Agricultural terms of trade in Pakistan: issues of profitability and standard of living of the farmers.
Khan, Abdul Aleem ; Ahmed, Qazi Masood
1. INTRODUCTION
In the wake of the liberalised trade regime, Pakistan is undergoing
structural adjustments. At the heart of the adjustments is
liberalisation of markets and prices, including freeing the currency
market, reducing industrial protection, and introducing financial
austerity and macroeconomic stability. The agricultural sector is also
undergoing these changes, which include eliminating export taxes and
other trade restrictions and reducing producer subsidies (input and
output subsidies). Such changes in the sector are critical as
agriculture is the largest sector of Pakistan economy.
Due to the dominance of the agricultural sector in the economy and
its linkages with other sectors, the changes in value-added, employment,
and prices in this sector would significantly affect the overall
economic growth and employment in the country. The standard of living in
the country in general and in rural areas in particular are also
affected by such changes. Variations in the prices of agricultural
outputs and inputs affect income distribution, both within agriculture
sector and also between the agricultural sector and the non-agricultural
sectors. Pricing policies of the government and the local and
international trade environment, have a major impact on profitability in
the agricultural sector. Thus, changes in agricultural prices affect
living standards, employment, incomes, and poverty levels in the rural
areas. An increase in the producer prices increases the profitability
and improves the standard of living of the people depending on crop
income, and vice versa, keeping fixed other factors such as the quantity
of goods. If the rate of increase in consumer prices is more than the
rate of increase in producer prices then the farmers' purchasing
power declines. On the other hand, an increase in the prices of inputs
(which are costs to the farmers) results in a decline in the
profitability from agricultural production. In short, the farmers gain
if producer prices increase more than consumer prices and input prices,
keeping quantity fixed. However, under market clearing assumptions when
per capita production rises to an extent that it offsets the decline in
relative prices, the total gains to the farmers increase.
This paper aims to compute the relative price changes in the crop
sector to explore whether profitability in this sector has improved or
deteriorated. It also aims to gauge the impact of price changes on the
standard of living of the farmers. For this purpose, various terms of
trade are calculated. The terms of trade for crop sector are defined as
the ratio of the index of prices received by the crop sector to the
index of prices paid by the sector. In order to determine profitability
in the sector, the relative price changes between the prices received by
the crop sector for its products and the prices paid by the sector for
the major inputs used in the crop sector have been used. To ascertain
changes in the standard of living, the terms of trade between the prices
received by the crop sector and the prices paid by the farmers for
consumer goods and services are calculated. In order to account for
changes in productivity and population 'real per capita income terms of trade' are also calculated. A significant aspect of this
paper is that it studies the impact of partial (only output side)
free-trade scenario on the agricultural prices. It probes how movements
in international crop prices affect the profitability in the sector and
the standard of living of the farmers. For this purpose two further
indices have been calculated using international crop prices with
respect to domestic consumer and input prices.
The paper is divided into five sections. Section 2 reviews the
literature; in Section 3 we briefly describe the methodology and the
data; Section 4 presents results and discusses them and finally Section
5 concludes the paper.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
The debate over agricultural prices revolves around two different
views. One view is that the government must support the agricultural
prices and the farmers must be protected from the decline in market
prices of the agricultural commodities. Qureshi (1985) mentions that
high farm prices not only benefit the large producers but also the small
farmers. Higher prices in agricultural sector not only have implications
for an efficient use of resources but can also shift the production
function upwards by price-induced technological and institutional
innovations and infrastructure investment in rural areas. Brown (1978)
has shown a link between public investment and farm prices in
agriculture. Financial rate of return on agricultural projects increases
when prices for agricultural produce increase. This justifies increased
allocations for the agricultural sector.
Chaudhry and Chaudhry (1997) have criticised the pricing policies
of the government, arguing that the adverse pricing policies followed by
the government had a greater negative impact on small farmers than on
large farmers. They argue that, except for the 1960s, agricultural
commodities have generally been under-priced. This has led to lower
profit margins for the farmers and as a consequence declining employment
opportunities for agricultural labour.
