Impact of exchange rate volatility on growth and economic performance: a case study of Pakistan, 1973-2003.
Azid, Toseef ; Jamil, Muhammad ; Kousar, Aneela 等
1. INTRODUCTION
"Exchange rate" is the price of one currency in relation
to another. In a slightly different perspective, it expresses the
national currency's quotation in respect to foreign ones. Thus,
exchange rate is a conversion factor, a multiplier or a ratio, depending
on the direction of conversion, it is believed that if exchange rates
can freely move, it may turn out to be the fastest moving price in the
economy, bringing together all the foreign goods with it.
In the existing literature, (most of the time) volatility comes
with the exchange rate. Volatility is defined as "instability,
fickleness or uncertainty" and is a measure of risk, whether in
asset pricing, portfolio optimisation, option pricing, or risk
management, and presents a careful example of risk measurement, which
could be the input to a variety of economic decisions.
Volatility of exchange rates describes uncertainty in international
transactions both in goods and in financial assets. Exchange rates are
modeled as forward-looking relative asset prices that reflect
unanticipated change in relative demand and supply of domestic and
foreign currencies, so exchange rate volatility reflects agents'
expectations of changes in determinants of money supplies, interest
rates and incomes.
As many developing countries have or are considering implementing
changes in their development strategies, now is an opportune time to
investigate the issue of weather alteration, in exchange rate
arrangement have an effect on economic growth or to what extent exchange
rate volatility may be responsible for variation in the rate of economic
production. Because such moves are accompanied by increase in the
volatility of both, nominal and real exchange rates [Caporale and Pittis
1995].
Real exchange rate uncertainty can have negative effects on both
domestic and foreign investment decisions. It causes realloeation of
resources among the sectors and countries, between exports and imports
and creates an uncertain environment for investment. Two branches of
macroeconomic theory relate to the question of how exchange rate
volatility affects macroeconomic performance.
(1) The first examines how the domestic economy responds to foreign
and domestic real and monetary shocks under different exchange rate
regimes.
(2) The second focuses on the issue of how exchange rate volatility
under flexible exchange rate regimes affects international trade.
In the case of free mobility of capital, an economy that is
affected mainly by shocks to the LM curve, due to changes in money
demand for example, will experience large fluctuations in output,
inflation, and the exchange rate if the exchange rate is flexible.
If the exchange rate is fixed and capital is internationally mobile
then the money supply is endogenous--changes in money demand determine
changes in the money supply so that LM shocks will have no effect on
output or inflation. Some recent work has certainly suggested that
developing countries that peg their exchange rates achieve lower
inflation than those whose exchange rate floats [Ghosh, et al. (1995);
Aghevli, et al. (1991); Obsffeld (1995); Alogoskoufis (1992); Collins
(1996); Bleaney and Fielding (1999)].
(1) The most important reasons for a devaluation to trigger an
aggregate demand contraction include: a redistribution of income towards
those with high marginal propensity to save, a fall in investment, an
increased debt burden, reduction in real wealth, a low government
marginal propensity to spend out of tax revenue, real income declines
under an initial trade deficit, increased interest rates, and increased
foreign profits [Diaz-Alejandro (1965); Cooper (1971, 1971a, 1971b);
Krugman and Taylor (1978); Branson (1986); Buffie (1986a); Van
Wijnbergen (1986); Gylfason and Risager (1984); Gylfason and Schmid
(1983); Hanson (1983); Gylfason and Radetzki (1991); Barbone and
Rivera-Batiz (1987)].
(2) On the other hand, aggregate supply may suffer after
devaluation because of: more expensive imported production inputs, wage
indexation programmes, costlier working capital [Bruno (1979); Gylfason
and Schmid (1983); Hanson (1983); Gylfason and Risager (1984); Islam
(1984); Gylfason and Radetzki (1985); Branson (1986); Solimano (1986);
Van Wijnbergen (1986); Edwards (1989)].
(3) Increases in the volatility of the real effective exchange
rate, exert a significant negative effect upon export demand in both the
short-run and the long run and these effects may result in significant
reallocation of resources by market participants. The issue is
particularly important for countries that Switched from a fixed to a
flexible exchange rate regime due to the higher degree of variability
associated with flexible exchange rates [Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978);
Coes (1981); De Grauwe (1988); Brada and Mendez (1988); Caballero and
Corbo (1989); crt6 (1994); Baum, et al. (2001) and Arize, Osang, and
Slottje (2004)].
(4) The impact of exchange rate volatility on investment and hence
on economic growth is not a recent source of concern. It is noted in the
literature that uncertainty reduces investment in the presence of
adjustment costs and when the investment process includes
irreversibilities. Real exchange rate uncertainty creates an uncertain
environment for investment decisions and therefore, investors delay
their investment decisions to obtain more information about the real
exchange rates if investments are irreversible and exerts negatively on
economic performance.
Campa and Goldberg (1993) found a negative impact of exchange rate
volatility on investment. Whereas Aizenman (1992) finds positive
relationship. While Campa and Goldberg (1995) find almost no impact.
Keeping such relationships in mind a hypothesis is developed
relating to the link between exchange rate volatility and economic
growth. It is considered an opportune time for such analysis because
more and more countries are considering revisions in their exchange rate
arrangements. Theory suggests a direct link between exchange rate
volatility and economic performance in the presence of open economies.
In such state of affairs the aim of the study is to find out the nature
of this relationship, i.e. positive or negative or even insignificant.
The rest of the study is arranged as: Section II takes into
discussion the empirical methodology employed and contain explanation
about the construction and utilisation of variables. Section I11
discusses and analyses the results. And finally the last section
contains summary and conclusions.
II. METHODOLOGY AND DATA DESCRIPTION
This section discusses the methodology employed to measure
volatility, and the techniques suggested to capture the effects of
volatility on economic performance.
II.1. The Empirical Methodology
II.1.1. Measurement of Volatility
When dealing with time varying measures of volatility in exchange
rate series, economists construct a rolling (moving) variance of the
series. However, the rolling variance is a naive derivation of
uncertainty. It assumes that economic agents are not necessarily
exploiting patterns in the data when making forecasts of uncertainty and
measures fluctuations of the exchange rate but not the uncertainty in
exchange rate [Dorantes and Pozo 2001].
The choice stands for GARCH as a measure of uncertainty that
forecasts exchange rate movements and measure uncertainty around that
forecast. ARCH stands for autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity.
