Foreign capital inflow, skilled-unskilled wage gap, and welfare in the presence of the informal sector.
Gupta, Kausik ; Basu, Tania
This paper attempts to analyse the impact of trade liberatisation
on the skilled-unskilled wage gap and the level of welfare of developing
countries, which are generally characterised by large
"informal" labour markets. A neo-classical full-employment
four-sector model has been developed, where the informal sector produces
either a final product or an intermediate product on subcontracting
basis. Evidence shows that in either case, trade liberalisation, in the
form of an increase in foreign capital inflow, widens the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy under some reasonable
conditions It also shows that as a result of an increase in the foreign
capital inflow, the level of welfare of the economy increases, when the
informal sector produces a final product. However, when the informal
sector produces an intermediate product on subcontracting basis, the
level of welfare of the economy falls.
1. INTRODUCTION
International trade and skilled-unskilled wage gap has recently
emerged as a topic of substantial research interest in economics. The
issue is particularly important in the context of liberalisation of
developing countries. Inspite of the existence of a large number of
studies on this topic, we find most of the works are confined to the
issue in the context of developed countries. Only a few studies are
conducted for the developing countries. Robbins (1994, 1994a, 1995,
1995a, 1996, 1996a) and Wood (1997) have conducted some studies for the
East Asian and Latin American developing countries on the wage-gap
issue. The results of these studies show that liberalisation has reduced
the wage gap in East Asia but has widened the same in Latin America.
In recent years some attempts have been made to theoretically
justify these empirical facts. Feenestra and Hanson (1995) have
developed a simple model to show that increase in foreign investment in
Mexico has widened the wage gap between the skilled and unskilled
workers. Similar results have been derived by Marjit (1998, 1999);
Marjit, Broil, and Sengupta (1997) and Acharyya and Marjit (2000) in
their respective papers.
The present paper also tries to analyse the impact of a relatively
open trade regime on the skilled-unskilled wage gap in the developing
economy. Our purpose here is to focus on some of the structural features
of a typical developing economy, to incorporate them in the model and
then to look for the consequences of liberalisation. One of the most
widely observed characteristics of the labour markets in developing
countries is its formidable reservoir of unskilled labour employed in
the informal segment of the economy. This has been pointed out in
numerous papers. But in most of the papers the informal sector has been
considered in a Harris-Todaro framework (1970), which has been
criticised in recent years by a number of authors. (1) Therefore in this
paper a neo-classical full-employment model has been considered.
In the present paper we consider a multisectoral neo-classical
full-employment model where the labour force of the economy is divided
into two major categories--skilled and unskilled. Skilled labour is used
to produce an exportable product by sector x and an importable product
by sector m. Sector y produces an agricultural product and the informal
sector i produces a final product (2) with the help of unskilled labour.
In order to produce its product, sector x uses foreign capital, which is
sector specific, in addition to skilled labour. (Domestic) formal
capital is perfectly mobile between sectors y and m whereas informal
capital is specific to the informal sector i.
Our purpose here is to examine the impact of liberalisation, in the
form of an increase in the foreign capital inflow, on the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy and on the level of welfare of
the economy in the presence of an informal sector.
After specifying the basic model we consider an alternative version
of the model. In the alternative version of the model we assume that the
informal sector produces an intermediate product on a subcontracting
basis (3) for sector x, instead of a final good. For the sake of
simplicity we assume that the informal sector, instead of sector
specific capital, uses the same capital as that used by sectors y and m.
Here also our purpose is to examine the impact of liberalisation in the
form of foreign capital inflow on the level of skilled-unskilled wage
gap of the economy and the level of welfare of the economy.
The interesting results of this paper can be summarised in the
following manner: In the basic version of our model we find that
investment liberalisation, in the form of increased foreign capital
inflow, widens the skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy. However,
increase in foreign capital inflow increases the level of welfare of the
economy. Thus we can say that the Brecher-Alejandro proposition (4)
(1977) is not valid, as there is a change in the level of welfare even
in the absence of tariff. In the alternative version of our model we
also find that increase in foreign capital inflow widens the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy but reduces the level of
welfare of the economy. In other words, we can conclude that investment
liberalisation always widens the skilled-unskilled wage gap of a
developing economy, irrespective of the fact that the informal sector of
the economy produces a final traded good or an intermediate good on a
subcontracting basis. But the level of welfare of the economy increases
when the informal sector produces a final traded product. On the other
hand, when the informal sector produces an intermediate product, the
level of welfare of the economy falls.
The layout of the paper is as follows: The basic model is developed
in Section 2. Section 3 examines the comparative static results. Section
4 describes the alternative version of the model and the comparative
static exercises of this model. Finally, concluding remarks are made in
Section 5.
2. THE BASIC MODEL
We consider a small open economy with four sectors--the urban
skilled sector (x) producing exportable, another urban skilled sector
fro) producing importable, the rural unskilled sector (y) producing
agricultural products and the traded final good producing unskilled
informal sector (i). The products of sectors x and y are exported. All
the sectors use labour and capital as inputs to produce their products.
