Baluchistan) j = Sectors (j = 1 Agriculture;
j = 2 Industry;. j = 3 Services) t = Time Period (Years) [t.sub.0] =
Year of Estimation of relative wages (1990-91) s = Years of schooling
a=Age in years [a.sub.0] = Age group 10-14 years W = Wage Rates [eta] =
Proportion of employed labour force in province i with s year of
schooling L = Total employed labour force.
The estimation is divided into three steps: (i) computation of the
relative wage rates, a proxy for productivity, (ii) estimation of the
proportion of employed labour force in each sector j, by province i,
according to level of education, and age, (iii) multiplication of
productivity with total employed labour force, by education level, and
age, in each respective sector, by province.
3.1. Computation of Wage Rates
The computation of wage rates itself requires two distinct steps:
(i) Estimation of the Mincer Wage Equation which is simply the
regression of the natural log of wages on education level and experience
(ii) the regression results are used to compute relative wages. During
1990, relative wages vary across regions and over time due to change in
technology, it is reasonable to use variable weights in different
decades for each respective province. Therefore relative wages are
computed for the fiscal years 1990-91 and 1999-2000.
3.1.1. Estimation of the Mincer Wage Equation
Standard Mincerian earnings function uses years of schooling as a
measure of educational attainment. This crude measure will now be
complemented with a more detailed investigation by looking at returns to
specific degrees. Assuming that the degree gained is more important than
actual years spent at school, the linearity assumption implicit in the
years of schooling specification is abandoned. Similarly, there is no
information about actual work experience or years of work interruption available in the Labour Force Surveys. Therefore, we take age as a proxy
for experience, rather than potential experience (age minus years of
schooling minus six) in the regression analysis. Finally, ordinary least
squares method is applied to the following earnings function:
ln w = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] (age) + [[beta].sub.2]
([age).sup.2] + [[beta].sub.3] (P) + [[beta].sub.4](Mi) + [[beta].sub.5
](Ma) + [[beta].sub.6] (In) + [[beta].sub.7] (Gr) + [[beta].sub.8] (PG)
+ [[beta].sub.9] (Ot) + u ... ... ... ... ... ... (6)
where, w is monthly wages, and P, Mi, Ma, In, Gr, and Pg are dummy variables indicating completion of Primary, Middle, Matric,
Intermediate, Graduation and Post Graduation levels of education of the
employed labour force respectively, while Ot indicates other categories
of professional education and non-professional education.
3.1.2. Data
The data sets used in the estimation of the Mincer wage equations
is drawn from the Labour Force Survey (LFS) 1990-91, collected by the
Federal Bureau of Statistics (FBS). The LFS data provides detailed
socio-economic information about more than 111,000 individuals. The
information on labour market activities is provided for individuals of
10 years of age and above. To adjust for seasonal variations, the data
collection is spread over all the years. The survey collects
comprehensive information on various activities of workers. The
information about age, literacy, education, and earnings is particularly
important for this study.
Since 1965, the Labour Force Surveys are the major source of
information on labour market statistics in Pakistan. Province-wise
labour market statistics are available since 1974-75 and micro data sets
are available since 1990-91. A comparison of LFS with other data sources
shows the superiority of LFS because of greater internal and external
consistencies [Zeeuw (1996)]. Since 1990s, the questionnaire of the LFS
has been revised twice and a number of other changes are made to improve
the quality of data collection as well as coverage of different
sub-groups. The first available micro data set of the Labour Force
Survey 1990-91 is used in the estimation of the Mincer Wage Equation.
3.1.3. Sample Selection Issues
The aim of the estimating the Mincer Wage Equation is to compute
the relative wage rates; therefore, we restricted our sample to only
regular wage and salaried workers of 10 to 70 years of age, including
both male and female. (3) The majority of these individuals are fulltime
employees who work more than 35 hours per week. The data on earnings
include only cash payments; other benefits such as bonuses are not
included in these earnings.
Table 1 provides summary statistics for the employed labour force
used in the wage rate regression by industrial category, and by
province. In 1990-91 the final sample of regular salaried workers
comprised of 15,516, 8,055, 5,707 and 2,992 individuals in Punjab,
Sindh, NWFP and Balochistan respectively.
The summary statistics provided in Table 2 reveals that the average
wage in Sindh is 24 percent, 21 percent and 9 percent higher than the
average wage in Punjab, NWFP and Balochistan respectively.
3.1.4. Rate of Returns on Education (4)
When estimating the Mincerian Wage Equation "illiterate"
is taken as the reference category for education levels. Similarly, for
the sectoral analysis, agriculture is selected as the reference sector.
This selection enables us to use wage of the illiterate agrarian worker
as the numeraire when computing the relative wage rates. The best-fit
estimation results for the respective Mincerian Wage Equations for
1990-91, for all four provinces, are presented in Table 3. All the
results are in line with the human capital theory.