(1) Autoregressive describes a feedback mechanism that incorporates
past observations into the present,
(2) Conditional implies a dependence on the observations of
immediate past, and
(3) Heteroscedasticity represents a time-varying variance (i.e.,
volatility).
Therefore, ARCH Models allow the error term to have a time varying
variance i.e. to be conditional on the past behaviour of the series.
ARCH models were introduced by Engle (1982) and generalised as GARCH
(Generalised ARCH) by Bollerslev (1986) that offer a more parsimonious model (i.e., using fewer parameters) that lessons the computational
burden [Bollerslev, Chou, and Kroner (1992) and Bollerslev, Engle, and
Nelson (1994)]. These models are widely used in various branches of
econometrics, especially in financial time series analysis [Kroner and
Lapstrapes (1994); Grier and Perry (2000); Arize (1998); Glistens, et
al. (1993)]. The application of GARCH provides variable of interest i.e.
the exchange rate volatility.
II. 1. 2. Stationary/Unit Root Test
The first step of the empirical process involves a test for unit
roots. This is necessary because the co-integration tests can be applied
only to variables that are non-stationary in levels (contain a unit
root). Dickey and Fuller (1979, 1981) and Said and Dickey (1984) have
developed a method to determine whether a variable contains a unit root.
The tests are conducted, including a driR term and both with and without
a trend. The inclusion of a trend allows testing that whether the series
is trend or difference stationary [Amuedo and Pozo (2001); Sinha (1999);
Pesaran and Smith (1998)].
II.1.3. VAR and Cointegration Test
Applying test for stationary and confirming stationary otherwise
leads to VAR (Vector Autoregressive Model) constructed in order to take
account of all the dynamic and co-integrating interrelationships and
impact of random disturbances on the system of variables that result in
forecasting systems of interrelated time series. Granger Causality test
(1969) is used to see any cause and effect relationship between
variables, (how much of the current value of a dependent variable can be
explained by past values of that variable and testing whether adding
lagged values of independent can improve the explanation).
Movement on such smooth track leads to "co-integration"
that implies identifying the co-integrating (long-run equilibrium)
relationships. Using the methodology developed by Johansen (1991, 1995).
Co-integration implies that stationary linear combinations of
non-stationary variables exist. (1) The central concept of
co-integration is the specification of models that include the long-run
movements of one variable relative to others, the test require an
appropriate VAR specification among the variables of interest [Joyce and
Kamas (1994); Alexakis and Apergis (1994); Bahmani-Oskooee and Alse
(1995); Cifarelli (1995); Faruqee (1995) and Sinha (1999)].
II.1.4. Variance Decomposition and Impulse Response Functions
Finally to infer the dynamic relationship among variables in the
modal the variance decomposition along with the IRFs (impulse response
function) are performed.
IRFs [Hamilton (1994)] trace the effects of a shock to an
endogenous variable in VAR. IRF traces the effect of a one standard
deviation shock to (innovations) current and future values of the
endogenous variables due to the fact that a shock to the ith variable
directly affects the ith variable, and is also transmitted to all of the
endogenous variables through the dynamic structure of the VAR.
Whereas, variance decomposition decomposes variation in an
endogenous variable into the component shocks in the VAR, and provide
information about the relative importance of each random innovation to
the variables in the VAR.
11.2. Data Sources and Construction of Variables
The variables in the analysis are real money (RM), the real
exchange rate (RER), real exchange rate volatility (VOL), exports (EX),
imports (IM), and manufacturing production indexes (Y). Because the
approach necessities the use of high frequency data, the analysis is
constrained to using narrow measure of economic production i.e.
manufacturing production indexes as used by Dorantes and Pozo (2001).
The series are constructed as follows. The real exchange rate is
the relative inflation adjusted exchange rate, and is constructed by
multiplying the nominal exchange rate by the ratio of consumer price
indexes (e.g. RER=(PAK/USA)*(CPI US/CPI PAK)). The real exchange rate
volatility (VOL) i.e. the variables of interest is computed by using
GARCH model.
The real money supply series are obtained by deflating the money
supply series with the consumer price indexes; CPIs are converted into
common base of 1995. The exports and imports are taken on unit values
with common base of 1995. As a measure of output (RY) the manufacturing
production series is used.2 Prior to the estimation all variables are
transformed into natural logarithms, with the exception of real exchange
rate volatility.
Data span from 1973-Q1 to 2003-Q4, providing series of 120
observations.
All the series expect the manufacturing production are obtained
from international financial statistics (IFS) up to 1998, from 1998 to
2003 the series are obtained from Statistical Bulletin of Government of
Pakistan, Finance Division. Data regarding manufacturing indexes are
obtained from statistical bulletin.
11.3. Variables Performance Over Time
11.3.1. Real Exchange Rate
Real exchange rate being a measure of international
competitiveness, helps to identify inflation and currency effects, and
represents the relative cost or price expressed in common currency. Real
exchange rates are presented as indexes, the lower the index the more
competitive is the country.
Figure 1, shows an upward trend in real exchange rate, i.e. the
real exchange rate (inflation adjusted) depreciated over time. During
1973-1982 Pakistan maintained a fix exchange rate of Rs 9.90, so the
real exchange rate exhibits slight movements in it.
After 1982, when rupee was allowed a managed float, its value
depreciated by more than 230 percent between January 1982 and June 1996.
During most of the 1980s, the crawling peg caused the movement or
floating exchange rate when the State Bank of Pakistan depreciated the
rupee by few paisas whenever needed, but since 1993, these deprecations
are directly supported by devaluations on the name of technical
adjustments.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Frequent devaluation stimulates speculation, leading to confidence
erosion. Such practice of continuous devaluation not only result in
distortions in income, consumption, industrial growth and public
finance, but also disturb the harmonious blend of internal and external
balance, affecting both monetary and fiscal indicators, e.g. exports,
imports, manufacturing growth, money supply and so on.
After July 2001, the government decided for the free-floating of
the exchange rate, which result in drastic changes in real exchange
rate, and after reaching almost its maximum of Rs 64 in 2002, shows a
downward trend (appreciation) when the market forces played well in
favour of Pakistan. The continued build up in foreign exchange reserves,
surplus in current account balance and increased inflow remittances
through banking channel has strengthened Pakistani rupee via US dollar.
