Economic growth, inflation, and monetary policy in Pakistan: preliminary empirical estimates.
Khalid, Ahmed M.
I. INTRODUCTION
The recent increase in financial market volatility and the
increased surge within developing world to become part of the global
market have posed several challenges for policy-makers in the emerging
markets to decide on a policy regime--monetary or exchange rate--that
suits their needs and could also provide stability to the financial
system. In view of the macroeconomic characteristics of these emerging
economies, the choice of an appropriate policy becomes important to
achieve certain targets such as sizeable domestic and foreign
investment, reduced reliance on external borrowings, fiscal discipline,
etc. These would require both price and exchange rate stability and
country's ability to deal with external shocks to maintain and
achieve sustainable economic growth. Pakistan is no different and until
recently had a history of macroeconomic imbalances with extremely high
foreign (as well as domestic) debt, high budget and current account
deficits, extremely low international reserves, high inflation, high
nominal interest rates and low economic growth. The average economic
growth over 40 years is around 4 percent. The main focus of any policy
has been to achieve a sustainable growth pattern. However, due to a
number of macroeconomic imbalances such as high budget deficits,
extremely high indebtedness, low savings and investment rates, lack of
fiscal discipline, undeveloped financial markets, unstable exchange
rates along with high population growth and huge defence expenditure
made this task almost impossible. Some of these macroeconomic imbalances
contributed to episodes of high inflation and unemployment that the
country experienced during most of the period since independence.
Some important steps to reform the economy were initiated in early
1990s and further efforts were made in early 2000. One of the main
focuses of the later reforms was to achieve price stability through
monetary policy. Highlights of these reforms were providing autonomy to
its central bank (State Bank of Pakistan; SBP), privatisation of
commercial banks, establishing a domestic bond market and launching
Pakistan bonds in the international market and maintaining high foreign
exchange reserves. Autonomy to the SBP was needed to enable the central
bank for the design and implementation of an independent monetary
policy. This is an essential to achieve sustainable growth through price
stability, among other measures. As a result of these measures, the SBP
has been able to bring inflation down to single digits at a time when
the economy has performed strongly. However, high domestic and
international debt and consistently high budget deficits remain central
issues in Pakistan's monetary policy. The current surge in fuel
prices has further aggravated the problem. Given that the SBP is
enjoying a relatively more autonomous environment and the country has
been able to achieve remarkable growth performance since 2003, this is
probably the best time to decide on the future choice of a policy regime
to pursue and achieve long-term and sustainable economic growth.
Recently, some emerging economies decided to switch to an inflation
targeting regime. The successful experience of these emerging economies
may help to draw important lessons for Pakistan. (1) Any policy shift
towards inflation targeting will, however, require an identification of
a causal relationship between inflation and other important
macroeconomic variables. This will also need a correct specification of
inflation model for Pakistan for forecasting purposes. The focus of this
paper, therefore, is to empirically analyse the above two objectives.
The paper is organised in the following manner. The introduction is
followed by a discussion on inflation targeting in the context of some
emerging economies. An empirical model for inflation is specified and
estimated in Section III. Finally, some conclusions are drawn in Section
IV.
II. PRICE STABILITY AND INFLATION TARGETING: EMERGING ECONOMIES,
EXPERIENCE
The debate on the effectiveness of monetary policy places
significant importance of the information mechanism in the economy. An
efficient information mechanism leads to price stability which is
important instrument to achieve a sustainable economic growth. It is for
this very reason that many emerging economies with a history of high and
volatile inflation considered inflation targeting as a choice of
monetary policy. Inflation Targeting (IT) can be defined as a monetary
policy strategy with an explicit objective of achieving and maintaining
price stability. This objective is achieved through an easily
understandable numerical target value of inflation. This requires a
country's central bank to have some flexibility in choosing
monetary policy instruments most appropriate to achieve the target
(inflation target). Price stability does not strictly mean a
'constant price level or zero inflation' but a stable price
level that helps to achieve a target inflation with some tolerance band
over a specified time horizon. Inflation targeting is a forward-looking
policy regime which relies strongly on rational expectations of monetary
policy transmission. The way IT is implemented in emerging economies
suggests the central banks in inflation targeting countries enjoyed some
discretionary power to make adjustment in monetary instruments as and
when needed.