The age variable (a proxy for experience) and its squared both are
significant, and express a concave relationship between wage and
experience (the linear term is positive and the quadratic term is
negative) in all four provinces.
The coefficients of all education dummies are positive and
significant, which reflects that having no schooling can put a serious
strain on career advancement. However, as expected, return to higher
academic degrees rises unequivocally with higher level of education in
all four provinces. Comparison of province-wise estimates of returns to
education level for 1990-91 portrays a picture of regional disparity.
For instance, return to primary education is highest in Punjab and
lowest in Sindh. Possible reasons for variation in returns to education
may be the variation in labour supply as well as employment
opportunities in both public and private sectors in a province. (5)
3.1.5. Computation of the Relative Productivity
The goal of this section is to provide estimates of productivity
with explicit statements of underlying assumptions used in the
computation. An important question in this regard is: what is the
initial stock of human capital in each province? We work on the
assumption that the zero schooling person is the same, always and
everywhere, as assumed by Mulligan and Martin (1995). The assumption
does not imply that zero schooling people will earn the same income
always and everywhere. Their productivity will differ across regions
because the aggregate stock of physical and human capital, and other
inputs will differ across the regions. The main reason for using this
assumption is that we need a numeraire to express the human capital
index in a unit, which is homogenous across space and time. People with
any positive amount of schooling will tend to introduce interregional
and intertemporal differences in the level of schooling, simply because
the resources devoted to education, and the human capital of the
teachers, will differ across economies. Therefore, people with any
positive amount of schooling cannot be used as numeraire. Following the
same argument and in the absence of any technological revolution in the
agriculture sector, which might affect the productivity of the agrarian
illiterate labourer, we use the illiterate agrarian labourer as
numeraire. In other words, the illiterate agrarian labourer in all
provinces during 1990-91 has the same productivity, which is one.
Based on the above discussion, a province-wise productivity measure
for various levels of education is computed by using relative wages:
[[theta].sub.ij](t,s,a) =
[w.sub.j]([t.sub.o]s,a)/[w.sub.j]([t.sub.0],0,[a.sub.0]) ... ... ... ...
... ... (7)
In other words, the average worker in each province with s years of
schooling at time t is assumed to be [theta](t. s. a) times more
productive than a worker with zero years of schooling and 10-14 years of
age group. This productivity measure [theta](t, s. a) is computed for
each province during 1990-91.
From the estimates of the mincer wage equations we compute average
monthly earnings for each schooling group, for each province, in the
three respective sectors, for 1990-91. Average monthly earnings are
estimated by dividing the civilian labour force, aged 10-70 years into
eight schooling categories, starting from no schooling to professional
education. However, nursery school and kindergarten are not counted as
educational levels, therefore, an individual qualifies for the no
schooling category if he attended nursery school or kindergarten, or
even if he attended, but did not complete primary education. Similarly,
for other levels only those workers have been included that have
completed the particular level of education. The details of education
levels are as follows:
(0) No schooling (1) Primary (completed 5 years of schooling) (2)
Middle (completed 8 years of schooling) (3) Matric (completed 10 years
of schooling) (4) Intermediate (completed 12 years of schooling) (5)
Graduate (completed 14 years of schooling) (6) Post Graduate (completed
16 years of schooling) (7) Professional (possessing a professional
degree (6))
As in the case of education levels, we also computed relative wage
rates for twelve age groups, beginning from 10-14 and ending at 65-69
years. However, for comparison, only the estimated relative wage rates
for the age group 25-29, during 1990-91, in three sectors, for four
provinces, as a ratio of the reference group (employed inexperienced illiterate agrarian labour) are presented in Table 4. (7)
As expected, education level plays a significant role in wage
determination, in all sectors, and regions. In Punjab the relative wage
rate for postgraduates is more than three times the relative wage rate
of the illiterate workers of the same age group, in each sector. In
fact, it is nearly eight times the wage rate of the agrarian illiterate
labourer of age group 10-14 years.
However, return on professional education is less than post
graduation, which may be because of the wider coverage of the
professional education category; professional education also includes
degrees based on only three years of education after matric. Another
noticeable point with respect to the return on education is the higher
growth in relative wages after intermediate; this indicates the
non-linearity in returns to completed years of schooling.
Similarly, in Sindh the relative return to education increased with
the level of education, and the highest jump occurred in the case of
graduation in all sectors, and in both years. During 1990-91, return on
post-graduation was also very high.
As in the case of Sindh and Punjab, relative wage rates
disproportionately increased with the level of education in NWFP. The
highest jump occurred in relative wage rates between graduation and
post-graduation. In 1990-91, this increase was more than 50 percent, as
compared to no schooling, the relative wage rate for post graduation is
three times higher. In Balochistan also, relative wage rates increase
disproportionately with level of education, and the highest increase in
the relative wage rate is from intermediate to graduation.