In both open market and interbank market rupee appreciated 3.25 percent
and 3.49 percent respectively during the period of study. Figure 2
depicts the trends in real exchange rate uncertainty/volatility.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
II.3.2. Exports
"Exports" representing the sales in other countries,
generate foreign currency earnings, and boost economic growth. Demand
for exports depends on economic conditions in foreign countries, prices
(relative inflation and exchange rate), and perception of quality,
reliability, and so on.
According to the orthodox approach, the devaluation enhances
competitiveness, increases exports and bends demand toward domestically
produced goods, thus expanding the production of tradable. However,
frequent output declines in the aftermath of devaluations hinted that
the benign relative price adjustment caused by devaluations could bring
about a recession. For demand and supply side contractionary effects
[Diaz-Alejandro (1963); Krugman and Taylor (1978); Barbone and
Rivera-Batiz (1987)], the studies of supply side include [Bruno (1979);
Gylfason and Schmid (1983); Van Wijnbergen (1986); Agenor (1991);
Gylfason and Radetzki (1991) and Yaye (1999)].
In 1972-73 after 21 successive years of unfavourable balance of
trade, Pakistan achieved surplus due to deliberate policy of devaluation
and export promotion measures. Pakistan's exports are highly
concentrated in cotton, leather, rice, synthetic textiles and sports
goods. These five categories accounted for 82.6 percent of total exports
during 2002-03. Pakistan trades with a large number of countries but its
exports are highly concentrated with USA, Germany, Japan, the UK, Hong
Kong, Dubai and Saudi Arabia. Among these countries, the maximum export
proceeds are from the USA making up approximately 24 percent of the
total.
Figure 3 shows an upward or increasing trend for Pakistani exports,
with favourable composition changing for manufacturing and
semi-manufacturing exports and a decreasing share of primary exports. On
July 2001, the share of these sectors was 75 percent, 14 percent, and 11
percent respectively, because at international level the prices of
manufactured items are more stable than primary products. Exports show
drastic change in 1990s, when not only the internal and external factors
affected heavily, a very strong factor causing drastic variations was
the exchange rate arrangement of "managed floating", where the
government continuously changed the value of Pakistani rupee. After free
floating of rupee in July 21, 2000, the variations were smoothed out
again. Moreover, during 2003 the exports grew by 10.3 percent.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
II.3.3. Imports
"Imports" measuring purchases from abroad, add to well
being but may displace domestic production and drain financial
resources. Changes in imports prices reflect changes in foreign prices,
exchange rates and quantity.
Like exports, Pakistan's imports are also highly concentrated
in a few items namely, machinery, petroleum and petroleum products,
chemicals, transport equipments, edible oil, iron and steel, fertiliser
and tea. These eight categories of imports accounted for 75.9 percent of
total imports during 2002-03.
Imports for Pakistan increases overtime including both consumer and
capital goods. However, consumer goods increase more rapidly than
capital goods, which are a prerequisite for long term self-sustained
growth of the economy. The share of raw materials for consumer goods in
the total imports continued to be high while that for capital goods
remained low. The percentage share of industrial raw material has
declined from 11 percent in 1969-70 to 5 percent in 2000-01. The share
of capital goods exhibited a declining trend--mainly because of a slow
down in investment in the country. Now started pick up because of a
revival in the domestic economy. During the 2003, the share of consumer
goods did not show any change and remained at 10 percent while that of
raw materials for consumer goods came to 51 percent from 55 percent,
However, due to higher imports of machinery, the share of capital goods
increased from 29 percent to 32 percent. The share of raw material for
capital goods showed an improvement of one percentage point during this
period and stood at 7 percent. Figure 4 depicts that imports show a
continuous upward trend, throughout 1970s to early 1990s, due to WTO pressure for liberalised import policy. During 2003, imports grew by
27.6 percent.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
II.3.4. Money
Money being the corner stone of modern economy provides a bridge
between the nominal and real magnitudes. Measured in notes, coins and
various bank deposits; it works as an indicator of level of
transactions, inflation and output. Money supply in Pakistan shows a
smooth upward trend in its growth, which gets momentum after year 2000.
During 1999 and 2000, the monetary policy stance remained tight to
keep inflation under control and bring stability in exchange rate to
preserve export competitiveness. This policy stance has been eased since
2001 to promote investment and growth. During 2002-2003, the annual
growth rate of money was 16.8 and 18.4 percent respectively (see Figure
5).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
II.3.5. Manufacturing Production
Manufacturing production measures the value-added output of
manufacturing sector, and an indicator of industrial activity.
Manufacturing sector is the second largest individual sector of the
economy accounting for 18 percent of gross domestic product (GDP).
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Pakistan developed a substantial industrial sector in a very short
period. During 1970s, the growth rate of GDP shows a decreasing trend
and fell to 4.84 percent. The manufacturing sector growth rate was also
low due to policy of nationalisation. During 80s, the industrial policy
laid greater emphasise on employment generation, export promotion and
increased efficiency of production units. Consequently, the
manufacturing sector grew annually at a rate of 7.3 percent as compared
to 5.4 percent in the previous decade and rose to 8.26 in 1991-92.
During 1990s owing to a host of problems like tariff reforms and
escalating utility prices, the growth remains lackluster. The growth
rate of 4.0 percent was disappointing during 1990s. Since 1987-88, the
year 2002 became the best performing year for manufacturing with growth
rate of 7.7 percent. The contribution of manufacturing in GDF has
increased overtime, from 6 percent in 1970-71 to 122 percent in
2001-2002. The above explanation can be seen in Figure 6.
III. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
Unit Root Test
The data for this study exhibits the regular characteristics
associated with most Macroeconomic variables. This conclusion derives
from the unit root tests carried out on the variables used. Checking
stationary is necessary because during building models for time series,
the underlying stochastic process that generated the series must be
invariant with respect to time. If the characteristics of the stochastic
process change over time, i.e., if the process is non-stationary, it
will often be difficult to represent the time series over past and
future intervals of time by a simple algebraic model. This lead to
misleading result. (3)
On the other hand, if the stochastic process is fixed in time,
i.e., if it is stationary, then one can model the process via an
equation with fixed coefficients that can be estimated from past data.
We report the results for the ADF test because it has an Over-riding
advantage on the series, as ADF automatically controls for higher order
correlations by assuming that the coefficient of the series follows an
AR (p) process and automatically adjusts the test methodology. Results
of ADF tests shows that all the variables of the model are integrated at
1(1), suggesting the need for differencing of the variables. This means
that we can precede with the Johansen co-integration tests for these
variables. Table 1 contains the results from the unit root test.