The contrasting view is that the support prices and subsidies have
made the agriculture sector highly dependent on government support and
in order to survive in the WTO trade regime the sector must become
highly competitive, efficient, and self dependent. The proponents
believe that by reducing the level of protection, domestic resources
would automatically shift to the areas of comparative advantage. Chishti
and Malik (2001) argue that when government takes measures to reduce
duties and subsidies on agricultural trade, it results in increased
efficiency in agricultural production due to increased competition from
other countries. Producers of those agricultural products, which can
fetch higher prices in international market, generally gain from the
increased prices and larger market. Consumers in this case have to pay
higher prices. When the prices in the international market are lower
than the domestic market the free trade brings reduced profits for the
farmers but greater purchasing power for the consumers. In both cases
i.e. whether the prices in the international market are higher than the
prices in the local market or lower than the prices in the domestic
market, the society reaps the net gain.
Earlier studies such as [Lewis and Hussain (1967) and Lewis
(1968)], focus on the terms of trade between the agricultural sector and
the manufacturing sector. Afzal (1977) has addressed the impact of
relative price changes on the agricultural sector for overall Pakistan.
He has covered the period 1966-76 to see the movements in the terms of
trade in agricultural domestic prices only.
Cheong and D'Silva (1984) have computed the terms of trade
indices by using the estimates of GDP at factor costs in current prices
originating in agricultural and manufacturing sectors and their
corresponding estimates at constant prices. The main purpose of their
study is to assess the performance of agricultural sector in the light
of government policy. Qureshi (1985) has calculated three types of terms
of trade for the agricultural sector, for the period 1951-64: (a) net
barter terms of trade, (b) income terms of trade, and (c) single
factorial terms of trade. The net barter terms of trade of the
agriculture sector are computed by dividing the GDP deflator for the
agriculture sector by the GDP deflator for the manufacturing sector. The
income terms of trade for any sector measure the purchasing power of
that sector. The income terms of trade are defined as the ratio of the
value of sales by a sector to its average import price. Since no data
series exists for the marketed surplus, Qureshi (1985) has measured the
income terms of trade as a product of the net barter terms of trade and
an index of agricultural output. Single factorial terms of trade, is the
net barter terms of trade adjusted for changes in the productivity of
agricultural inputs.
Our paper is based on the methodology used by Zahid and Hyder
(1986), which studies the effects of relative price changes on the
agricultural sector. Zahid and Hyder (1986) have covered the period
1973-84 and have calculated agricultural terms of trade based on
producer prices, input prices, and consumer prices. The results of Zahid
and Hyder's study show that the domestic terms of trade with
respect to consumer prices improved over the base year-1973-74 for only
three years i.e. 1975-77 and 1978-79, and for the remaining periods the
domestic terms of trade declined over the base year. The real per capita
income terms of trade remained below the base year for first six years
from 1974 to 1980 and then improved for three years from 1980 to 1983
and declined in the last year of the study i.e. 1983-84. The terms of
trade index with respect to input prices remained above the base
throughout the study period. This shows that the rate of increase in
prices of agricultural output was more than the rate of increase in
prices of agricultural inputs, providing greater margin to farmers. When
we see their results of international prices received by farmers it
appears that if the international prices had prevailed in the domestic
market, the agricultural sector would have had more rapidly declining
terms of trade and the standard of living would have substantially
declined relative to the base year. The index of international producer
prices shows that there is a continuous decline in the prices of
agricultural outputs. They believe that the agricultural sector in
Pakistan appears to have become relatively worse off during the period
1973-83.
The study of Zahid and Hyder was in the context of a fixed exchange
rate regime. Since then, the economy has gone through various structural
changes and the role of international trade has also become prominent.
Moreover, the study of Zahid and Hyder does not discuss in detail the
implications of variations in agricultural output and input prices for
the farmers in particular and the rural population in general. In this
paper we have addressed these issues. The paper covers the twenty years period from 1983-84 to 2002-03. The analysis is partial in the sense
that it covers only the crop sector in agriculture, but the crop sector
alone generates around 50 percent of the agriculture value added. The
dynamics of exchange rates are now different from the seventies and
early eighties, and this paper incorporates these. The results stand
very useful because there is no other latest study available regarding
agricultural terms of trade.