3.2 Estimation of Proportion of the Employed Labour Force
For the period, prior to 1990-91, in the absence of micro-data,
estimation of employed labour force by education levels, age and
sectors, in each province is a challenge. The labour force surveys did
not publish specific tables containing all the desired information.
Therefore, the estimation of the employed labour force by education
level, age, and sector, for each respective province, involves three
steps: (i) sector-wise proportion of employed labour force by education
levels is computed using tables "Percentage distribution of
employed persons of 10 years age and above by major industry Divisions
and major occupation groups" and "Percentage distribution of
employed persons of 10 years age and above by Literacy and Level of
Education and major Occupation Groups" published in respective
Labour Force Surveys; (ii) population of 10 years and above is
categorised into 12 age groups 10-14,15-19, 20-24, 25-29, 30-34, 35-39,
40-44, 45-49, 50-54, 54-59, 60-64, and 65-70 for eight education levels:
no schooling, primary, middle, matric, intermediate, graduate,
post-graduate, and others, for the time period 1982-83 to 1999-2000 by
using the table "Percentage Distribution of Population by Age, Sex,
Literacy and Level of Education"; (iii) the proportion of employed
labour force by sector, education level and age is computed by using the
matrices describes in steps (i) and (ii) (iv) above and finally, these
proportions are multiplied by the total employed labour force to obtain
the number of employed labour force by sector, education level and age
for each province.
Table 5 presents the estimates of overall total labour force
working in three sectors by education level, and by province. The share
of employed labour force with no schooling has declined markedly over
the years, in each province. In Punjab the share has declined from over
70 percent to roughly 56 percent. In Sindh and NWFP it is down to 51
percent and 61 percent respectively in 1999-2000, from around 74 percent
in 1982-83. Moreover, the employed labour force, with education level
matric and intermediate, has grown at a faster pace as compared to the
other educational categories.
3.3. Computation of the Human Capital Index
Finally, sector-wise stock of human capital for each province is
computed by multiplying relative wage rates categorised according to
education level and age with comparable categories of the employed
labour force. This sector-wise stock is aggregated at provincial and
national levels to compute provincial as well as national stock of human
capital. Moreover, to compare the growth of human capital between
provinces, the human capital index is based on the stock of human
capital in 1982-83.
4. TRENDS IN PROVINCIAL/NATIONAL HUMAN CAPITAL
The national and regional human capital stock measures presented in
this paper are in the form of indices. These indices describe the
evolution of Pakistan's human capital stock at both the provincial
and national level over time.
Table VI presents the results of the estimated provincial and
national human capital indices. The national estimates show that
Pakistan's human capital stock almost doubled during 1982-83 to
2003-2004 growing at an annual compound growth rate (ACGR) of 3.3
percent.
Based on the trend in the growth of the human capital index the
analysis may be divided into three periods: (i) 1982-83 to 1989-90 and
(ii) 1990-91 to 1999-2000 (iii) 2001-2004. During the time period
1982-83 to 1989-90, the national human capital index grew at 3.4 percent
per annum, largely driven by higher growth in Punjab (3.3 percent) and
Sindh (4.8 percent).
During the second period of analysis (1991-2000), a slowdown in the
growth of Pakistan's overall stock of human capital is observed.
This is mainly the reflection of slower growth of only 1.5 percent per
annum in Sindh (as compared to 4.8 percent in 1982-90). However,
post-2000 human capital accumulation in Sindh recovered to 6.3 percent
per annum, manifesting in an overall ACGR for the national-level HCI of
4 percent for the last period of analysis 2000-2004. Sindh accounts for
24 percent of the overall HCI, while Punjab contributes 63 percent.
Province-wise disaggregation further shows that growth in Punjab has
consistently hovered around 3.2 percent -3.3 percent per annum. In
contrast, the performance by Sindh, as discussed above, was relatively
erratic, with the 1990s emerging as a very difficult decade. Further,
the remaining 2 provinces, NWFP and Balochistan, post a ACGR of 2.6
percent and 3.4 percent respectively over the 22 years of analysis; but
given the very small base of the two provinces (together they account
for only 13 percent of the overall stock of human capital) their impact
on the overall national HCI is limited.
4.1. Trend in Sectoral HCI
It would be interesting to compare the pattern of human capital in
the different sectors of the economy, as this will in turn provide us an
insight into the causative factors behind the provincial and national
HCI growth patterns. Tables 7, 8, and 9, present the sector-wise HCI at
both the provincial and the national level. Our analysis reveals that
the main driver of growth in HCI, in all provinces, is the services
sector, which grew at a much higher rate compared to the manufacturing
and agricultural sectors. In the provinces of Sindh, and Punjab, human
capital in the services sector more than doubled during the period under
review (see Table 7).