Application of ARCH/GARCH for "Volatility"
The variable of Volatility is a measure of risk, which is generated
through ARCH/GARCH process, allowing the error term to have a time
varying variance. Table 2 shows the results.
Correllogram of the series indicate the existence of
autocorrelation and partial autocorrelation up to three lags, indicating
the pattern of temporal dependence in the series, with p-value 0.009,
indicating spurious results. The inclusion of AR (3) solve the problem
of correlation and provide the variable of interest i.e., Volatility.
Testing for unit root indicate that the variable is stationary at first
difference, i.e. I (1) (see Table 3).
Granger Causality and VAR
To account for both feedback and dynamic effects, and to facilitate
a meaningful interpretation of any long run relationships among the
series we chose a VAR framework for our analysis. In estimating, a VAR
there is a choice between a large model, which captures all of the
possible forces affecting variables of interest, and a more parsimonious
model, which uses less degree of freedom and enables estimation that is
more efficient. Given the aim of estimating the impact of the exchange
rate volatility on output (manufacturing sector), it is common to choose
a small, three or four variable model. Given the available data, it is
felt that a three variable model including the real exchange rate,
volatility, and manufacturing product will best describe the
relationship between variables. The volatility picks up the effect of
exogenous and endogenous shocks on the manufacturing product, while the
real exchange rate will pick up the impact of domestic monetary policy
on output. Finally, the manufacturing product variable will pick up all
of the other shocks, which affect GDP.
The ordering of variables is important for impulse response
functions. Since there is no specific theory of how to determine a
causal structure, the order of the variable can be arbitrary. Usually,
theoretical motivation or even data arability motivation is used to
order the variables. However, the specific order can have major
consequences for the policy implications of a model. (4) Therefore, it
is important to check if alternative ordering gives significantly
different results. Choosing an appropriate lag length is also important,
since too many lags reduce the degree of freedom, while too short a lag
structure may lead to serial correlation in error terms, which can
result in spurious significance and inefficient estimates.
The procedure of choosing the lag length is based on use of Akaike
Information Criteria (AIC), the Schwartz Bayesian Criterion (SBC) and
Hannanquinn criterion (HQC). It is observed that the AIC tends to prefer
longer lags while SBC and HQC tend to choose shorter lags; in this
analysis the choice stands for SBC. The value of [R.sup.2] is 0,950834.
Therefore, 95 percent variations in each of the variables can be
interpreted by the lagged values of all the endogenous variables.
Within a VAR framework, Granger causality is characterised by a
finite number of linear restrictions on a subset of parameters. Granger
causality is a measure of the significance of one variable in
forecasting another. To find out any cause and effect relationship
between manufacturing product, real exchange rate, and volatility the
granger causality test is applied. The results are not in favour of the
relationship among these variables. We have checked the granger
causality under the lag lengths of 1 to 6 for the above three variables.
The results of Granger causality test are given in Table 4. The results
showed that manufacturing product and volatility does not granger cause
at any lag length, indicating that both the variables are independent.
The results for real exchange rate and manufacturing product exhibits
that at lag lengths I and 2 causality is bi-directional and at lag
lengths 3, 4, 5, and 6 only manufacturing productivity does granger
cause real exchange rate.
The results appeared contrary to the theory, which suggests that
exchange rate variations effects manufacturing production, positively or
negatively depending upon the underlying facts. In a microeconomie
context, at the level of the firm, the exchange rate variations directly
affect the firm's decisions to take up production or not. However,
in a macro-economic context, the relationship is more likely to be
bi-directional. Suggesting that the real exchange rate might have an
indirect effect through its impacts on cost of domestic to foreign
goods, leading to import substitutions. Although the characterisation of
causality is invariant to stationary properties of the series, the
statistical inference under non-stationary and/or co-integrated systems
is driven by very irregular asymptotic properties for which the usual
critical values remain valid only under special conditions.
For all the VARs considered, we can never accept that volatility
adds significant contribution to manufacturing product.
Variance Decomposition and Impulse Response Functions The dynamic
relationships among the variables in the three variable models can be
inferred from the variance decomposition along with the impulse response
functions. Theory suggest that the real exchange rate and production
series should be co-integrated because real exchange rate depreciations
lowers the relative costs of domestic to foreign goods, causing import
substitution to take place and promoting exports. Such effect would tend
to increase the level of production.
Considering the following equations to check whether cointegration
relationship exists among variables manufacturing product and volatility
and manufacturing product and real exchange rate.
LP_Y = [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1]Vol
Results of the linear regression of the variables manufacturing
product, volatility and real exchange rate are given in Table 5. The
coefficient value is 322.2278, indicating that a 1 percent variation in
volatility, contributes positively up to 322.2278 percent. However, the
low value of [R.sup.2] i.e. 0.161294, suggests that the independent
variable cannot explain many of the time series of manufacturing
product. On the other hand value of [R.sup.2] i.e. 0.857717 suggests
that independent variable explain many of the time series of
manufacturing product.
If linear combination of the variables is integrated of order less
than the integration of the variables then it implies cointigration
exists. The unit root test is applied to check the level of stationary
of the linear combination of the variables (residual terms) on both
Intercept and Trend and Intercept. Error terms for the first regression
is stationary at first difference and series of residuals ([e.sub.1]) is
integrated of order one while error term for the second regression
([e.sub.2]) is stationary at level and the series of residual is
integrated of order zero i.e. 1 (0).
As all the variables manufacturing product, volatility and real
exchange rate integrated of first order only the series of residuals
([e.sub.2]) is integrated of order zero, this implies the co-integration
relationship between the variables manufacturing product and real
exchange rate. This leads to the estimation of error correcting
equations, regressing difference of the log(RER) on the previous value
of error term and similarly difference of log (y) on the previous value
of error term ([e.sub.2](-1)). Here the value of
[[alpha].sub.2] =-3.194182
[[beta].sub.2] = 1.987633
While in the adjustment equations a = -0.468990 and b = 0.042996.
(a-b[[beta].sub.2]) = [(-0.468990)-((0.042996X1.987633))]=
-0.554450 < 0
The value of (a-b[beta].sub.2])< 0, so the error correction
process is a stabilising process, and long run adjustment process exist.