Since the early 1990s, many emerging economies switched to
inflation targeting as their monetary policy regime. These countries had
different economic environments and hence decided to follow a policy
suitable to a specific economic environment. We can split these
countries into three groups. (2) First, countries with relatively strong
financial market fundamentals, a stable macroeconomic environment and
independent central bank moved to inflation targeting with flexible
exchange rates with specific inflation targets to be achieved over a
specified period. The second group of countries did not have the same
environment and switched to inflation targeting with tolerance bands.
The third group of countries had difficulty in maintaining a specific
target due to a less credible central bank and adopted a policy of
'inflation targeting lite'. (3)
New Zealand was the first country to adopt an inflation targeting
regime. Since then many emerging economies in Asia, Latin America and
Europe have switched to inflation targeting as their monetary policy
objective. (4) For instance, the Latin American region experienced the
highest inflation in the world in the 1980s. At regional level,
inflation averaged 145 percent annually. As such price stability became
the most important argument of the monetary policy. Chile (1990), Peru
(1994) and Mexico (1999) used a gradual approach to adopt an inflation
targeting regime while Brazil (1999) used a big-bang approach to do the
same. Among these countries, Chile followed a 'gradual convergence
towards full-fledged inflation targeting (1990-99) when the Central Bank
of Chile adopted a legal, operation and goal independence. The Bank of
Chile also pursued an exchange rate target from 1984-1999. The Central
Bank of Chile used the period 1990-99 to provide price stability and
announced inflation targets (or a range) on an annual basis before it
decided to move to full-fledged inflation targeting and set an
indefinite target range of 2-4 percent in 2001. (5) Mexico used a
somewhat similar approach (1995-2001) but started with a monetary growth
target in 1995 and at the same time used this monetary growth target to
bring down inflation from 52 percent in 1995 to 16 percent in 1997.
Eventually, the Central Bank of Mexico moved towards a gradual
transition to full-fledged inflation targeting in 1998. Contrary to the
example of Chile and Mexico, the Central bank of Brazil used a Big-bang
approach (1999-2001) to move to a full-fledged inflation targeting
regime in July 1999, with a 2 percent tolerance band.
Among the Central European transitional economies, Czech Republic and Poland are the only two countries which have adopted an IT regime.
The Czech Republic adopted an IT regime in January 1998 alter abandoning
the currency peg in May 1997. The Czech central bank adopted a strict
version of IT with a strong commitment to price stability. The Polish IT
regime was introduced at time when Poland was experiencing relatively
high inflation. The Polish central bank decided to target CPI inflation
after moving to a fully floating exchange rate regime.
Columbia presents an example of inflation targeting with
small-scale foreign exchange intervention. Although Columbia implemented
several elements of IT starting as early as 1992, the full-fledged IT
regime was only implemented in 1999Q3. In this way, Columbia
experimented with inflation targeting with exchange rate bands. The
absence of pre-conditions and macroeconomic mismanagement lead to the
deepest and longest recession in this country. Columbia experienced 22
percent peso depreciation between January 1998 and December 1999, just
about the time that Columbia adopted inflation targeting. The central
bank lost about 18 percent of its international reserves during the same
period in an effort to defend the peso. As evident from Table 2, the
country was also going through severe recession with economic growth at
-4.2 percent at the time of adoption to IT. Eventually, Columbia
switched to a floating regime and a full-fledged IT regime in late 1999.
As regards to exchange rate policy, the Central Bank of Columbia
followed a ruled-based foreign exchange market intervention to reduce
volatility in international reserves. However, due to certain internal
and external factors which led to a sharp depreciation of the peso, the
Central Bank of Columbia engaged in large foreign exchange market
intervention in 2003 and again in 2004. (6)
In view of the above discussion and the successful experience of
emerging economies in controlling inflation through a policy of
inflation targeting, it would be interesting to see if Pakistan should
pursue the same policy to achieve a sustainable growth target. Khalid
(2006) provides a comparison of Pakistan's current state of the
economy with other emerging economies (stated above) and argues that
Pakistan's economy is in a much better shape that some of the Latin
American or Central European countries at the time of adoption of an IT
regime. Given this, one can assert that this is probably a good time to
assess the feasibility of inflation targeting in Pakistan. However, any
policy shift towards IT would require the State Bank of Pakistan to
fully understand the path and mechanism under which inflation is
determined in Pakistan. This is needed to achieve two purposes. First,
the policy makers need to have a clear understanding of the movement of
policy variables that may influence prices. Any movement in these
variables would signal the direction and magnitude of movement in prices
level and would require certain policy measures to keep prices stable.