The goal of this study is to answer the following questions:
* Are crop incomes declining for farmers?
* Are the living standards of farmers, that are dependent on farm
income only, improving?
* Has the purchasing power of farmers increased?
* Has profitability in the crop sector improved over the last
twenty years?
* Are the agricultural terms of trade contributing to rising rural
poverty? (1)
3. RESEARCH METHODOLOGY
(a) Sources of Data
Data are taken for the period from 1983-84 to 2002-03. There are
two reasons for taking 1983-84 as the base year. First, the exchange
rate mechanism shifted to floating rate regime during the early
eighties. Second, there is no study available for the period after
1983-84.
Data for the calculation of indices are taken from secondary data
sources. Domestic prices of agricultural products are taken from
Pakistan Economic Survey, Statistical Year Book, Agricultural Statistics
of Pakistan, and Monthly Statistical Bulletin. The Consumer Price Index
was taken from Pakistan Economic Survey and was adjusted for 1983-84 as
the base year. The world prices for the agricultural produce are taken
from International Financial Statistics (IFS). Prices of four
inputs--fertiliser, water, light diesel oil and pesticides were taken
from National Accounts of Pakistan, Pakistan Economic Survey, Pakistan
Energy Year Book, Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan, and Estimates of
Receipts for all Provinces, for various years. The data for index of
rural population was taken from Pakistan Economic Survey.
(b) Terms of Trade
Six types of term of trade are used in the analysis.
(i) Ratio of the Domestic Prices Received by Farmers to the Prices
of Consumer Goods and Services
First, the index of domestic prices received by farmers and the
index of consumer prices are calculated. To calculate index of domestic
prices received by farmers, 20 agricultural commodities were selected.
(2) A simple index of prices of each commodity was derived for the base
year 1983-84. The weights were calculated by the values of the
production of these commodities in the base year. The prices of the
commodities taken for this index are the average annual wholesale prices
that farmers receive for their produce. (3)
The indices were calculated as follows using Laspeyres Formula
(with 1983-84 as the base year).
PI = [20.summation over (j=1)] [W.sub.oj] x ([P.sub.ij] /
[P.sub.oj] x 100
Where, PI = Price Index for any group, j = commodity and i = year
(1983-84 to 2002-03), Woj = Weight of commodity 'j' in the
base year 'o', Pij = Current year price of commodity
'j' and Poj = Base year price of commodity 'j'. And
also,
W = [q.sub.oj] x [P.sub.oj] / [20.summation over (j=1)] [q.sub.oj]
x ([P.sub.oj]
Where, W is the weight of commodity 'j', qoj = base year
quantity of commodity 'j'. The formula stated above was used
to calculate all the price indices.
(ii) Ratio of the International Prices of Crops to the Prices of
Consumer Goods and Services The indices used to calculate these terms of
trade are the index of international prices of crops that farmers can
get in the international market (under unrestricted trade scenario) and
the index of consumer prices of goods and services. Eight commodities
were selected to calculate the index of international prices received by
farmers. Due to insufficient data on international prices of other
crops, more commodities could not be added in this list. (4) This,
however, will not affect the significance and reliability of our
analysis as the selected commodities covered a major portion of the crop
production of Pakistan. The prices of these commodities were converted
into rupees from dollars on the basis of prevailing exchange rates of
the respective periods. In the denominator the adjusted consumer price
index was used.
(iii) Ratio of the Domestic Prices Received by Farmers to the
Prices of Major Agricultural Inputs
Index of prices of agricultural inputs was calculated to find the
price trends of the agricultural inputs that farmers purchase
domestically for crop production. Four major inputs i.e. fertiliser,
light diesel oil (which covers most of the operational cost of
mechanical technology i.e. tractors, tube-wells, and other machines),
water, and pesticides were selected to compute this index. First,
separate simple price indices were calculated for each input. Then the
weights were found by using the base year value of each input's
consumption. Due to the unavailability of reliable data on seeds and the
common practice of the farmers of making their own seeds from the crops,
we have not included seeds in our analysis. It is worth mentioning that
although seeds are an important input for the crop sector, even with the
inclusion of seeds the remaining four inputs would weigh around 80
percent in total.