Sign of "a" is negative showing that output by itself
contributes positively to readjustment process. The co-efficient
"b" of error correction model is also positive. Which shows
that adjustment through real exchange rate positively contribute to
output.
Impulse responses are estimated to evaluate shock dynamics. Which
provide distinct and complementary information. Non-zero impulse
responses from one variable to another need not imply the presence of
Granger causality, and vice versa [Dufour and Tessier (1993); Dufour and
Renault (1998)]. Even though Granger causality analysis is a useful tool
for analysing dynamic structures between time series, it cannot provide
an estimate of the direction (sign) or magnitude of the relationships of
interest.
This is why Sims (1980) proposed to invert the autoregressive part
of the process and to work with the underlying moving-average
representation. The VARs are similar to the ones in the previous
section. However, the inversion procedure calls for a stationary VAR
process, which can be set up by differencing every integrated variable
included in the system. To evaluate the potential impact of different
shocks on manufacturing product, we consider the following causality
structures.
log (RER). log (y) (Structure 1)
Vol. log (y) (Structure 2)
For these two variable systems, we are interested in shocks
affecting the manufacturing production. The impulse response functions
are given in Appendix A, B and C. The impulse functions for volatility
resulting from manufacturing production turn out to be insignificants.
In contrast, for all cases, real exchange rate shocks appear to have a
significant impact on manufacturing production, with the expected
positive sign.
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
The advantages and disadvantages of different exchange rate regimes
have inevitably spawned a massive literature [e.g. Aghevli, et al.
(1991); Obstfeld (1995)].
Over the years flexible exchange rate arrangements (encouraging
market forces to play without fear of intervention) have positively
affected in a detectable way to the pace of economic performance. Though
we cannot measure the effect of exchange rate uncertainty on GDP growth,
we obtain evidence on its effects by tracing the impact of exchange rate
uncertainty on manufacturing production as done by Dorantes and Pozo
(2001).
Instead of using rolling variance to capture uncertainty, the study
employ conditional estimate of the variable of interest, exchange rate
uncertainty. This methodology allows for more of the past information to
be incorporated and provide us with measure of uncertainty that is less
naive than other measures commonly employed in the literature, i.e.
standard deviation, rolling variance etc.
Applying unit root suggested that all the variables are stationary
at first difference, i.e. I (1). We construct VAR; including three
variables to differentiate between the hypotheses that exchange rate
uncertainty depresses vs. promote manufacturing production. The results
obtained are positive but are insignificant, and do not support the
position that excessive volatility or shifting of exchange rate regimes
has pronounced affects for manufacturing production. These results are
consistent with what we obtain from the impulse responses.
The concerns raised by the policy-makers about the costs of
adopting flexible exchange rate systems are not borne out by results.
In the previous empirical work, a negative link between exchange
rate volatility and economic growth seems to prevail. Most of the
previous studies used cross sectional data. Here we prefer time series
to capture exchange rate uncertainty.
One can never provide definite proof of a negative proposition. It
is believed, however, that this study adds to the body of evidence
suggesting that exchange rate variability has no significant effect on
manufacturing product.
Comments
The paper is a useful contribution in an important area of research
relating to exchange rate volatility. The research on volatility of
exchange rate has assumed great significance for exchange rate policy in
Pakistan since the adoption of flexible exchange rate policy in July
2000. The paper analyses the economic performance in response to the
volatility in exchange rate. The paper concludes that volatility in
exchange rate does not have any impact on manufacturing. This result is
contrary to the theory which suggests that variation in exchange rate
has an indirect effect through its impact on cost of domestic to foreign
goods which might lead to import substitution. Moreover empirical
studies also show that volatility in exchange rate harms the capital
accumulation, economic performance and growth [Dorantes and Pozo
(2001)]. Aizenman (1992) and Goldberg (1993) increase in exchange rate
volatility leads to reduction in the level of investment. Cottani, et
al. (1990) shows that volatility in exchange rate around the real
exchange rate is negatively associated with the economic performance.
However, according to Dollar (1992) the exchange rate variability
depresses the economic growth for the higher income countries but does
not affect the growth for the lower income countries.
Whereas the paper makes significant contribution to the analysis, I
would like to make few suggestions and hope that these would be helpful
to the authors when they revise the paper.
The major concern I have with this paper is that when the exchange
rate was under the direct influence of State Bank of Pakistan there was
hardly any volatility. Moreover over the initial period, i.e., from
1973:1 to 1981:4 the exchange rate was fixed at Rs 9.9/$. Volatility is
observed only in the last few quarters when the exchange rate regime was
changed to flexible from manage/dirty float. Therefore, analysing from
1973 when initially the exchange rate is fixed and later the volatility
was quite low, one cannot conclude that there is longer term impact of
exchange rate volatility on economic performance. In this case the
results of the study may be spurious.
There have been atleast three major structural changes during
1973:1 to 2003:4, which would significantly affect the analysis but
authors assumed that there was no structural change. Firstly, in 1982:1
when managed float exchange rate regime was adopted and the real
exchange rate devalued by 14.8 percent. Secondly, in 1999:2, State Bank
stopped announcing the official exchange rate and the Rupee-Dollar rate
jumped from Rs 46/$ to Rs 51.39/$. Thirdly, in 2000:3 Pakistani rupee
was floated and became fully flexible and the value of exchange rate
jumped from Rs 51.79/$ to Rs 58.44/$ and by the last quarter of 2000 the
rupee-dollar parity went up to Rs 64/$. Finally, major structural change
occurred after September 2001 when the rupee started appreciating. In
the presence of such structural changes ADF test is not the appropriate
test to use, instead Philip-Perron (PP) test should be used. Moreover,
to avoid the serial correlation in the ADF test lagged differences
should be included while checking the ADF test. However, authors did not
use or forgot to mention the inclusion of number of lagged differences
in the ADF test.
Industrial production index is used as a proxy to GDP. No doubt,
for some industrialised countries such as UK, USA etc., it may be used
as a proxy because the industrial production has major share in the GDP.
However, the quarterly data of GDP for these industrailised countries
are available so one can use that as well. But in countries like
Pakistan, Bangladesh, and India industrial production index is not a
good proxy to GDP because of the agrarian nature of their economies. It
is a blessing that now PIDE has generated quarterly series of GDP, which
can be used instead of manufacturing indices.