Skilled labour is perfectly mobile between the two sectors x and m
whereas unskilled labour is perfectly mobile between the other two
sectors, y and i. There exists full employment of both types of labour
force. Sector x uses sector-specific foreign capital, which is
exogenously given. (5) Similarly informal capital, is specific for the
informal segment of the economy. However (domestic) formal capital is
perfectly mobile between the other two sectors, y and m. The small open
economy assumption implies that the economy is a price taker in the
international market. Finally, we have the usual assumptions of a
neo-classical general equilibrium model like constant returns to scale
production function for each sector and competitive market conditions.
The notations used in this model are stated in the following
manner:
[P.sub.j]--world price for the product of jth sector, j = x, m, y,
i.
[a.sub.ij]--quantity of the ith input required for the production
of one unit of output of the jth sector
i = S,K,L, [K.sub.1], and j =x, m, y, i.
S--stock of skilled labour
L--stock of unskilled labour
K--stock of(domestic) formal capital
[K.sub.F]--stock of foreign capital
[K.sub.I]--stock of (domestic) informal capital.
[W.sub.S]--wage rate of skilled labour
W--wage rate of unskilled labour
r--rate of return on (domestic) formal capital
[r.sub.F]--rate of return on foreign capital
[r.sub.I]--rate of return on (domestic) informal capital
X--level of output of sector x
Y--level of output of sector y
M--level of output of sector m
I--level of output of sector i
Z--total factor income of the economy.
The equational structure of the model can be explained as follows:
The competitive equilibrium conditions are given by the following
four equations
[P.sub.x] = [a.sub.Sx] [W.sub.s] + [a.sub.KFx] [r.sub.F] ... (1)
[P.sub.m] = [a.sub.sm] [W.sub.S] + [a.sub.Km] r ... (2)
1 = [a.sub.Ly]W + [a.sub.Ky]r ... (3)
[P.sub.i] = [a.sub.Li]W + [a.sub.Kli][r.sub.I] ... (4)
The product of the rural sector is considered as the numeraire and
its price has been set equal to unity.
Factor market equilibrium conditions are given by the following
equations.
[a.sub.Sx]X + [a.sub.Sm]M = S ... (5)
[a.sub.KFx]X - [K.sub.F] ... (6)
[a.sub.Km] M + [a.sub.Ky] Y = K ... (7)
[a.sub.Ly]Y + [a.sub.Li] I = L ... (8)
[a.sub.Kli]I = [K.sub.l] ... (9)
Equations (5) to (9) imply that there exists full employment in the
factor markets.
In this model we have nine equations with nine endogenous variables--[W.sub.s], W, [r.sub.F], r, [r.sub.l], X, M, Y and 1. Thus
the system is determinable.
The working of the model can be explained in the following manner.
From Equation (1) we find that, given [P.sub.x], [r.sub.F] is a
decreasing function of [W.sub.s]. Again, from Equation (2) we find that,
given [P.sub.m] [W.sub.s] is a decreasing function of r. Thus it can be
concluded that both [r.sub.F] and [W.sub.S] are functions of r. i.e.
[r.sub.F] = [r.sub.F] (r) [W.sub.s] = [W.sub.s](r) where [[partial
derivarive]r.sub.F]/[[partial derivative]f > 0 and [partial
derivative][W.sub.S]/[partial derivative] r < 0
Using Equation (6), Equation (5) can be written as
([a.sub.Sx] /[a.sub.KFx]) [K.sub.F] + [a.sub.Sm] M = S [right
arrow][PSI] (r) [K.sub.F] + [a.sub.Sm] M = S ... (5.1)
where [PSI] = ([a.sub.Sx] / [a.sub.KFx]), [a.sub.Sx] = [a.sub.Sx]
([W.sub.S]/[r.sub.F]) = [a.sub.Sx] (r) and [a.sub.KFx] = [a.sub.KFx]
([W.sub.S][r.sub.F]) = [a.sub.KFx](r) Thus [PSI] = [PSI](r) where
[PSI]' > 0.
The combination of r and M which maintains equilibrium in the
market for skilled labour is given by the SS locus, in Figure 1. The
slope of this locus, as obtained from Equation (5.1) is given by
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Since the input-output ratio is positive and the function[PSI] and
the input-output ratio [a.sub.Sm] varies directly with r, therefore the
curve SS is negatively sloped.
Substituting Equation (9) in Equation (8), Y can be derived (6) as
a decreasing function of r. Thus Equation (7) can be rewritten as
[a.sub.Km] (r) M + [a.sub.Ky](r) Y(r) = K ... (7.1)
The locus of r and M, which maintains the equilibrium of the
domestic capital market, is given by the KK curve in Figure 1. The slope
of this curve as obtained from Equation (7.1) is given by
[(dr/dM)|.sub.KK] - [-a.sub.Km]/(M [a.sub.Km'] +
[a.sub.Ky]Y')
Since the input-output ratios are positive and the fuctions
[a.sub.Km], [a.sub.Ky] and Y varies inversely with r, the curve KK is
positively sloped.
The intersection of SS and KK locus gives us the equilibrium values
of r and M. Once M is determined one can easily determine X from
Equation (5) and Y from Equation (7). When Y is known, I can be
determined easily from Equation (8). Similarly the factor prices
[W.sub.S], [r.sub.F], W and [r.sub.I] can be determined with the help of
Equations (1), (2), (3) and (4), once the value of r is determined.