Second, factors that determine inflation would be needed to develop
inflation forecasting model for a credible monetary policy. Both of
these require some empirical estimation. These questions are discussed
in the nest section.
III. INFLATION MODEL FOR PAKISTAN: SOME PRELIMINARY ESTIMATES
There are two main issues to be investigated here. First, what are
the leading indicators of inflation in Pakistan? These leading
indicators would help policy makers to predict future path of inflation
and to devise policies to restrict inflation within a target band.
Granger causality tests are performed to identify leading indicators of
inflation in Pakistan. Second, what are the determinants of inflation in
Pakistan? A well-specified inflation equation can be used as a
forecasting model for inflation which is an important part of IT policy.
The estimation of inflation equation is performed using a
general-to-specific method.
For determining leading indicators of inflation for Pakistan, we
modify Debelle and Lira (1998) to estimate a bivariate VAR suitable for
Pakistan's economic environment. The model estimated is of the
following form.
[DELTA][CPI.sub.t] = [alpha](L)[DELTA][CPI.sub.t-1] +
[beta](L)[DELTA][Y.sub.t-1] + [e.sub.t] [DELTA][Y.sub.t] =
[alpha](L)[DELTA][Y.sub.t-1] + [beta](L) [DELTA][CPI.sub.t-1] +
[u.sub.t] ... (1)
Where;
CPI = price index
Y = set of indicators
Output gap (YGap); budget deficit-GDP ratio (DefGDP); US inflation
(USINF); seigniorage (DM1GDP); log of domestic credit (LDC); the share
price index (SP); the Call Money Rate (CMR); real GDP (RGDP); openness
(ITGDP); exchange rate depreciation against Us dollar ([DELTA]ER); money
depth (M2GDP); and domestic borrowing (DBOR).
It is important to determine the order of integration before
estimating a VAR or identifying any causal relationship among this set
of variables. Standard Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) method is used to
determine the order of integration. Results of unit root tests are
reported in Table 3. These results suggest that CPI, USINF, Def/GDP,
[DELTA]M1GDP, M1/GDP are stationary in levels. However, real GDP (RGDP),
output gap (Ygap), domestic credit (LDC), stock price index (SP),
CMRate, exchange rate (ER), M2/GDP, domestic borrowing (DBOR) and
openness (TT/GDP) are stationary in first difference; I(1). We,
therefore, use these variables in first-difference in the VAR model.
We perform two different types of Granger causality tests to
identify a causal relationship and its directions. First we, use
pair-wise Granger causality tests to focus on each indicator and its
causal relationship with inflation. In this way, we isolate feedback
through other variables. We allow up to four lags. The results are
reported in Table 4. The data suggests that US inflation (USINF),
seigniorage ([DELTA]M1GDP) and openness (TTGDP) do cause inflation. The
results, however, suggest that inflation causes changes in the budget
deficits (DefGDP), domestic credit (LDC), domestic interest rates
(CMRate) and financial depth (M2/GDP). We also found evidence of a
bi-directional causality between outputgap (YGap) and Inflation. These
results indicate that inflation in Pakistan is not influenced by
indigenous factors only. Due to influence of US dollar in domestic
currency valuation, US inflation does affect domestic prices. The
inflationary pressure through the use of seigniorage is not surprising
and is consistent with theoretical prediction. Openness causes inflation
due to negative trade balance and captures the effect of rising import
prices. It is a bit surprising to see a reverse causality between
inflation and budget deficits. However, one possible reason could be the
factors such as; the high level of external debt, debt servicing and
sizeable defence expenditure as well as higher price level puts pressure
on budget deficits. Higher inflation means a lower real cost of
borrowing and thus may lead to increased demand for credit. Higher
inflation also puts upward pressure on domestic interest rates.
Bi-directional causality between inflation and output gap shows central
bank's effort to exert monetary pressure to achieve a higher growth
which they may not achieve due to higher and increasing inflation
(consistent with historical trends in Pakistan till 2002). This may also
suggest some indication of higher sacrifice ratio.