4.1.1. Trend in HCI--Services
In this section we again break our analysis of HCI--services into
the three time periods: (i) 1982-83 to 1989-90 and (ii) 1990-91 to
1999-2000, and (iii) 2000-2004. Table VII shows that during 1982-83 to
1989-90, the province of Sindh took the lead in terms of growth in the
HCI-services sector, which almost doubled in this period growing at an
annual compounded growth rate of 9.8 percent. In comparison,
HCI-services for Punjab, NWFP and Balochistan, grew by 6 percent, 3.8
percent and minus 0.9 percent, respectively, for the same time period.
However, in the decade of the 1990s, we find a reversal in the hierarchy
vis-a-vis human capital growth in the services sector, with Sindh losing
its steam and falling behind the other three provinces. The highest
increase in HCI-services, in the 1990s, was observed in Balochistan,
followed by NWFP, and Punjab. Post 1999, Sindh regained its growth
momentum, and a convergence in the respective provincial growth
trajectories is observed.
4.1.2. Trend in HCI--Manufacturing
With respect to growth in HCI-manufacturing, a similar pattern as
in the case of services is observed. During the first period of our
analysis i.e. 1982-83 to 1989-90 growth is led by Sindh;
HCI-manufacturing grew at an annual compound growth rate of 6.7 percent,
followed by Punjab, which demonstrated a moderate growth of 1.5 percent
during the same period. In comparison, both Balochistan and NWFP, show a
de-accumulation in their human capital in the manufacturing sector, in
the time period 1982-83 to 1989-90. In comparison, during the second
period of analysis, 1990-91 to 1999-00, we observe NWFP
HCI-manufacturing making a leap jump from negative 0.5 percent growth on
average per annum, in 1982-83 to 1989-90, to almost 5 percent CAGR in
the 1990s, while Punjab, Sindh and Balochistan grew by 3, 0.3 and minus
3 percent respectively (see Table 8). In 2000-2004, Sindh made a
comeback, and posted an annual average growth rate of 10.9 percent,
while Punjab grew at 4.9 percent, NWFP at 3.2 percent, and Balochistan
at 20.6 percent, which appears to be an aberration; moreover, given
Balochistan's small base, contributing only 1 percent toward the
national-level manufacturing sector HCI, this result is not very
meaningful).
4.1.3. Trend in HCI--Agriculture
Growth in agriculture is mainly led by Punjab, which is not
surprising given the province's large agrarian base. Though both
NWFP and Balochistan show reasonable overall growth in HCI-Agriculture,
in terms of actual contribution toward the national HCI, given the
narrow base of the agriculture sector in the two provinces, this growth
is not meaningful. Sindh, on the other hand, showed a lackluster performance in HCI-agriculture in the time-period 1983-2000, however,
annual average growth picked up in 2000.
5. CONCLUSION
This paper reviews the trend in the growth of human capital in the
provinces of Pakistan by estimating sector-wise human capital indices.
This measure of human capital stock is based on the completion of
education levels, as well as on work experience. This is the first
attempt to compute a measure of human capital by province, and by
sector, and may fall short of an ideal measure. Nonetheless, this
measure of HCI builds upon and improves existing national-level
measures, and hopefully will attract attention and stimulate future
efforts for the development of what may become an important instrument
for the understanding of regional economic performance. In the near
term, this measure will be used in various regional/national
applications.
To consolidate, the province-wise sectoral analysis provides a
better insight into the overall trend demonstrated by the aggregate
national-level human capital index. In the 1980s Sindh and Punjab were
the leaders in terms of human capital growth, which was largely driven
by human capital growth in the manufacturing and services sectors.
However, with the passage of time, in the decade of the 1990s, we
observe a loss of momentum in terms of human capital development in
Sindh. Punjab, NWFP and even Balochistan grew at a faster pace than
Sindh in the 1990s. But, by 2000, Sindh had regained its original
trajectory, posting a CAGR of 6.3 percent in the last phase of the
analysis, 2000-2004.
REFERENCES
Alan, Krueger B. and Mikael Lindahl (2001) Education for Growth:
Why and for Whom. Journal of Economic Literature 39:4, 1101-1136.
Ashenfelter, Orley C. and Layard Richard (1986) Handbook of Labor
Economics. North-Holland: Elsevier Science Publishers, Vol. I & II.
Barro, Robert J. and Jong Wha Lee (1996) International Measures of
Schooling Years and Schooling Quality. American Economic Review 86:2,
218-223.
Becker, Gary S. (1993) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical
Analysis with Special Reference to Education. University of Chicago
Press, Third Edition.