Quantity of fertiliser was available in nutrient tonnes and the
prices were available for 50Kg bags, hence prices were calculated per
nutrient kilogram. A weighted index was calculated for the three types
of nutrients and this weighted index was taken as the overall indicator
of fertiliser price trends. To calculate the index of water charges, per
acre water charges were calculated by dividing the 'Revenue from
Irrigation' with 'Irrigated Area Sown'.
(iv) Ratio of the International Crop Prices to the Prices of Major
Agricultural Inputs
These terms of trade are calculated using the price index of eight
agricultural commodities assuming that the farmers sell the commodities
directly in the international market. In the denominator we have the
price index of four agricultural inputs.
(v) Real Per Capita Income Terms of Trade (Domestic)
The terms of trade mentioned from (i) to (iv) reflect changes in
the profitability and living standard of farmers, only on the basis of
price changes. The gains however, are also affected by changes in
productivity of the farmers and the output levels. For instance, the
prices may decline for a period but an increase in per capita production
would result in higher gains despite of low margins. To account for
changes in productivity and population, we have calculated 'Real
Per Capita Income Terms of Trade' for both domestic and
international prices. Real per capita income terms of trade were
calculated by using Quantum Index of crop production and rural
population index. Quantum Index of Agricultural Produce was calculated
by taking the production of the same 20 crops listed earlier for all
years and their prices for the base year. The weights were same as the
weights in index of domestic prices received by farmers. This index
shows the output trends keeping the prices constant.
To compute the index of rural population, the rural population for
all relevant years (1983-84 to 2002-03) was estimated on the basis of
inter-censal growth rates between the 1981 and 1998 Census. Then the
real per capita income terms of trade index was calculated based on the
annual change in rural population. The formula for quantum index is
given below:
QI = [20.summation over (j=1)] Woj x (qij / qoj) x 100
Where, QI = Quantity Index, Woj = Weight of commodity 'j'
in the base year 'o', qij = output of the commodity
'j' for the current year. And;
Woj = qoj x Poj / [n.summation over (j=1)] qoj x Poj
Population index was calculated by using this formula.
PopI = (Popi / Popo) x 100
Where, PopI = Population Index, [Pop.sub.i] = Current year
population, and [Pop.sub.o] = Base year population.
(vi) Real per Capita Income Terms of Trade Based on International
Crop Prices
Method of calculation of these indices was same as the real per
capita income terms of trade based on domestic crop prices. The only
difference was that in order to calculate this index on the basis of
international prices we took quantum index of those eight commodities of
which the international prices are available. The quotient of quantum
index and rural population index was multiplied with the terms of trade
based on international crop prices and domestic consumer prices.
4. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
1. Standard of Living
(i) Ratio of the Domestic Prices Received by Farmers to the Prices
of the Consumer Goods and Services
From the results in Table 1, we can see that the terms of trade for
farmers have shown a mixed trend. The terms of trade declined from
1983-84 to 1986-87 and improved in 1987-88. They started deteriorating again in 1989-90 and this trend continued till 1996-97. However, in all
these years the index remained below the base year. There was a period
of only three years from 1997-98 to 1999-00 during which the terms of
trade improved over the base year. In 1996-97 there was a significant
drop in agricultural production of many crops due to pest attack. This
resulted in an increase in producer prices in the subsequent years.
There was a marginal increase in agricultural production in 1998-99, as
is shown by the index of agricultural production (see Table 2). In
1999-00 there was a bumper crop and due to excess supply the result was
a decline in producer prices. In other words, for most of the years the
index of consumer prices increased more than the index of producer
prices. The domestic terms of trade depict that, assuming constant
quantity and changing prices the purchasing power of the farmers has
relatively decreased over the base year. It shows that the farmers are
worse off and, as measured by this criterion their standard of living
has worsened for most of the years except for the years 1997-00.