Next, we use a VAR as specified in Equation (1) to identify the
leading indictors allowing some feedback effects as well. The results
are reported in Table 5. These results indicate that output gap(YGDP)
gap and share price index (SP) have a high degree of predictive content
on inflation. Narrow money also has some predictive content. However,
both narrow money and share prices cause inflation with a lag of three
years. On a reverse causality, inflation causes changes in domestic
credit, exchange rates and government bond yields. One has to look at
these results with caution. As quarterly data on GDP is not available in
Pakistan, in this preliminary analysis we estimate the model using
annual data. In order to analyse the predictive performance of an
inflation forecasting model, one has to use quarterly data. (7) The
results, however, highlight an important point. As it is evident from
Table 5 that exchange rate is influenced by changes in CPI, a monetary
policy objective of price stability would help to stabilise exchange
rates as well as making central bank intervention in currency markets a
less likely event.
Finally, we estimate an equation for inflation. Again we modify
Debelle and Lim (1998) to specify an equation for inflation of the
following form.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (2)
We estimate two different specifications of Equation (2). The
results are reported in Table 6. Column 2 of Table 6 reports the results
of Model 1 (first specification). These results indicate that first lag
of inflation have positive and statistically significant influence on
current inflation and thus may help to predict inflation. A positive
estimate for the parameter of Output Gap suggests the use of
expansionary monetary policy to expand the economy could lead to higher
inflation. A negative and statistically significant coefficient for
[DELTA]ER could be result of a reduced trade gap through higher exports
(through exchange rate depreciation) and hence resulting in lower
inflation. The results also indicate strong evidence of imported
inflation in Pakistan as USINF is positive and statistically
significant. Consistent with theoretical predictions, higher deficits
lead to inflationary pressure. The results suggest that increases in
public sector spending which result in higher budget deficits could also
be a source of higher inflation in Pakistan. Further, financing these
budget deficits through seigniorage leads to monetary expansion and thus
to higher inflation. We also found the financial depth (M2/GDP) leads to
higher inflation. This result is consistent with the experience of many
emerging economies at the early stage of liberalisation. Increase in
nominal short-term interest rate serves as an announcement effect of the
future monetary policy and thus could lead to lower inflationary
expectation. Model 2 (second specification) excludes the seigniorage
from the equation. The results are reported in Column 3 of Table 6.
These results, in general, are consistent with the results of Model 1.
This could be due to the fact that Model 2 still has M2/GDP in the
equation and effect of MI is imbedded in M2.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
Like many central banks in the emerging markets, the State Bank of
Pakistan is also under pressure to discuss and design a policy that
could provide a stable and sustainable economic growth as well as
address the necessary conditions to be part of the global economy. The
main issue to be resolved is what type of monetary policy should be
pursued to achieve certain goals over a medium to long-term. Inflation
targeting has been experimented in some emerging economies in Latin
America and East Asia. However, a switch towards inflation targeting as
part of the monetary policy is subject to certain pre-requisites
including an understanding of the determinants of inflation and a
reasonable forecasting mechanism. This is the main objective of this
paper.
Pakistan has made significant progress in implementing economic and
institutional reforms since 2000. Some of these developments have been
well recognised. Pakistan achieved the most rapid privatisation of the
banking system during this period. The State Bank of Pakistan has been
identified as the most efficient central bank in emerging economies in
2004. Inflation was been brought to single digits and economic growth
reached a record high level during 2004. Although debt is still a major
issue to be resolved, a sizeable foreign reserve has reduced the risk of
default. Given these characteristics of the economy, it is probably the
time to seriously consider an appropriate choice of monetary policy for
the central bank. Inflation targeting is one of such alternative.
The paper focuses on inflation targeting (IT) as a choice of
monetary policy and to achieve economic stability. The paper provides a
detailed illustration of the experience of some emerging economies that
opted inflation targeting with a comparison to Pakistan's current
economic performance. The examples of the Latin American and some
Central European countries suggest the feasibility of inflation
targeting in emerging economies even if these countries had complicated
political and economic environments and did not satisfy all the
pre-conditions suggested in the literature. (8) These examples also
suggest that inflation targeting benefited these countries in providing
price and macroeconomic stability. However, this success requires
measures to ensure central bank transparency and committed policies to
develop strong fiscal, financial and monetary institutions.