3. THE COMPARATIVE-STATIC EFFECTS
In this section we consider the impact of liberalisation on the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy. It is captured through an
increase in the stock of foreign capital inflow into the economy. With
the larger inflow of foreign capital into the economy, the level of
output of the sector using it increases. For given r and hence for given
input-output ratios [a.sub.KFx], [a.sub.Sx] and [a.sub.Sm], an increase
in [K.sub.F] implies an increase in the level of output of sector X. As
the endowment of skilled labour force, S, is given it implies a
contraction of M. In other words, from Equation (5.1) we find that for
given r, an increase in [K.sub.F] implies a reduction in A1 i.e. a
leftward shift of SS locus. However there will be no effect on the KK
curve. Hence a new equilibrium has been obtained, where both r and M
fall. As a result of decrease in r, both W and [W.sub.s] rise (as
[P.sub.m] and [P.sub.y] are given). Hence from competitive equilibrium
conditions (1) and (4) we find that both [r.sub.F]. and [r.sub.I] fall
and in order to determine the impact of liberalisation on the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy, we have to examine the
movement of ([W.sub.s]/W) with a rise in [K.sub.F] i.e
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Taking total differentiation of Equations (2) and (3) and then
dividing Equations (2) and (3) by [P.sub.m] and [P.sub.y] respectively
we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2.1)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.1)
where [[theta].sub.ij] implies the share of ith input in the
product of jth sector and [??] = dz/z for z
Putting [[??].sub.m] = [[??].sub.y], the equations can be further
transformed as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2.2)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.2)
Subtracting Equation (3.2) from Equation (2.2) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In an economy where the agricultural sector is backward and the
manufacturing sector is highly capital-intensive, we would expect the
value of([[theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly]) to be very low and the value
of ([[theta].sub.Km]/[[theta].sub.Sm]) to be very high. In such an
economy we would expect
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus it can be concluded that, under some reasonable conditions,
increase in foreign capital inflow raises the skilled-unskilled wage gap
of the economy.
We now consider the impact of foreign capital inflow on the total
factor income of the economy when the foreign capital income is fully
repatriated. (7) It is given by
Z = W L + [W.sub.S] S + r K + [r.sub.I] [K.sub.I] ... (10)
Differentiating Equation (10) with respect to [K.sub.F] we get
(dZ/[dK.sub.F]) = L(dW/[dK.sub.F]) + S(d [W.sub.S] / [dK.sub.F]) + K (dr
/ dK.sub.F]) + [K.sub.I] ([dr.sub.I]/[dK.sub.F]) We can rewrite as
(dZ/[dK.sub.F]) = L(dW/[dr.sub.I])([dr.sub.I]/[dk.sub.F])+
S([dW.sub.s]/dr)(dr/[dK.sub.F]) + K (dr /[dK.sub.F]) +
[K.sub.I]([dr.sub.I] / [dK.sub.F])
Using the Shephard-Samuelson relations we find from competitive
equilibrium conditions
(dW /[dr.sub.I]) = -([a.sub.Kli]/[a.sub.Li]) and ([dW.sub.s]/dr) =
- ([a.sub.Km] / [a.sub.Sm])
Therefore
(dZ/[dK.sub.F]) = L )[dr.sub.I]/[dK.sub.F])[(K.sub.I]/L) -
([a.sub.Kli]/[a.sub.Li]) + S(dr/[dK.sub.F]) [(K/S) -
([a.sub.Km]/[a.sub.Sm])]
As ([dr.sub.I]/[dK.sub.F]) < 0 and (dr / [dK.sub.F]) < 0
Under sufficient conditions (K / S) < ([a.sub.Km]/[a.sub.Sm])
(8) and ([K.sub.I]/L) < ([a.sub.Kli]/[a.sub.Li])
we find that (dZ / [dK.sub.F]) > 0
Hence we find that under the given conditions, an increase in
foreign capital inflow increases the level of welfare of the economy.
We summarise the results in the form of following proposition.
Proposition 1. Trade liberalisation in the form of an increase in
the foreign capital inflow in an economy raises the skilled-unskilled
wage gap of the economy. Such an inflow also increases the level of
welfare in the presence of the informal sector under some reasonable
conditions.
Finally, we are interested to examine the impact of foreign capital
inflow on the output of the informal sector. We have shown that as a
result of an increase in [K.sub.F], both r and [r.sub.F]. falls. Hence
from Equation (9) it implies that [a.sub.Kli] increases. Given the stock
of informal capital, [K.sub.I], we can thus conclude that the output of
the informal sector falls.
We can thus write the following proposition
Proposition 2. In an economy with skilled-unskilled division of
work force, an increase in foreign capital inflow reduces the output
of" the informal sector when it produces internationally traded
final goods.