Volatility means unsure movements. With a rise in prices it is
expected that the exchange rate would rise. The Graph 2.2 shows the
volatility in the exchange rate which is not explained by the authors
and its is needed to be explained. It shows that volatility of exchange
rate increased with an increase in the value of the exchange rate. After
2001 it declined and then remained low and stable when exchange rate
started appreciating. This shows that depreciation leads to higher
instability and appreciation helps in controlling the instability in
exchange rate.
On page 4 it seems that they are using Johansen approach of
cointegration which is based on the rank test and maximum eigenvalues.
However, on page 14 they are reporting ADF test results of the error
which shows that they might have used Engle-Granger approach of
cointegration.
Impulse response function estimated by the authors gave some very
good results but it has been under-utilised. The more elaborate
explanation would be helpful for better policy-making.
There are some minor comments for example on page 5 author wrote
that from January 1982 to June 1996 the value is depreciated/devalued by
230 percent. However, it is 67 percent in case of nominal exchange rate
and 39 percent in case of real exchange rate. I think the calculation
method of devaluation is wrong, which should be corrected later. On page
6 it is written that in both open market and interbank market rupee
appreciated 3.25 percent and 3.49 percent respectively but over what
period is not mentioned. Table 3.2 shows the GARCH results of real
exchange rate but authors did not mention that why did they take period
from 1983:1-2003:4 and ignore the previous ten years, while running the
regression.
The data for the same variable is taken from two sources (IFS and
Monthly Statistical Bulletin of SBP) for two different periods. However,
it does not make any difference if both sources are getting the data
from the same source, However, in Graph 2.3 and 2.4 the movements of
unit value of imports and exports in the last quarters are somehow
confusing. When I checked the graph after getting the data from IFS from
1973:1 till 2003:4 the movements are different so I think there is some
kind of data error in the series which should be checked before revising
it.
The results are very useful, and I suppose in the light of these
comments the paper will come out as a very good paper.
M. Ali Kemal
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Appendices
APPENDIX A
IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTION OF MANUFACTURING PRODUCT AND REAL
EXCHANGE RATE
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
APPENDIX B
IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTION OF MANUFACTURING PRODUCT AND VOLATILITY
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
APPENDIX C
IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTION OF MANUFACTURING PRODUCT AND VOLATILITY
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Agenor, P. R. (1991) Output, Devaluation, and the Real Exchange
Rate in Developing Countries. Weltwirts chaftliches Archive 127, 18-41.
Aghevli, B. B., S. K. Mohsin, and P. J. Montiel (1991) Exchange
Rate Policy in Developing Countries: Some Analytical Issues. Washington,
D. C.: International Monetary Fund. (Occasional Paper No. 78.)
Aizenman, J. (1992) Exchange Rate Flexibility, Volatility and the
Patterns of Domestic and Foreign Investment. IMF Staff Papers, December
1992, 890-922.
Aizenman, J. (1994) Monetary and Real Shocks, Productive Capacity
and Exchange Rate Regimes. Economics 61:244, 407-34.
Alexakis, P., and N. Apergis (1994) The Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle
and Exchange Rate Regime: Evidence from Cointegration Test. Journal of
Policy Modeling 16, 459-472.
Alogoskoufis, G. S. (1992) Monetary Accommodation, Exchange Rate
Regimes and Inflation Persistence. Economic Journal 102, 461-80.
Amuedo-Dorantes, C., and S. Pozo (2001) Exchange-Rate Uncertainty
and Economic Performance. Review of Development Economics 5:3, 363-74.
Arize, A. T. O., and D. Slottje (2004) Exchange Rate Volatility and
Foreign Trade: Evidence from Thirteen LDCs. Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics 18, 10-17.
Arize, A. C. (1998) The Effects of Exchange Rate Volatility on U.S.
Imports: An Empirical Investigation. International Economic Journal
12:3, 31-40.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., and J. Asle (1995) Is There any Long-Run
Relation Between the Terms of Trade and the Trade Balance? Journal of
Policy Modeling 17, 119-205.
Barbone, L., and F. Rivera-Batiz (1987) Foreign Capital and the
Contractionary Impact of Currency Devaluation, With an Application to
Jamaica. Journal of Development Economics 26, 1-15.
Baum, C. F., M. Caglayan, and N. Ozkan (2001) Nonlinear Effects of
Exchange Rate Volatility on the Volume of Bilateral Exports. Journal of
Applied Econometrics.
Bleaney, M. F., and D. Fielding (2002) Exchange Rate Regimes,
Inflation and Output Volatility in Developing Countries. Journal of
Development Economics 68, 233-45.
Bollerslev, Tim (1986) Generalised Autoregressive Conditional
Heteroscedasticity. Journal of Econometrics 31, 307-327.
Bollerslev, T., and J. M. Wooldridge (1992) Quasi-Maximum
Likelihood Estimation and Inference in Dynamic Models with Time Varying
Covariance. Econometric Reviews 11, 143-172.
Bollerslev, T., R. F. Engle, and D. B. Nelson (1994) ARCH Models.
In Chapter 49 of Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 4. North-Holland.
Brada, J. C., and J. A. Mendez (1988) Exchange Rate Risk, Exchange
Rate Regime and the Volume of International Trade. Kyklos 41, 263-280.
Branson, W. H. (1986) Stabilisation, Stagflation, and Investment
Incentives: The Case of Kenya, 1979-1980. In S. Edwards and L. Ahmad
(eds.) Economic Adjustment and Exchange Rates in Developing Countries.
Chicago: Chicago University Press, 267-293.
Bruno, M. (1979) Stabilisation and Stagflation in a
Semi-industrialised Economy. In Rudiger Dornbusch and Jacob A. Frenkel (eds.) International Economic Policy. Theory and Evidence. Baltimore,
270-289.
Buffie, E. F. (1986a) Devaluations and Imported Inputs: The Large
Economy Case International. Economic Review 27 (February), 123-140.
Buffie, E. F. (1986b) Devaluation, Investment and Growth in LDCs.
Journal of Development Economics 20 (March), 361-379.
Caballero, R. J., and V. Corbo (1989) The Effect of Real Exchange
Rate Uncertainty on Exports: Empirical Evidence. The World Bank Economic
Review 3, 263-278.
Campa, J., and L. S. Goldberg (1995) Investment in Manufacturing,
Exchange Rates and. External Exposure. Journal of International
Economics 38, 297-320.