Any decision to adopt inflation targeting requires a good
theoretical model and some empirical estimates to understand the pricing
mechanism in Pakistan. This paper attempts to develop and estimate a
model for Pakistan and provides estimate for leading indicators of
inflations as well estimating the determinants of inflation for
Pakistan. Our results suggest that imported inflation, seigniorage and
openness cause inflation in Pakistan. The results also indicate that
imported inflation, deficit-GDP ratio, seigniorage, money depth,
exchange rate depreciation and domestic credit may be important
determinants of inflation in Pakistan. A mechanism to predict the
movements of these variables would help the State Bank of Pakistan to
curtail inflation within its target bands. This preliminary analysis
could be used as a step forward to develop a more comprehensive model
and econometric methodology to address these issues in further details.
It would be ideal to use, at least, quarterly data for inflation
forecasts. It is also important to decide which definition of inflation
is appropriate for Pakistan's case. An analysis of policy
alternatives would help to understand which policy suits the best for
Pakistan's economic environment. These are possible extension being
pursued in a separate paper. Nevertheless, this paper serves to initiate
the discussion on this important issue and attempts to answer some
important empirical questions in the context of Pakistan economy.
REFERENCES
Amato, Jeffery D., and Stefan Gerlach (2002) Inflation Targeting in
Emerging Market and Transition Economies: Lessons After a Decade.
European Economics Review 46, 781-90.
Ariff, Mohamed, and Ahmed M. Khalid (2005) Liberalisation and
Growth in Asia: 21st Century Challenges. U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing
Company. 399 p.
De Gregorio, Jose, Andrea Tokman, and Rodrigo Valdes (2005)
Flexible Exchange Rate with Inflation Targeting in Chile: Experience and
Issues, Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department. August.
(Working Paper No. 540.)
Debelle, Guy, and Cheng Hoon Lim (1998) Preliminary Considerations
of An Inflation Targeting Framework for the Philippines. International
Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C., March. (IMF Working Paper.)
Khalid, Ahmed M. (2006) is Inflation Targeting the Best Policy
Choice for Emerging Economies? A Survey of Emerging Market Experiences
and Lessons for Pakistan. SBP-Research Bulletin (forthcoming).
Kuttner, Kenneth N. (2004) A Snapshot of Inflation Targeting in
it's Adolescence. Paper presented at the Reserve Bank of Australia 2004 Conference on 'The Future of Inflation Targeting', 9- I 0
August.
Vargas, Hernando H. (2005) Exchange Rate Policy and Inflation
Targeting in Columbia, Inter-American Development Bank, Research
Department. (Working Paper No. 539.)
Author's Note: An earlier version of this paper was presented
at the PSDE Conference: 19-21 December 2005.
(1) New Zealand was the first country to adopt an
inflation-targeting regime in 1990. Since then, many countries have
joined the club including both industrialised countries (such as
Australia, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom) and emerging
economies (such as Brazil, Chile, Columbia, Czech Republic, Iceland,
Israel, Mexico. Peru, the Philippines, Poland and South Africa).
(2) Some of the Latin American countries moved to inflation
targeting along with dollarisation, thus completely giving up their
monetary policy and national currencies. This could be considered as the
fourth group. There is also another small group that may adopt inflation
targeting along with currency boards.
(3) ITL is a transitional regime until the country is ready to move
to a full-fledged IT regime.
(4) The experience of some of these countries is summarised in
Table 1.
(5) de Gregorio. Tokman and Valdes (2005) discuss in detail the
Chilean experience of inflation targeting with flexible exchange rate
regime.
(6) See Vargas (2005) for a detailed discussion on Columbian
experience of exchange rate policy and inflation targeting.
(7) We plan to use some statistical methods to form a series of
quarterly GDP and replicate this analysis. This stresses the need for
more frequent statistical reporting especially on important
macroeconomic variables such as GDP.
(8) See Khalid (2006).
Ahmed M. Khalid is based at Bond University. Gold Coast, Qld.,
Australia.