In Table 1 the index of producer prices and the index of consumer
prices show that in all the years except for the period 1997-00 consumer
prices have increased more than the producer prices, although there is
not a very significant gap between the two. Similarly, Figure 1 depicts
that the domestic terms of trade with respect to consumer prices have
neither deteriorated significantly nor have they improved. The producer
prices and consumer prices have increased simultaneously but the rise in
consumer prices was more than the rise in producer prices in most of the
years as shown by the gap between consumer prices and the producer
prices.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
(ii) Real Per Capita Income Terms of Trade Based on Domestic Prices
The real per capita income terms of trade are calculated by
multiplying the domestic terms of trade for producer and consumer prices
with the adjustment factor. The adjustment factor was computed by
dividing the quantum index with the rural population index. The real per
capita income terms of trade was computed to take into account the
changes in production and population. It is taken as a proxy for real
per capita income. If the adjustment factor for any year is greater than
one, it means that the per capita production has increased in that year
and the value of adjustment factor of less than one would mean that the
per capita production has decreased. With greater than one adjustment
factor the real per capita income of the farmer might increase despite
of the decline in producer prices. This means that the decline in the
prices would be more than offset by the rise in production, and despite
of low margins the over all income of the farmer would increase.
Similarly significant rise in prices can also offset the decline in
production.
Our results show that although the domestic terms of trade based on
producer and consumer prices, keeping production (quantity) constant,
have decreased over the base year but due to rise in per capita
production the overall gains for the farmers have increased (see Table
2). This shows that the real per capita income has slightly increased
over time. Two main reasons could be cited for this increase in real per
capita income terms of trade for most of the years. First, that the
population growth rate has declined in both rural and urban areas and
second, that because of the greater use of fertilisers as compared to
the seventies and early eighties the productivity has increased.
Increase in per capita production despite of a marginal rise in producer
prices shows that the efficiency in agricultural production might has
improved. Farmers' margins have declined and in order to maintain
their standard of living the small farmers have tried to increase their
production. There are few years in which rate of increase in production
could not outpace the decline in the producer prices relative to
consumer prices, for instance 1989-90. In some other years real per
capita income terms of trade declined due to decline in quantum index,
for instance in 1992-93. In 2000-01 both the relative prices and
production declined. The increasing gap between the real per capita
income terms of trade and the domestic prices terms of trade, shown in
Figure 2, is due to the population control measures and rising
production. The producer prices have remained sluggish.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
(iii) Ratio of the International Prices of Crops to the Prices of
Consumer Goods and Services
These terms of trade are calculated for the purpose of building a
scenario in which farmers are allowed to sell their crops in the
international market under free trade conditions (and assuming that the
developed countries continue to provide agricultural subsidies to their
farmers) then what would be the impact on their standard of living.
The results show that the terms of trade were positive (i.e. above
the base year value) in favour of the farmers for only six years i.e.
1989-91, 1995-98 and 2001-02 (refer to Table 3, for graphical view see
Figure 3). For most of the period the terms of trade with respect to
international crop prices and domestic consumer goods prices were below
the base year. Another fact is that these terms of trade increased only
due to the exchange rate factor, otherwise the prices in the
international market are continuously declining over the study period.
This shows that the international market is going through momentous price adjustments in the wake of the WTO regime.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The result of these declining terms of trade is that if the farmers
would sell their crops directly in the international market their
standard of living would become worse. It is however worth mentioning
that if the developed countries remove their subsidies from their
agricultural sector the prices of crops would rise sharply in the
international market giving a greater margin to Pakistani farmers under
free trade scenario. This would naturally have a negative impact on
consumers and the farmers also in terms of consumer prices.
If we compare the international prices of crops given in Table 3
with the domestic producer prices of crops shown in Table 1 we can see
that the international prices have not risen at the pace domestic prices
have increased. This shows how the subsidies provided by developed
countries to their farmers have kept the international prices low and
have marginalised the farmers of developing countries by distorting the
international free market prices.