Cohen, Daniel and Marcelo Soto (2001) Growth And Human Capital:
Good Data, Good Results. OECD. (Technical Papers No. 179.)
http://www.oecd.org/dev/publication/tp1a.htm
de-Zeeuw, Maarten (1996) The Household Integrated Economic Survey
of Pakistan 1990-91: Internal and External Consistency. The Pakistan
Development Review 35:1, 71-84.
Khan, Shahrukh R. and Mohammad Irfan (1985) Rate of Returns to
Education and Determinants of Earnings in Pakistan. The Pakistan
Development Review 24:3&4, 471-680.
Koman, Reinhard and Dalia Marin (1997) Human Capital and
Macroeconomic Growth: Austria and Germany, 1960-1992. (NBER Working
Paper No. 1551.)
Laroche, Mireille and Marcel Merette (2000) Measuring Human Capital
in Canada. Canada: University of Ottawa.
Linda L. Moeller (2002) On the Estimation of Classical Human
Capital Wage Equations with Two Independent Sources of Data on Actual
Work Experience, U.S. Department of Labour, Bureau of Labor Statistics.
(Working Paper 362.)
Machlup, Fritz (1982) Issues in the Theory of Human Capital:
Education as Investment. The Pakistan Development Review 21:1, 1-18.
Mulligan, Casey B. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1995) Measuring
Aggregate Human Capital. (NBER Working Paper No. 1149.)
Mulligan, Casey B. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1997) A
Labour-income-based Measure of the Value of Human Capital: An
Application to the States of the United States. Japan and the World
Economy 9:2, 159-1991.
Nasir, Zafar M. (1998) Determinants of Personal Earnings in
Pakistan: Findings from the Labour Force Survey 1993-94. The Pakistan
Development Review 37:3, 251-274.
Nehru, Vikram, Eric Swanson, and Ashutosh Dubey (1995) A New
Database on Human Capital Stock in Developing and Industrial Countries:
Sources, Methodology and Results. Journal of Development Economics 46:2,
379-401.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Years) Labour Force Survey.
Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pasha, H. A., Aynul Hasan, et al. (1996) Integrated Social-sector
Macroeconometric Model for Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review
35:4, 567-79.
Samuel, Bowles, Herbert Gintis, and Melissa Osborne (2001) The
Determinants of Earnings: A Behavioural Approach. Journal of Economic
Literature 39:4, 1137-1176.
Shabbir, Tayyeb (1994) Mincerian Earnings Function for Pakistan.
The Pakistan Development Review 33:4, 1-18.
Shabbir, Tayyeb and Alia H. Khan (1991) Mincerian Earnings Function
for Pakistan: A Regional Analysis. Pakistan Economic and Social Review
24, 99-111.
Sunde, U. (2001) Human Capital Accumulation, Education and Earnings
Inequality. (IZA Discussion Paper No. 310.)
Swanda, Y. (1997) Income Risks, Gender and Human Capital Investment
in Rural Pakistan. Department of Economics Stanford University,
Stanford. July 1997. (Mimeographed.)
Muhammad Sabir <muhammadsabinkhan@yahoo.com> and Zehra Aflab
<zafiab01@yahoo.com> arc, respectively, National Expert, GRB1 and
Senior Economist, SPDC, Karachi, and Research Fellow, PIDE, Islamabad.
Authors' Note: The authors gratefully acknowlcdge comments and
suggestions on an earlier draft of this paper from Hafiz A. Pasha,
Director, Regional Bureau for Asia and Pacific. UNDP, Andrew Sharp,
Executive Director, CSLS, Ottawa, and Shagil Ahmed, former Acting
Managing Director, SPDC, Karachi. We also acknowledge the comments
received from Tony Venables, Professor of International Economics London
School of Economics and Political Science, UK, and Arvind Virmani,
ICRIER, India, at the 22nd Annual General Meeting and Conference of the
Pakistan Society of Development Economists, 19th-22nd December, 2006,
Lahore.
(1) In this paper formal education is defined as primary and above.
(2) An aggregated measure of the Human Capital Index was computed
by SPDC, Karachi (see the Integrated, Social Policy Macro Model).
(3) There is convincing evidence available on gender differentials
and generally separate samples of males and females are selected for
analysis. However, in Pakistan, female participation rate is very low,
which may create a problem with respect to degrees of freedom in case of
separate sample estimation for males and females by sector and by
province.
(4) The individual Mincerian wage equations were estimated for each
province to compute the stock of human capital for each respective
province. The provincial HCI than aggregated to compute the stock of
human capital at the national level.
(5) The respective mincerian wage equations formed an input in the
computation of the HCI, and therefore the coefficients are not discussed
in detail to avoid de-trackting from the orginal focus of the paper,
which is to analyze the pattern in human capital accumulation over the
last twenty years.
(6) Generally, Professional degrees require 4 or 5 years of
schooling after Intermediate.
(7) See age-wise detail table in Annex.