4. THE ALTERNATIVE VERSION OF THE MODEL
Informal sectors of a developing economy mostly produce non-traded
intermediary products for the formal sectors of the economy, instead of
final traded goods. Empirical evidences also support this fact. (9) In
order to capture this characteristic of developing countries, we have
modified the basic version of our model and tried to examine the impact
of trade liberalisation on the skilled-unskilled wage gap of the
economy, within this framework. In this version of our model one can
assume that the product produced by the informal segment of the economy
is used both by the sector x and the sector m, as an intermediate
product. (10) But for the sake of simplicity, we assume that the product
of sector i is used as an intermediate input by sector x to produce its
product. Thus, sector x uses skilled labour, foreign capital and
intermediate product, i, to produce its product. It implies that the
competitive equilibrium condition of sector x is modified in the
extended version of the model as
[P.sub.x] = [a.sub.Sx] [W.sub.s] + [a.sub.KFx] [r.sub.F] +
[a.sub.Ix] [P.sub.i) ... (1a)
Since the product I is used as an intermediate product on a
subcontracting basis, its price, Pi, is endogenously determined and its
demand-supply equation is given as
[a.sub.Ix] X = I ... (9a)
Again for the sake of simplicity it is assumed that the unit
requirement of informal sector input by the formal sector, x, is fixed
i.e. the input-output coefficient, [a.sub.Ix] is fixed. (11)
To simplify matters, in the present model we assume that the
informal sector uses the same capital that is used by the formal part of
the economy, instead of sector specific capital. We refer to it as
domestic capital. Equation (4) of the basic model is thus transformed as
[P.sub.i] = [a.sub.Li] W + [a.sub.Ki] r ... (4a)
Equation (7) of the basic model is thus modified in the extended
version of the model, as the capital is perfectly mobile among sector y,
m and i instead of y and m.
[a.sub.Ky] Y + [a.sub.Ki] I + [a.sub.Km] M = K ... (7a)
Thus in the extended version of the model, we have nine equations
with nine endogenous variables r, [r.sub.F], [W.sub.S], W, [P.sub.i], X,
Y, I and M which implies the system is determinable.
In context of this model, we want to examine the impact of trade
liberalisation i.e. larger foreign capital inflow into the economy on
the level of skilled-unskilled wage gap. In other words, we want to
examine the movement of ([W.sub.s]/W) as a result of increase in
[K.sub.F] i.e
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
After total differentiation of Equation (8) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8a)
where [[lambda].sub.ij] implies the share of ith input in the
product of jth sector. Assuming that the production function of sector y
is Cobb-Douglas (12) production function, we can write the elasticity of
substitution as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and by using the Equation (3), (for details see the Appendix), the
above equation can be further transformed as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8.1)
Similarly Equation (5) can be rewritten as (see the Appendix for
details)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5.2)
Differentiating Equations (3) and (4a) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In a developing economy like India, the agricultural sector has
already experienced mechanisation in the form of Green Revolution
whereas the informal sector is mainly a labour absorbing sector, thus it
can be assumed that ([[theta].sub.Ki]/[[theta].sub.Li]) <
([[theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly])
Therefore [absolute value of [theta]] <0.
Similarly the value of [[??].sub.s] and [[??].sub.F] are obtained
from Equations (2) and (1a) respectively
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where B = {(-[[theta].sub.Ly])/[absolute value of
[theta]][[theta].sub.Sm]}
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where
A = -{([[theta].sub.Km][[theta].sub.Ly][[theta].sub.KFx] -
[[theta].sub.lx][[theta].sub.Sm][absolute value of [theta]] +
[[theta].sub.Sx][[theta].sub.Km][[theta].sub.Ly])/([absolute value of
[theta][[theta].sub.Sm][[theta].sub.KFx])}
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Substituting the value of ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]) in Equation (8.1), the equation can be finally
transformed as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8.2)
(see Appendix for detailed derivations)
Similarly by putting the values of ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] in Equation (5.2) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5.3)
where C = ([[lambda].sub.Sx][[theta].sub.KFx]A +
[[lambda].sub.Sm][[theta].sub.Km]B)
Using Equation (6) we can solve for ([??])and then by substituting
the value of ([??]) in Equation (5.3) the above equation can be further
transformed and from that we can express [??] in terms of [[??].sub.i]
(see the Appendix for details)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Again by differentiating Equation (7a) it can be written as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7.2)
Pre=multiplying Equation (8.2) by [[lambda].sub.Ky] and Equation
(7.2) by [[lambda].sub.Li] and then subtracting Equation (7.2) from
(8.2) after some mathematical manipulation and by incorporating the
value of [??] we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7.3)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
E = [[lambda].sub.Km][[lambda].sub.Ly][[lambda].sub.Sm]B)
[absolute value of [lambda]] = ([[lambda].sub.Ky][[lambda].sub.Li]
- [[lambda].sub.Ki][[lambda].sub.Ly])
As ([[lambda].sub.Ky]/[[lambda].sub.Ly]) >
([[lambda].sub.Ki]/[[lambda].sub.Li])
Therefore [absolute value of [lambda]] > 0
On the basis of the assumption that the rural sector of the economy
is much more capital-intensive than the urban informal sector of the
economy, it can be concluded that [[absolute value of [theta]] < 0
and A > 0. Since [absolute value of [theta]] < 0 and all
[[theta].sub.ij] s and [[lambda].sub.ij] s are positive.
Therefore B > 0, C > 0, E > 0 and D < 0.