Campa, J., and L. S. Goldberg (1999) Investment, Pass-through, and
Exchange Rates: A Cross-country Comparison. International Economic
Review 40:2, 287-314.
Caporale, G. M., and N. Pittis (1995) Nominal Exchange Rate Regimes
and the Stochastic Behavior of Real Variables. Journal of International
Money and Finance 14:3, 395-415.
Coes, D. V. (1981) The Crawling Peg and Exchange Rate Uncertainty.
In John Williamson (ed.) Exchange Rates Rules. New York: St. Martins.
113-136.
Collins, S. M. (1996) On Becoming More Flexible: Exchange Rate
Regimes in Latin America and the Caribbean. Journal of Development
Economics 51, 117-38.
Cooper, R. N. (1971a) Currency Devaluation in Developing Countries.
In G. Ranis (ed.) Government and Economic Development. New Heaven: Yale
University Press.
Cooper, R. N. (1971b) Devaluation and Aggregate Demand in Aid
Receiving Countries. In J. N. Bhagwati, et al. (eds.) Trade Balance of
Payments and Growth. Amsterdam and New York: North-Holland.
Cooper, R. N. (1971c) An Assessment of Currency Devaluation in
Developing Countries, Essays in International Finance, No. 86. New
Jersey, Princeton University.
Cote, A. (1994) Exchange Rate Volatility and Trade: A Survey.
International Department Bank of Canada. (Working Paper May, 94-5.)
De Grauwe, P. (1988) Exchange Rate Variability and the Slowdown in
Growth of International Trade. IMF Staff Papers 35 (March), 63-84.
Diaz-Alejandro, C. F. (1965) Exchange Rate Devaluation in a Semi
Industrialised Country: The Experience of Argentina, 1955-1961.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1979) Distribution of the
Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Journal of
the American Statistical Association 74, 427-431,
Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller (1981) Likelihood Ratio Test for
Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Econometrica 49, 1057-72.
Dufour, Jean-Marie, and D. Tessier (1993) On the Relationship
between Impulse Response Analysis, Innovation Accounting and Granger
Causality. Economics Letters 42, 327-333.
Dufour, Jean-Marie, and E. Renault (1998) Short Run and Long Run
Causality in Time Series: Theory. Econometrica 66:5, 1099-1125.
Edwards, S. (1989) Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation, and
Adjustment. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Engle, R. F. (1982) Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity
with Estimates of the Variance of U.K. Inflation. Econometrica 50,
987-1008.
Faruqee, H. (1995) Long-Run Determinants of the Real Exchange Rate:
A Stock-Flow Perspective. IMF Staff Papers 42:1, 80-107.
Ghosh, A. R., A. M. Guide, J. D. Ostry, and H. C. Wolf (1995) Does
the Nominal Exchange Rate Regime Matter? Washington, D. C.,
International Monetary Fund. (Working Paper No. 95/121.)
Glosten, L. R., R. Jaganathan, and D. Runkle (1993) On the Relation
between the Expected Value and the Volatility of the Normal Excess
Return on Stocks. Journal of Finance 48, 1779-1801.
Goldberg, L. S. (1993) Exchange Rates and Demand Uncertainty. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 185-227.
Granger, C. W. J. (1969) Investigating Causal Relations by
Econometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods. Econometrica 37, 424-438.
Grier, K. B., and Mark J. Perry (2000) The Effects of Real and
Nominal Uncertainty on Inflation and Output Growth: Some Garch-m
Evidence. Journal of Applied Econometrics 15:1, 45-58.
Gylfason, T., and M. Radetzki (1991) Does Devaluation Make Sense in
the Least Developed Countries? Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, 1-25.
Gylfason, T., and O. Risager (1984) Does Devaluation Improve the
Current Account? European Economic Review 25, 37-64.
Gylfason, T., and M. Schmid (1983) Does Devaluation Cause
Stagflation? The Canadian Journal of Economics 25, 37-64.
Hamilton, J. D. (1994) Time Series Analysis. Princeton, New Jersey:
Princeton University Press.
Hanson, J. A. (1983) Contractionary Devaluation, Substitution in
Production and Consumption and the Role of the Labor Market. Journal of
International Economics 14, 179-189.
Hooper, P., and S. W. Kohlhagen (1978) The Effect of Exchange Rate
Uncertainty on the Prices and Volume of International Trade. Journal of
International Economics 8, 483-511.
Islam, S. (1984) Devaluation, Stabilisation Policies and the
Developing Countries: A Macroeconomic Analysis. Journal of Development
Economics 14, 37-60.
Johansen, S. (1991) Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models.
Econometrica 59, 1551-1580.
Johansen, S. (1995) Likelihood-based Inference in Co-integrated
Vector Autoregressive Models. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Joyce, J., and L. Kamas (1994) Money and Output under Alternative
Exchange Rate Regimes in the U.S. Journal of International Money and
Finance 13:6, 679-697.
Kroner, K., and W. Lastrapes (1993) The Impact of Exchange Rate
Volatility on international Trade: Reduce form estimates Using the
GARCH-in-Mean Model. Journal of International Money and Finance 12,
298-318.
Krugman, P., and L. Taylor (1978) Contractionary Effects of
Devaluation. Journal of International Economics 8, 445-456.
Krugman, P. (1989) Exchange Rate Instability. Cambridge, MA: The
MIT Press.
Nickell, S. (1981) Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects.
Econometrica 49, 1417-1426.
Obstfeld, M. (1995) International Currency Experience: New Lessons
and Lessons Exchange Rate Volatility and International Trading Strategy.
Journal of International Money and Finance 10 (June), 292-307.
Pesaran, M. H., and R. Smith (1998) Structural Analysis of
Cointegrating VARs. Journal of Economic Surveys 12, 471-505.
Pindyck, R. S., and D. L. Rubinfeld (1998) Econometric Models and
Economic Forecasts (4th Edition). New York: McGraw.
Rose, A. (1996) After the Deluge: Do Fixed Exchange Rates Allow
Intertemporal Volatility Tradeoffs? International Journal of Finance and
Economics 1, 47-54.
Said, S. E., and D. A. Dickey (1984) Testing for Unit Roots in
Autoregressive Moving Average Models of Unknown Order. Biometrika 71,
599-607.
Sims, C. (1980) Exchange Rate Volatility, International Trade, and
the Value of Exporting Firms. Journal of Banking and Finance 16,
155-182.