Table 1
Sample Size of Salaried Workers in LFS 1990-91
Agriculture Manufacturing Services Total
1990-91
Punjab 5,864 2,364 7,288 15,516
Sindh 2,782 1,224 4,049 8,055
NWFP 2,154 463 3,090 5,707
Balochistan 1,317 134 1,541 2,992
Total 12,117 4,185 15,968 32,270
Source: Authors Estimates Based on LFS 1990-91.
Table 2
Average Monthly Wages in 1990-91
Agriculture Manufacturing Services Total
1990-91
Punjab 1,063 1,325 1,646 1,547
Sindh 1,367 1,995 1,963 1,926
NWFP 1,234 1,386 1,643 1,592
Balochistan 1,549 1,522 1,799 1,765
1,277 1,608 1,757 1,698
Source: Authors Estimates Based on LFS 1990-91.
Table 3
Province-wise Estimates of the Mincer Wage Equations for 1990-91
Punjab Sindh NWFP Balochistan
Constant 5.7929 5.8922 5.9696 5.9008
0.0694 0.1159 0.1057 0.3121
Age 0.0408 0.0521 0.0479 0.0639
(Agriculture) 0.0058 0.0074 0.0078 0.0181
Age 0.0557 0.0684 0.0491 0.1516
(Manufacturing) 0.0047 0.0071 0.0076 0.0444
Age 0.0497 0.0344 0.0476 0.0319
(Services) 0.0042 0.0051 0.0061 0.0070
(Age) (2) -0.0004 -0.0005 -0.0006 -0.0007
(Agriculture) 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002
(Age) (2) -0.0006 -0.0008 -0.0005 -0.0022
(Manufacturing) 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0007
(Age) (2) -0.0005 -0.0003 -0.0005 -0.0003
(Services) 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001
Manufacturing -- -- -- -1.2342
0.7067
Services -- 0.4219 -- 0.6468
0.1453 0.3339
Primary 0.1511 0.0619 0.1457 0.1127
0.0319 0.0296 0.0500 0.0466
Middle 0.2890 0.2385 0.3262 0.1513
0.0318 0.0330 0.0495 0.0476
Matric 0.4427 0.2736 0.4038 0.2277
0.0265 0.0288 0.0369 0.0338
Intermediate 0.6505 0.4202 0.5037 0.3765
0.0379 0.0316 0.0492 0.0464
Graduate 0.9101 0.6711 0.7134 0.6792
0.0432 0.0318 0.0558 0.0701
Post Graduate 1.1833 0.9128 1.1264 0.8539
0.0537 0.0500 0.0657 0.0883
Others 1.1546 1.0412 1.0939 0.9410
0.0580 0.0450 0.0882 0.0683
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.3629 0.3887 0.3393 0.3670
Table 4 Province-wise Estimates of Relative Productivity - 1990-91
Level of Education Agriculture Manufacturing Other Sectors
Punjab
No Schooling 1.4 1.9 1.7
Primary 1.7 2.2 2.0
Middle 1.9 2.5 2.3
Matric 2.2 2.9 2.7
Intermediate 2.8 3.6 3.3
Graduate 3.6 4.7 4.3
Post Graduate 4.7 6.2 5.6
Professional 4.6 6.0 5.5
Sindh
No Schooling 1.6 2.1 1.8
Primary 1.7 2.3 1.9
Middle 2.0 2.7 2.3
Matric 2.1 2.8 2.4
Intermediate 2.4 3.2 2.7
Graduate 3.1 4.1 3.5
Post Graduate 4.0 5.3 4.5
Professional 4.5 6.0 5.1
NWFP
No Schooling 1.4 1.6 1.5
Primary 1.6 1.8 1.7
Middle 1.9 2.2 2.1
Matric 2.1 2.4 2.3
Intermediate 2.3 2.6 2.5
Graduate 2.9 3.2 3.1
Post Graduate 4.3 4.9 4.6
Professional 4.2 4.7 4.5
Balochistan
No Schooling 1.7 1.8 1.9
Primary 2.0 2.1 2.1
Middle 2.0 2.1 2.2
Matric 2.2 2.3 2.3
Intermediate 2.5 2.7 2.7
Graduate 3.4 3.6 3.6
Post Graduate 4.1 4.3 4.3
Professional 4.5 4.7 4.7
Note: Estimates are only for age group 25-29 years.
See Annex for all age groups.