Since [a.sub.lx] is fixed, it implies [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Therefore by incorporating the value of [??] = ([[??].sub.F] -
[[theta].sub.Sx] [A[??].sub.i] )in the Equation (7.3) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[[??].sub.i]/[[??].sub.F] > 0
Putting the value of [[??].sub.i] in the expression (as obtained
from Equation (3)) we get [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]
Similarly, by incorporating the value of [[??].sub.i] in the
expression (as obtained from Equation (2)) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Subtracting [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where G = [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since [absolute value of [lambda]] > 0, [alpha] > 0, A >
0, [absolute value of [theta]] < 0
Therefore G > 0
Thus
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
iff ([[theta].sub.KM]/[[theta].sub.Sm]) >
([[theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly])
In this model, it has been assumed that the sector m uses skilled
labour to produce its product whereas the sector y, which produces
agricultural products, absorbs the unskilled labour to produce its
product. The assumption ([[theta].sub.Km]/[[theta].sub.Sm]) >
([[theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly]) implies that for sector m capital
per unit of skilled labour is higher than capital per unit of unskilled
labour for sector y. Generally the sector that is dependent on skilled
labour invests more on capital than the sector that is dependent on
unskilled labour. In other words, capital used per unit of skilled
labour is generally higher than the capital used per unit of unskilled
labour. The reason is that the skilled workers are more trained and also
more familiar, compared to that of the unskilled workers, to work with
modern machineries and equipments. So the sector that uses skilled
labour find it profitable to invest more on capital equipments per unit
of skilled labour than the sector that uses unskilled labour. This is
true in both physical and value terms. Thus it can be concluded that the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy rises with an increase in the
foreign capital inflow.
We now consider the impact of foreign capital inflow on the total
factor income of the economy when the foreign capital income is fully
repatriated. It is given by
Z = WL + rK + [SW.sub.s] ... (12)
Differentiating Equation (12) with respect to [K.sub.F] we get
(dZ/[dK.sub.F] = L (dW/[dK.sub.F]) + K (dr/[dK.sub.F]) + S
([dW.sub.s]/[dK.sub.F]) = (dr/[dK.sub.F]) [K + L (dW/dr) + S
([dW.sub.s]/dr)]
Since we already know from competitive conditions (using
Shephard-Samuelson relations) that
(dW/dr) = - ([a.sub.Ky]/[a.sub.Ly]) and ([dW.sub.s]/dr) = -
([a.sub.Km]/[a.sub.Sm]) therefore
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
If we assume that the sum of the share of formal capital, K, with
respect to the share of unskilled labour in sector Y and the share of
formal capital, K, with respect to the share of skilled labour in sector
M (in physical terms) is less than 1, i.e.
{([lambda].sub.Ky]/[lambda].sub.Ly]) +
([lambda].sub.Km]/[lambda].sub.Sm])} <1, we find (dZ/[dK.sub.F])<
0 as (dr/[dK.sub.F]) < 0
We summarise the results in the form of following proposition.
Proposition 3. Trade liberalisation in the form of foreign capital
inflow in an economy widens the skilled-unskilled wage gap of the
economy, in the presence of an informal sector that produces an
intermediate product on a subcontracting basis, if the following
assumptions are satisfied (i) the rural sector of the economy is much
more capital intensive than that of informal sector, and (ii) sector m
uses more capital per unit of skilled labour as compared to the capital
used by sector y per unit of unskilled labour. The foreign capital
inflow with full repatriation of foreign capital income also reduces the
level of welfare of the economy in the presence of informal sector
provided the condition {([lambda].sub.Ky]/[lambda].sub.Ly]) +
([lambda].sub.Km]/[lambda].sub.Sm])} <1 is satisfied
4. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The paper has analysed the impact of liberalisation on the
skilled-unskilled wage gap as well as on the level of welfare of the
economy, in the presence of an informal sector. It has been considered
both as final goods-producing and as intermediate goods-producing
sector.
In the first part of the model we have considered that the informal
sector of the model produces a final good, so that its price is
internationally determined. While in the second part of the paper the
informal sector produces an intermediate product for the formal sector,
x, so its price is endogenously determined. In either case we observe
that liberalisation widens the skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy
under reasonable conditions. But with an increase in the foreign capital
inflow, the level of welfare of the economy increases, when the informal
sector produces a final product. On the other hand, when the informal
sector produces an intermediate product on a subcontracting basis, the
level of welfare of the economy falls.
Although some economists have analysed the problem of impact of the
foreign capital inflow on skilled-unskilled wage gap, the importance of
the present exercise is that we have introduced the role of he informal
sector to analyse the problem. For example, Ghosh and Gupta (2001) have
considered a Harris-Todaro framework and analysed the same problem in
the absence of the informal sector and obtained contrary to ours
results. However, for a developing economy one cannot ignore the role of
the informal sector. Once it is introduced, one can obtain interesting
results and empirically more valid results, for less developed
countries. Our model can be considered as a generalisation of the
Acharyya and Marjit's (2000) model. Here we have considered the
issue of the foreign capital inflow, and also both the final
goods-producing and intermediate goods-producing informal sectors, while
Acharyya and Marjit (2000) have considered only intermediate
goods-producing informal sector. Moreover, in our paper we have
considered a four-sector division of the economy to capture more clearly
the features of a developing economy.
Our paper would have been more interesting if both final
goods-producing and intermediate goods-producing sectors were considered
simultaneously to analyse the problem. Apart from this, one can take
into account the environmental aspects associated with the expansion of
the informal sector. We want to takeup all these issues for our future
research agenda.
APPENDIX
Basic Model
Proof of Proposition 1
Totally differentiating Equation (5.1) and (7.1) and rearranging in
matrix form we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The value of determinant matrix is given by
[DELTA] = [psi]'(r)[K.sub.F] [a.sub.Km] + [a'.sub.Sm] M
[a.sub.Km] - [a'.sub.Ky] Y [a.sub.Sm] - [a.sub.Ky] Y'
[a.sub.Sm] (i)
Since all the input-output ratios are positive and [psi]'(r)
> 0, [a'.sub.Sm] > 0, [a'.sub.Km] < 0,
[a'.sub.Ky] < 0 and Y' < 0.