Table 1
Pakistan--Basic Macroeconomic Indicators (1960-2005)
1961-70 1971-80 1981-90 1991-95
National Accounts
GDP Growth (%) 3.35 4.81 6.19 4.85
Per Capita GDP (US$) 138.86 180.18 327.06 404.85
Financial Indicators (%)
GDS/GDP -- 13.81 13.83 14.81
GFCF/GDP 15.37 15.38 16.96 18.07
Inflation (per Annum) 3.51 12.42 6.98 11.20
M2/GDP 36.14 41.76 41.25 43.39
M3/GDP 40.26 46.78 49.62 50.38
DC/GDP) 38.44 45.49 51.18 52.70
Fiscal Balance/GDP -5.17 -7.41 -6.74 -7.67
Domestic Borrowing/GDP 1.84 3.42 5.29 5.60
Foreign Borrowing/GDP 3.34 3.74 1.45 2.06
Debt/Exports 403.90 606.09 509.28 --
Debt/GDP 33.91 61.96 64.15 --
Foreign Reserves/Imports 21.27 17.98 11.52 14.24
1996-2000 2000 2001 2002
National Accounts
GDP Growth (%) 3.07 4.26 2.72 4.41
Per Capita GDP (US$) 438.82 426.64 380.54 439.00
Financial Indicators (%)
GDS/GDP 13.29 14.40 14.60 13.60
GFCF/GDP 15.41 14.37 14.29 12.33
Inflation (per Annum) 7.30 4.37 3.15 3.29
M2/GDP 46.63 46.92 48.30 51.74
M3/GDP 49.69 50.19 50.85 55.54
DC/GDP) 50.63 49.57 45.47 42.34
Fiscal Balance/GDP -6.91 -5.47 -4.71 -4.62
Domestic Borrowing/GDP 4.89 4.56 2.51 3.35
Foreign Borrowing/GDP 2.03 0.91 2.20 1.27
Debt/Exports -- 550.66 -- --
Debt/GDP -- 90.00 -- --
Foreign Reserves/Imports 10.56 14.23 34.05 71.86
2003 2004 2005
National Accounts
GDP Growth (%) 5.1 6.4 8.4
Per Capita GDP (US$) 455 470 491
Financial Indicators (%)
GDS/GDP 17.6 16.4 13.7
GFCF/GDP 16.9 17.3 16.8
Inflation (per Annum) 3.1 4.6 9.3
M2/GDP 56.40 -- --
M3/GDP -- -- --
DC/GDP) 42.69
Fiscal Balance/GDP -3.7 -3.0 -.30
Domestic Borrowing/GDP 2.32 -- --
Foreign Borrowing/GDP 1.18 -- --
Debt/Exports -- -- --
Debt/GDP -- -- --
Foreign Reserves/Imports -- -- --
Source: Ariffand Khalid (2005).
Notes: M2 = Currency + quasi money; M3 = M2 + Other Deposits;
GDS: Gross domestic saving; GFCF = Gross fixed capital formation;
DC: Domestic credit.
Table 2
Macroeconomic Performance of Emerging Market ITters at the
Time of Adoption to Inflation Targeting
Fiscal
Real GDP Balance
Growth (%)-- (% of GDP)--
IT (One Year (in the
Adoption betore Year of Seigniorage
Countries Date Adoption) Adoption) (1992-95)
Chile 1999Q3 -0.98 -- 1.53
Peru 2002Q1 0.2 -- --
Mexico 2002Q1 6.64 -- 0.69
Brazil 1999Q2 0.79 -6.89 7.46
Columbia 1999Q3 -4.2 -- 1.97
Czech Republic 1998Q1 -0.76 -1.63 --
Poland 1999Q1 4.84 -4.98 2.23
Hungary 2001Q3 5.19 -- 4.12
Israel 1997Q2 4.51 -- 0.53
South Africa 2000Q1 2.12 -2.65 0.37
South Korea 1998Q2 5.01 -- 1.12
Thailand 2000Q2 4.43 -2.24 1.39
The Philippines 2002Q1 3.4 -- 1.39
Sources: Kuttner (2004), Amato and Gerlach (2002), Khalid (2006).
Table 3
Unit Root Tests Result
Variable ADF(Levels) ADF(First Difterence)
[DELTA][CPI.sub.t-1] -3.429210 ** -5.748879 *
USINF -3.003700 ** -6.570895 *
RGDP -.0266240 -3.500059 *
YGap 0.575690 -5.417021 *
DefGDP -3.849298 *
[DELTA]M1GDP -5.37479 *
LDC 2.725933 -4.817433 *
SP -0.749881 -4.082395 *
CMRate -2.146065 -7.323656 *
ER 2.842852 -3.673984 *
M1GDP -4.326640 * --
M2GDP -2.502640 -5.926836 *
DBOR 0.064564 -12.40113 *
TTGDP -1.815292 -41.200009 *
Note: *, ** and *** Indicate the rejection of null at 10 percent,
5 percent and 1 percent respectively.