Sinha, D. (1999) Export Instability, Investment, and Economic
Growth in Asian Countries: A time Series Analysis. Yale University and
Macquarie University (Australia). (Center Discussion Paper No.799.)
Solimano, A. (1986) Contactionary Devaluation in the Southern Cone:
The Case of Chile. Journal of Development Economics 23 (September),
135-151.
Taye, H. K. (1999) The Impact of Devaluation on Macroeconomic
Performance: The Case of Ethiopia. Journal of Policy Modeling 21:4,
481-496.
Van Wijnbergen, S. V. (1986) Exchange Rate Management and
Stabilisation Policies in Developing Countries. Journal of Development
Economics 23, 227-247.
Authors' Note: We would like to thank Mr Ali Kemal of Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics for his valuable comments on this
paper.
(1) In this study we have used the methodology developed by Engle
and Granger.
(2) It is assumed that manufacturing indices underestimate the true
GDP but at the time of this study the relevant data were not available.
(3) We also applied the PP test but no different results were
observed.
(4) See Pindyck and Rubinfeld (1998) for detail.
Toseef Azid is Professor of Economics, Markfield Institute of
Higher Education (Loughborough University) Leicestershire, UK. Muhammad
Jamil is Lecturer, Department of Economics, Bahauddin Zakariay
University, Multan. Aneela Kousar is studying for her PhD at the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Unit Root Tests of the Variables
ADF Test Statistics
Intercept Trend and Intercept
Level First Level First
Variables Difference Difference
RER -0.6366 -3.7790 * -2.3553 -3.7572 *
EX -0.0250 -4.9881 * -1.6760 -4.9879 *
IM -0.1563 -5.0260 * -2.5227 -5.006O *
RM 1.9635 -3.5333 * 0.4964 -4.1240 *
Y -0.2021 -3.8513 * -1.8023 -3.8521 *
Clinical
Values
1% -3.4681 -4.0373 -3.4865 -4.0380
5% -2.8857 -3.4478 -2.8859 -3.4481
10% -2.5795 -3.1488 -2.5796 -3.1489
PP Test Statistics
Intercept Trend and Intercept
Level First Level First
Variables Difference Difference
RER -0.6769 -8.8883 * -1.8599 -8.8420 *
EX -0.4416 -10.3147 * -2.7596 -10.2563 *
IM -0.5021 -10.4757 * -3.7167 -10.4133 *
RM -0.8706 -14.5910 * -4.0738 -14.5130 *
Y 1.9392 -9.6106 * 0.2139 -10.0051 *
Clinical
Values
1% -3.5604 -4.0661 -3.5073 -4.0673
5% -2.8947 -2.8951 -3.4614 -3.4620
10% -2.5942 -3.1567 -2.5844 -3.1570
* Series is Stationary.
Table 2
ARCH/GARCH Specification for Volatility
Dependent Variable: D (LOG (RER))
Method: ML-ARCH
Sample (adjusted): 1983: 12003:4
Included Observations: 84 after Adjusting Endpoints
Convergence Achieved after 77 Iterations
Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob.
C 0.007764 0.005047 1.538148 0.124000
AR(3) 0.257173 0.121361 2.119068 0.034100
Variance Equation
C 6.08E-06 2.04E-05 0.298448 0.7654
ARCH(1) -0.044754 0.008760 -5.108715 0.0000
GARCH(1) 1.053971 0.035410 29.76473 0.0000
R-squared 0.105030 Mean dependent var 0.011572
Adjusted R-squared 0.059715 S.D. dependent var 0.036007
S.E. of Regression 0.034916 Akaike info criterion -4.153220
Sum Squared Resid. 0.096309 Schwarz criterion -4.008528
Log Likelihood 179.4352 F-statistic 2.317785
Durbin-Watson Stat 1.845568 Prob (F-statistic) 0.064288
Inverted AR Roots .64 -.32+.55i -.32-.55i
Table 3
Unit Root Test of Volatility Variable
ADF Test Statistics
Intercept Trend and Intercept
Level First Level First
Variable Difference Difference
Vol -1.8485 -3.6855 * -1.6956 -3.7532 *
PP Test Statistics
Intercept Trend and Intercept
Level First Level First
Variable Difference Difference
Vol -1.7671 -9.7126 -1.5551 -9.7445
Critical values are used from Table 1.
* Series is stationary.
Table 4
Granger Causality Tests between Manufacturing Productivity,
Volatility, and Real Exchange Rate
Lag Lengths
Null Hypothesis 1 2 3
LP_Y does not
Granger Cause Vol 1.38564 1.03773 0.79719
Vol does not Granger
Cause LP_Y 0.81375 0.46229 0.69771
LP_RER does not
Granger Cause LP_Y 20.7207 * 8.13809 * 1.45101
LP_Y does not
Granger Cause
LP_RER 8.44616 * 4.25034 * 3.89092 *
Lag Lengths
Null Hypothesis 4 5 6
LP_Y does not
Granger Cause Vol 0.49741 0.48711 0.43662
Vol does not Granger
Cause LP_Y 0.99489 0.71539 0.38470
LP_RER does not
Granger Cause LP_Y 0.51851 0.89355 1.64944
LP_Y does not
Granger Cause
LP_RER 4.11184 * 3.94662 * 3.47908 *
* P-value is less than .05 indicates rejection of null hypothesis.
Table 5
Linear Regression between Manufacturing Product,
Volatility, and Real Exchange Rate
Independent Variable
Vol
Dependent
Variable [[alpha].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1]
LP_Y 3.5379 * 322.2278 *
[R.sup.2] 0.061294
Independent Variable
LP_RER
Dependent
Variable [[alpha].sub.2] [[beta].sub.2]
LP_Y -3.194182 * 1.987633 *
[R.sup.2] 0.857717
* Significant at 5 percent level of significant.
Table 6
Unit Root Test for the Error Term
ADF Test Statistics PP Test Statistics
Intercept Intercept
First First
Variable Level Difference Level Difference
[e.sub.1] -0.3364 -9.2619 * -0.7684 -14.1524 *
[e.sub.2] -3.4702 * -- -7.9724 * --
[e.sub.1] Residuals obtain by linear regression between LP_Y and Vol.
[e.sub.2] Residuals obtain by linear regression between LP_Y and
LP_RER.
* Series is stationary.