Therefore
[DELTA] > 0.
Now using Cramer's rule we have
(dr/[d.sub.KF]) = - {[psi](r) [a.sub.Km]}/[DELTA] or
(dr/[d.sub.KF]) < 0
Similarly
([dM/d.sub.KF] = {[psi] ([a'.sub.Km] M + [a'.sub.Ky] Y +
[a.sub.Ky] Y')}/[DELTA] or [dM/d.sub.KF] < 0
In order to examine the impact of liberalisation on the
skilled-unskilled wage gap of the economy ([W.sub.S] / W), we have to
compare the change in [W.sub.S] and W due to increase in [K.sub.F].
i.e. log [W.sub.S] - log W = log y
Totally differentiating Equations (2) and (3), using the envelope
conditions and then dividing the equations by [P.sub.m] and [P.sub.y]
respectively we get
([dP.sub.m] / [P.sub.m]) = ([a.sub.Sm] [W.sub.S] / [P.sub.m])
([dW.sub.S] / [W.sub.S]) + ([a.sub.Km]r / [P.sub.m] / [d.sub.r]) ...
(ii)
([dP.sub.y] / [P.sub.y]) = ([a.sub.Ly] W / [P.sub.y]) ([dW / W +
([a.sub.Ky]r / [P.sub.y] / [d.sub.r]) ... (ii)
It is to be noted that in the above derivations, by the envelope
conditions we get
Ws [da.sub.sm] + [rda.sub.Km] = 0 and W [da.sub.Ly] + r [da.sub.Ky]
= 0
Again, since [P.sub.m] and [P.sub.y] are exogenously given
([dP.sub.m]/[P.sub.m]) = ([dP.sub.y]/[P.sub.y]) = 0
Therefore Equation (ii) and Equation (iii) can be transformed as
0 = [[theta].sub.Sm] [[??].sub.s] [[theta].sub.Km][??] (iv)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (v)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Subtracting [??] from [[??].sub.s] we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
From sufficient conditions we get
([theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly] < ([[theta].sub.Km]/
[[theta].sub.Sm])
and ([??}/[[??].sub.F]) < 0 (already proved)
therefore
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The Alternative Version of the Model
Proof of the Proposition 3
Differentiating Equation (3) and Equation (4a), using the envelope
conditions and also using hat mathematics we can rewrite the equations
as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(Since [P.sub.y] is exogenously given, therefore [P.sub.y] = 0)
By Cramer's rule we get
[??} = -([[theta].sub.Ky]/[absolute value of [theta]])[[??].sub.i]
... (i)
and
[??] = ([[theta].sub.Ly]/[[absolute value [theta]])[[??].i] ...
(ii)
where
[[absolute value of [theta]] = ([[theta].sub.Ly][[theta].sub.Kt] -
[[theta].sub.Ky][[theta].sub.Li]) =
([[theta].sub.Ki]/[[theta].sub.Li])-([[theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly])
Since the rural sector is more capital intensive than the informal
sector therefore ([[theta].sub.ki]/[[theta].sub.Li]) <
([[theta].sub.Ky]/[[theta].sub.Ly])
i.e. [absolute value of [theta]] < 0
Similarly differentiating Equation (2). using the envelope
condition and also using hat mathematics we get
[[theta].sub.Sm] [[??].sub.s] + [[theta].sub.Km] [??] = 0
Putting the value of [??} (Equation (ii)) we get
[[??].sub.s] = -{([[theta].sub.Km][[theta].sub.Ly])/([[absolute
value of [theta]][[theta].sub.Sm])[[??].sub.i] ... (iii)
Similarly from Equation (1a) and by using the value of [[??].sub.s]
(Equation (iii)) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (iv)
By using the value of [[??}.sub.s] (Equation (iii)), [[??].sub.F],
(Equation (iv)), [??] (Equation (ii)) we can calculate
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (v)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (vi)
therefore A > 0 and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (vii)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (viii)
therefore B > 0 and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (ix)
Differentiating Equation (8) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (x)
where [[lambda].sub.ij] represent the share of ith input in the
product of jth sector. We know that the elasticity of substitution of
the sector y is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xi)
By applying envelope theorem, Equation (3) can he rewritten as
[Wda.sub.Ly] + [rda.sub.Ky] = 0
or[[theta].sub.Ly][[??].sub.Ly] + [[theta].sub.Ky][[??].sub.Ky] = 0
Therefore [[??].sub.Ky] =
-([[theta].sub.Ly]/[[theta].sub.Ky])[[??].sub.Ly]
Thus
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Replacing (-[[??].sub.Ly]/[[theta].sub.Ky]) in place of
([[??].sub.Ky] - [[??].sub.Ly]) in Equation (xi) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since the production function is a Cobb- Douglas production,
therefore [[sigma].sub.y] = 1
Thus,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Similarly with the help of Equation (4a) we get the value of
[[??].sub.Li]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Substituting the value of [[??].sub.Ly] and [[??].sub.Li] in
Equation (x) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Putting the value of ([??] - [??]) (Equation (ix)) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xii)
Similarly by differentiating Equation (5) and by incorporating the
value -[[??].sub.Sx] and -[[??].sub.Sm] (as obtained from Equation ( 1
a) and (2)) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xiii)
Putting the value of ([[??].sub.S] - [[??].sub.F]) (Equation (v))
and ([[??].sub.S] - [??]) (Equation (vii)) in Equation (xiii) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xiv)
where C = ([[lambda].sub.Sx][[theta].sub.KFx]A +
[[theta].sub.Km][[lambda].sub.Sm]B)
since A > 0 and B > 0
therefore C > 0
From Equation (6) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus by replacing the value of [??] in Equation (xiv) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xv)
Differentiating Equation (7a) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xvi)
By putting the values of [[??].sub.Ky], [[??].sub.Ki] and
[[??].sub.Km] as obtained from Equations (3), (4a) and (2) in Equation
(xvi) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xvii)
Putting the values of ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]) in Equation (xvii) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xviii)
Multiplying Equation (xii) by [[lambda].sub.Ky]), we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... (xix)
Multiplying Equation (xviii) by [[lambda].sub.Ly] we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xx)
Subtracting Equation (xx) from Equation (xix) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xxi)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since B >, ([[lambda].sub.Ky]/[[lambda].sub.Ly]) >
[[lambda].sub.Ki]/[[lambda].sub.Li]), therefore [absolute value of
[lambda]] > 0, D < 0 and E > 0.