Table 4
Granger Causality Test Results for Leading Indicators of Inflation
Null Hypothesis Lags F-Statistic Probability
YGap does not Granger Cause 1 3.71008 *** 0.0616
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 47.9989 0.0000
YGap
DefGDP does not Granger Cause 1 1.5518 0.2205
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 5.1110 ** 0.0296
DefGDP
USINF does not Granger Cause 3 2.9171 ** 0.0192
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 0.4597 0.7123
USINF
[DELTA]M1GDP does not Granger 1 5.5545 ** 0.0237
Cause [DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 0.4424 0.5099
[DELTA]M1GDP
[DELTA]LDC does not Granger Cause 3 0.8989 0.4525
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 3.1107 ** 0.0399
[DELTA]LDC
[DELTA]SP does not Granger Cause 4 0.4742 0.7543
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 0.4861 0.7458
[DELTA]SP
[DELTA]CMRate does not Granger 1 0.1918 0.6640
Cause [DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 6.8033 ** 0.0129
[DELTA]CMRate
[DELTA]RGDP does not Granger Cause 4 0.3955 0.8102
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 0.4297 0.7860
[DELTA]RGDP
[DELTA]ER does not Granger Cause 2 1.1035 0.3429
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 0.3123 0.7338
[DELTA]ER
[DELTA]M2GDP does not Granger 1 1.7768 0.1905
Cause [DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 4.0744 ** 0.0506
[DELTA]M2GDP
[DELTA]DBOR does not Granger Cause 4 0.0548 0.9941
[DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 0.2315 0.9184
[DELTA]DBOR
[DELTA]TTGDP does not Granger 2 23.003 * 0.0000
Cause [DELTA]CPI
[DELTA]CPI does not Granger Cause 2.5963 0.1154
[DELTA]TTGDP
Note: *, **, *** Denotes rejection of Granger non-causality in mean
at 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent levels of significant.
Table 5
Leading Indicators of Inflation (VAR Estimation)
Causality from
CPI to Other
Variables
F-stat Lags
GDP 3.11 1
CMRate 0.06 1
DC 27.04 * 1
ER 10.4 * 1
G.Bond 4.85 ** 1
Ml 1.51 3
M2 0.76 1
M4 0.004 1
SP 2.38 3
Causality from
Other Variables
to CPI
F-stat Lags
GDP 5.6 * 1
CMRate 0.000 1
DC 1.17 1
ER 0.38 1
G.Bond 0.57 1
Ml 4.38 ** 3
M2 0.09 1
M4 0.10 1
SP 18.2 * 3
Note: *, **, *** Denotes rejection of Granger
non-causality in mean at 10 percent, 5 percent
and 1 percent levels of significant.
Table 6
Inflation Forecasting Equation: Dependent Variable: [DELTA][CPI.sub.t]
Variable Model 1 Model 2
Constant -0.5209 * -0.4026 *
(-6.0234) (-4.8345)
[DELTA][CPI.sub.t-1] 0.4714 * 0.7093 *
(3.5564) (6.4157)
[YGap.sub.t-3] 0.2578 ** 0.1335
(2.2603) (1.1654)
[YGap.sub.t-4] 0.2060 *** 0.2287 ***
(1.8187) (1.8296)
[DELTA][ER.sub.t-2] -0.0l49 * -0.0142 *
(-4.4032) (-3.7841)
[USINF.sub.t-1] 0.0118 * 0.0114 *
(4.4021) (3.8684)
[USINF.sub.t-2] -0.0149 * -0.0167 *
(-4.2730) (-11.4266)
[USINF.sub.t-3] 0.0056 ** 0.0078 *
(2.2281) (2.9917)
[DefGDP.sub.t-1] 0.0103 * 0.0094 *
(4.2287) (3.5356)
[DELTA][M1GDP.sub.t-2] 0.0054 ***
(1.9933)
[DELTA][M1GDP.sub.t-3] 0.0074 **
(2.6402)
[M2GDP.sub.t-1] 0.0085 * 0.0083 *
(6.6090) (5.9690)
[M2GDP.sub.t-4] 0.0075 * 0.0048 *
(4.4726) (3.1743)
[CMRate.sub.t-1] -0.0169 *
(-4.7672)
[CMRate.sub.t-4] -0.0126 *
(-3.5697)
Adj-[R.sup.2] 0.8275 0.7887
D-h -3.0947 -1.5970
F-Statistics 14.6532 13.5553
Note: *, **, and *** Denote the signiticance level at 1 percent,
5 percent, and 10 percent respectively.