Table 5
Educational Attainment of Employed Labour Force (in 000)
No
Schooling Primary Middle Matric
Punjab
1982-83 11,288 1,973 1,362 1,150
1990-91 12.142 2,488 1,582 1,586
1999-2000 13,315 3,623 2,598 2,576
Sindh
1982-83 4,160 780 433 171
1990-91 3,964 1,117 505 582
1999-2000 3,805 1,074 579 797
NWFP
1982-83 2,280 310 196 230
1990-91 2,303 358 216 252
1999-2000 2,442 526 299 414
Balochistan
1982-83 791 56 57 64
1990-91 853 58 38 45
1999-2000 991 76 78 87
Intermediate Graduate Post-Graduate Professional
Punjab
1982-83 65 168 69 44
1990-91 446 212 76 88
1999-2000 767 410 202 99
Sindh
1982-83 23 23 23 23
1990-91 317 251 70 91
1999-2000 475 473 142 96
NWFP
1982-83 8 44 24 3
1990-91 78 45 19 15
1999-2000 148 92 50 19
Balochistan
1982-83 1 14 4 6
1990-91 15 5 3 5
1999-2000 27 22 13 6
Table 6
Human Capital Index
Punjab Sindh NWFP Balochistan Pakistan
1982-83 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
1983-84 104.0 105.2 102.1 102.8 104.0
1984-85 108.1 110.4 104.1 105.5 108.1
1985-86 107.2 110.3 104.0 101.5 107.4
1986-87 115.3 119.9 114.8 111.8 116.1
1987-88 115.5 121.7 112.7 112.7 116.5
1988-89 120.2 129.7 114.0 111.4 121.4
1989-90 125.1 138.5 115.5 110.3 126.6
1990-91 130.3 148.2 117.1 109.3 132.2
1991-92 138.2 149.0 116.4 122.7 137.8
1992-93 142.5 162.7 125.2 120.5 144.5
1993-94 145.9 157.2 132.9 127.1 146.4
1994-95 151.9 161.8 143.2 118.5 151.9
1995-96 157.2 165.5 141.3 121.9 156.0
1996-97 162.5 169.3 139.4 125.3 160.2
1997-98 166.0 173.8 149.8 144.8 165.3
1998-99 169.7 171.6 149.4 146.2 167.1
1999-00 173.5 169.4 148.9 147.7 169.0
2000-01 177.9 186.1 156.0 162.7 176.9
2001-02 182.2 202.8 163.0 177.8 184.8
2002-03 188.2 213.3 167.3 189.3 191.9
2003-04 194.2 223.9 171.7 200.8 198.9
Annual Cumulative Growth Rate
1983-1990 3.3% 4.8% 2.1% 1.4% 3.4%
1991-2000 3.2% 1.5% 2.7% 3.4% 2.8%
2000-2004 3.0% 6.3% 3.2% 7.3% 4.0%
1983-2004 3.2% 3.9% 2.6% 3.4% 3.3%
Regional Distribution of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 63% 24% 9% 4% 100%
Table 7
Human Capital Index: Services
Punjab Sindh NWFP
1982-83 100.0 100.0 100.0
1983-84 114.3 119.6 100.5
1984-85 128.5 139.3 100.9
1985-86 116.2 131.7 96.4
1986-87 135.7 155.4 125.3
1987-88 133.1 162.4 119.9
1988-89 141.4 176.7 124.8
1989-90 150.3 192.2 129.8
1990-91 159.7 209.0 135.1
1991-92 166.9 211.4 124.0
1992-93 180.8 241.4 149.5
1993-94 178.6 236.4 145.9
1994-95 197.6 241.9 175.5
1995-96 209.6 252.8 177.2
1996-97 221.7 263.8 179.0
1997-98 218.3 261.6 182.3
1998-99 214.6 253.1 182.3
1999-00 211.0 244.6 182.2
2000-01 225.0 280.2 194.2
2001-02 239.0 315.7 206.2
2002-03 245.2 325.9 219.7
2003-04 251.4 336.1 233.1
Annual Cumulative
Growth Rate
1983-1990 6.0% 9.8% 3.8%
1991-2000 3.1% 1.8% 3.4%
2000-2004 3.8% 6.3% 6.3%
1983-2004 4.5% 5.9% 4.1%
Regional Distribution
of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 60% 26% 10%
Balochistan Pakistan
1982-83 100.0 100.0
1983-84 100.4 113.1
1984-85 100.8 126.2
1985-86 72.8 115.1
1986-87 103.3 137.2
1987-88 90.3 135.8
1988-89 92.2 144.7
1989-90 94.1 154.3
1990-91 96.0 164.4
1991-92 110.7 168.8
1992-93 108.9 186.8
1993-94 110.7 184.4
1994-95 122.1 200.9
1995-96 127.5 211.2
1996-97 133.0 221.5
1997-98 145.1 219.9
1998-99 152.9 216.2
1999-00 160.8 212.5
2000-01 181.3 231.3