Putting the value of [??] in Equation (xxi) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xxii)
where a = [D/ [absolute value of [theta]] + E + {([[lambda].sub.Ly]
[[lambda].sub.Km]C)/([[lambda].sub.Sm])} +
([[lambda].sub.Sx][[lambda].sub.Km][[lambda].sub.Ly] [[theta].sub.Sx]
A)/ ([[lambda].sub.Sm])]
Since D < 0, E > 0, C > 0, A > 0 and [absolute value of
[theta]] < 0, therefore [alpha] > 0
Since [a.sub.Ix] is fixed, therefore [[??].sub.Ix] = 0
Thus [??] = [??] (from Equation (9a))
By replacing the value [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] in Equation (xxii) we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Therefore
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xxiii)
Since [absolute value of [lambda]] > 0, [alpha] > 0 and A
> 0
Therefore ([[??].sub.i]/[[??].sub.F]) > 0
Now we consider the value of ([??]/[[??].sub.F])
Putting the value of [[??].sub.i] (from Equation (xxiii) in the
equation
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Therefore
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xxiv)
Similarly we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (xxv)
where G = [{[absolute value of [lambda]] +
([[lambda].sub.Sx][[lambda].sub.Km][[lambda].sub.Ly])/
([[lambda].sub.Sm])}/{[alpha] + [absolute value of
[lambda]][[theta].sub.Sx] A}]
since [absolute value of [lambda]] > 0, [alpha] > 0, A > 0
therefore G > 0 and [[absolute value of [theta]] < 0
In this economy it has already been assumed that
([[theta].sub.Km]/[[theta].sub.Sm]) > ([[theta].sub.Ky]/
[[theta].sub.Ly])
therefore
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
REFERENCES
Acharyya, R., and S. Marjit (2000) Globalisation and Inequality: An
Analytical Perspective. Economic and Political Weekly 35:39, 3503-3510.
Bandyopadhyay, M., and M. R. Gupta (1995) Development Policies in
the Presence of an Informal Sector: A Note. Journal of Economics
(Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie) 61, 301-315.
Brecher, R. A., and C. F. Diaz-Alejandro (1977) Tariffs; Foreign
Capital and Immiserising Growth. Journal of International Economics 7,
317-322.
Chaudhuri, S., and U. Mukherjee (2002) Removal of Protectism,
Foreign Investment and Welfare in a Model of Informal Sector. Japan and
the World Economy 14, 101-116.
Chaudhuri, S., and K. Gupta (2004) Inflow of Foreign Capital,
Environmental Pollution and Welfare in the Presence of an Informal
Sector. Department of Economics, University of Calcutta. (Mimeographed.)
Chandra, V., and M. A. Khan (1993) Foreign Investment in the
Presence of an Informal Sector: A Note. Journal of Economics
(Zeitschrift fur Naionalokonomie) 61, 301-315.
Feenstra, R., and G. Hanson (1995) Foreign Investment, Outsourcing and Relative Wages. In Robert Feenstra, Gene Grossman, and Douglas Irwin (eds.) Political Economy of Trade Policy: Essay in Honour of dagadish
Bhagawati. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.
Ghosh, A., and K. Gupta (2001) Investment Liberalisation, Terms of
Trade and Skilled Unskilled Wage Gap in Developing Economies: A
Theoretical Analysis.
In R. Acharyya and P. B. Moitra (eds.) Aspest of Globalisation on
Industry and Environment. New Delhi: Lancer's Books.
Gupta, K., and M. R. Gupta (1997) Foreign Enclaves and Economic
Development: A Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Economics (Zeitschrift
fur Nationalokonomie) 67:3, 317-336.
Gupta, M. R. (1997) Informal Sector and Informal Capital Market in
a Small Open Less Developed Economy. Journal of Development Economics
52, 409-428.