2001-02 201.9 250.0
2002-03 225.4 258.8
2003-04 249.0 267.6
Annual Cumulative
Growth Rate
1983-1990 -0.9% 6.4%
1991-2000 5.9% 2.9%
2000-2004 11.1% 5.0%
1983-2004 4.4% 4.8%
Regional Distribution
of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 3% 100%
Table 8
Human Capital Index: Manufacturing
Punjab Sindh NWFP
1982-83 100.0 100.0 100.0
1983-84 108.0 104.5 106.4
1984-85 115.9 109.0 112.8
1985-86 105.4 106.8 90.1
1986-87 119.0 110.4 104.0
1987-88 103.1 117.6 109.2
1988-89 107.1 136.1 102.8
1989-90 111.2 157.5 96.7
1990-91 115.5 182.3 91.0
1991-92 128.7 175.8 90.4
1992-93 114.7 170.8 84.8
1993-94 113.6 148.0 85.2
1994-95 126.3 153.4 75.3
1995-96 130.8 168.4 91.6
1996-97 135.2 183.4 107.9
1997-98 129.8 164.3 121.2
1998-99 140.3 175.4 129.3
1999-00 150.7 186.6 137.4
2000-01 171.6 208.0 152.4
2001-02 192.5 229.4 167.4
2002-03 195.4 256.6 167.6
2003-04 198.3 283.8 167.7
Annual Cumulative
Growth Rate
1983-1990 1.5% 6.7% -0.5%
1991-2000 3.0% 0.3% 4.7%
2000 ?004 4.9% 10.9% 3.2%
1983-2004 3.3% 5.1% 2.5%
Regional Distribution
of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 68% 27% 5%
Balochistan Pakistan
1982-83 100.0 100.0
1983-84 121.2 107.2
1984-85 142.4 114.4
1985-86 104.9 104.8
1986-87 122.5 116.2
1987-88 70.2 106.5
1988-89 78.4 113.1
1989-90 87.6 130.6
1990-91 97.8 129.0
1991-92 116.2 136.9
1992-93 114.9 125.5
1993-94 88.7 119.4
1994-95 83.7 129.0
1995-96 74.8 136.4
1996-97 65.9 143.8
1997-98 72.5 136.6
1998-99 72.5 147.0
1999-00 72.5 157.3
2000-O1 122.4 178.3
2001-02 172.3 199.2
2002-03 193.5 207.5
2003-04 214.7 215.9
Annual Cumulative
Growth Rate
1983-1990 -1.9% 2.7%
1991-2000 -3.3% 2.2%
2000 ?004 20.6% 6.6%
1983-2004 3.7% 3.7%
Regional Distribution
of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 1% 100%
Table 9
Human Capital Index: Agriculture
Punjab Sindh NWFP
1982-83 100.0 100.0 100.0
1983-84 94.5 94.8 102.8
1984-85 89.0 89.6 105.5
1985-86 100.5 95.8 113.4
1986-87 97.5 96.7 107.1
1987-88 105.6 93.2 106.6
1988-89 107.7 93.5 106.0
1989-90 109.7 93.8 105.5
1990-91 111.8 94.1 105.0
1991-92 118.5 95.8 114.0
1992-93 121.4 103.0 109.9
1993-94 130.8 102.0 129.3
1994-95 123.9 105.7 125.5
1995-96 124.1 101.0 116.8
1996-97 124.3 96.3 108.2
1997-98 136.5 112.4 124.7
1998-99 143.8 111.0 122.4
1999-00 151.2 109.6 120.1
2000-01 142.1 111.3 121.1
2001-02 133.1 112.9 122.1
2002-03 140.0 118.9 118.7
2003-04 146.8 124.9 115.4
Annual Cumulative
Growth Rate
1983-1990 1.3% -0.9% 0.8%
1991-2000 3.4% 1.7% 1.5%
2000-2004 1.1% 3.9% -1.6%
1983-2004 l.8% 1.1% 0.7%
Regional Distribution
of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 64% 21% 10%
Balochistan Pakistan
1982-83 100.0 100.0
1983-84 103.7 95.8
1984-85 107.5 91.6
1985-86 126.3 101.9
1986-87 118.6 99.2
1987-88 134.6 104.1
1988-89 130.1 105.1
1989-90 125.8 106.2
1990-91 121.6 107.3
1991-92 133.5 113.3
1992-93 130.9 116.3
1993-94 143.5 124.3
1994-95 117.5 119.4
1995-96 119.8 117.6
1996-97 122.0 115.9
1997-98 148.7 130.1
1998-99 144.7 133.8
1999-00 140.7 137.6
2000-01 148.9 132.9
2001-02 157.2 128.2
2002-03 157.7 133.5
2003-04 158.2 138.9
Annual Cumulative
Growth Rate
1983-1990 3.3% 0.9%
1991-2000 1.6% 2.8%
2000-2004 2.0% 1.5%
1983-2004 2.2% 1.6%
Regional Distribution
of Human Capital Stock
Average Share 5% 100%