Gupta, K. (2002) The Urban Informal Sector and Environmental
Pollution: A Theoretical Analysis. Centre for Environment and
Development Economics (CEDE): Environment Department, University of
York, U.K. (Working Paper No. 02-006.)
Harris, J. R., and M. P. Todaro (1970) Migration, Unemployment and
Development: A Two Sector Analysis. American Economic Review 60,
126-142.
Marjit, S. (1994) On the Participation of Local Capital in a
Foreign Enclave: A General Equilibrium Analysis. Journal of Economic
Integration 9, 489-501.
Marjit, S. (1998) Trade, Fragmentation and Wage Inequality in
Developing Countries. CSSS, Calcutta. (Mimeographed.)
Marjit, S. (1999) Trade, Wage Inequality and the Developing
Nations. CSSS, Calcutta. (Mimeographed.)
Marjit, S., U. Broll, and S. Sengupta (1997) Trade and Wage-Gap in
Poor Countries: The Role of Informal Sector. CSSS, Calcutta.
(Mimeographed.)
Robbins, D. (1994) Malaysian Wage Structure and its Causes. Harvard
Institute for International Development, HIID.
Robbins, D. (1994a) Philippine Wage and Employment Structure
1978-1983. HIID.
Robbins, D. (1995) Earning Dispersion in Chill after Trade
Liberalisation. HIID.
Robbins, D. (1995a) Trade, Trade Liberalisation and Inequality in
Latin America and East Asia: Synthesis of Seven Country Studies. HIID.
Robbins, D. (1996) Stospler--Samuelson Losts in the Topics Trade
Liberalisation and Wages in Columbia. HIID.
Robbins, D. (1996a) HOS Hits Facts: Facts Win: Evidence on Trade
and Wages in Developing World. HIID
Wood, A. (1997) Openness and Wage Inequality in Developing
Countries--The Latin American Challenge to East Asian Conventional
Wisdom. World Bank Research Observer January, 33-57.
(1) see the works of Acharyya and Marjit (2000); Chaudhuri and
Mukherjee (2002), etc.
(2) The informal sector sometimes produces final traded goods like
small engineering goods, jewellery, clay toys, etc. See the works of
Chandra and Khan (1993); Bandyopadhyay and Gupta (1995) and Gupta
(1997), etc.
(3) See the work of Gupta (2002).
(4) See the work of Brecher and Alejandro (1977).
(5) We assume that the rate of return on foreign capital which the
foreign capitalists receive by investing in small open economy cannot be
less than the given world rate of return on foreign capital. However, we
also assume that there is control on the entry of foreign capital in the
economy. The government of the economy directly regulates it, so that
its stock is given exogenously. This is the experience of many
developing countries in the context of liberalisation. Marjit (1994) has
citied the example of Asian tigers in this context. See Gupta and Gupta
(1997) for details.
(6) From Equation (9) we get I = [K.sub.I]/[a.sub.Kli],
substituting the value of I in Equation (8) we get [a.sub.Ly]{W(r)/r} Y
+ [a.sub.Li] {W(r)/[r.sub.l] (W(r))}{[K.sub.I]/[a.sub.Kli](r)} = L
[right arrow] [a.sub.Ly] (r) Y + {[a.sub.Li] (r)/[a.sub.Kli] (r)}
[K.sub.I] = L [??] Y = f(r) where ([delta]Y / [delta] r < 0)
(7) In case of a small open economy, in the absence of tariffs
national income or factor income is considered as a measure of welfare.
See the works of Gupta and Gupta (1997): Gupta (1997), etc.
(8) This assumption is feasible in context of a developing economy,
like India, where we generally expect [a.sub.Km] to be quite high and
methods of production are highly capital intensive. It is to be noted
that K is shared between sectors m and y. So it is reasonable to assume
that trait requirement of capital per unit of skilled labour is higher
than the average capital-skilled labour endowment of the economy.
(9) In India, for example, many of the large industries like
leather bag and shoe manufacturing industries, garments industries etc.
use the intermediate inputs, which are produced by the informal sectors
of the economy. For example, in Kolkata the informal segment of the
economy carries out leather-tanning process for the shoe and bag
manufacturing industries. Similarly, for the garment industry' the
dyeing and stitching of garments are done by the informal sector of the
economy on a subcontracting basis.
(10) In that case results will remain unaffected.
(11) implies that fixed amount of the product of the sector i is
needed as an intermediate product by the sector x to produce one unit of
its product. It rules out the possibility of substitution between the
non-traded intermediary and other factors of production in sector x. It
is a reasonable assumption from the point of view of the nature of
subcontracting between the formal and informal firms, as experienced in
India. In industries like shoe making and garments, large formal sector
shift their production to small informal sector firms under the system
of subcontracting So the production is done in the informal sector firms
while the formal sector firms do packaging and marketing One pair of
shoes produced in the informal sector does not change in quantity when
it is marketed by the formal sector as a final commodity. Thus there
remains a fixed proportion between the use of intermediary and the
quantity of final commodity produced and marketed by the formal sector.
(12) This is just a simplifying assumption. See Chaudhuri and Gupta
(2004). Elasticity of substitution of the production function is given
as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
since the production function is a Cobb-Douglas production function
Therefore [[sigma].sub.y] = 1.
Kausik Gupta and Tania Basu are both based at the Department of
Economics. University of Burdwan, Burdwan. West Bengal. India.