(iv) Real per Capita Income Terms of Trade Based on International
Prices
These terms of trade were calculated to see how the variation in
per capita production affects terms of trade based on international crop
prices. The results (in Table 4) show that because the production index
has increased more than the population index, the real per capita income
terms of trade are increasing. However, again if we apply the assumption
of managed float, even the real per capita income terms of trade would
decline over the base year. In the year 2002-03 these terms of trade
would have declined by almost 72 percent if we had a managed exchange
rate scenario.
2. The Profitability in Crop Sector
(i) Ratio of the Domestic Producer Prices of Crops to the Major
Agricultural Inputs Prices
These terms of trade have been computed to find whether the
profitability in the crop sector has increased or decreased over the
twenty years. The terms of trade have remained below the base year
except for the period from 1997 to 2000. The relative prices show a
mixed trend over the study period. Table 5 shows that the index of
domestic prices of inputs has increased more than the index of domestic
producer prices of crops. The reason of rapidly rising input prices is
that the government has gradually removed the subsidies from the
agricultural inputs. Producer prices did not increase substantially
during these years because since 1990s the government is reluctant to
increase support prices and the prices in the international market were
also declining.
The results show that keeping productivity constant, the
profitability in the crop sector has declined over the study period. The
only exception is the period from 1997-98 to 1999-00 during which the
profitability in the crop sector increased. The years of profitability
coincide with the years of rising standard of living, which is evident
from increasing domestic terms of trade with respect to consumer prices
and increasing terms of trade with respect to input prices for the same
period i.e. from 1997-98 to 1999-00. The terms of trade also show that
the life is getting difficult for those small farmers who are depending
solely on crop income.
Figure 4 further supports the argument. Gaps between the input and
output indices cause the terms of trade (with respect to input prices)
to fall below the base points of 100 in many years, and the terms of
trade have gone above the base year for only three years (1997-00). Like
the terms of trade with respect to consumer prices these terms of trade
(with respect to input prices) have also not shown any significant or
consistent movement away from the base year level.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
(ii) Ratio of the International Crop Prices to the Prices of Major
Agricultural Inputs they Buy Domestically
Through this index we are interested in investigating what would be
the impact on farmers' profitability if the farmers buy the inputs
domestically and sell their crops in the international market. The
results (in Table 6) show that the terms of trade for farmers have
declined over the base year except for four years (1989-90, and 1995 to
1998). Even the exchange rate factor could not offset this decline,
which means that If we assume to have a managed float the decline in the
terms of trade for the year 2002-03 over the base year would be around
42 percent. Figure 5 clarifies that this is because the index of
domestic prices of inputs has increased more than the index of
international prices of output (see also Table 6.1).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
3. The Trends in Real Per Capita Rural Income
In order to confirm our results and to see the changes in the real
income and standard of living of the farmers we have computed index of
real per capita rural income based on all major and minor crops. To
calculate this index, first of all we calculated real per capita crop
income by dividing value added of all major and minor crops at constant
prices by the rural population in each year. Then we calculated a simple
index of the real per capita crop income, using the un-weighted average.
The fact that this index is not weighted is a deficiency in this index.
As this index was calculated just to have a basic idea about the
direction of the real per capita rural incomes hence our results are not
affected by this deficiency.
The results shown in Table 7 depict that rural per capita income
has been increasing slowly over the years. There is a very high
correlation between the real per capita income based on all major and
minor crops and the real per capita income terms of trade based on
domestic prices of the twenty commodities we have included in our
analysis. This is shown by a comparison of Column 2 and 3 of Table 7,
depicted in Figure 6.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
5. CONCLUSION
In the wake of the WTO regime, the government of Pakistan is
changing its policies regarding the agricultural subsidies and prices.
Profitability in the crop sector and standards of living of the farmers
have been affected by these policies.
Consumer prices over the twenty years period have increased more
than the producer prices but there was not a very significant difference
in these indices. The purchasing power of the farmers has relatively
decreased and so they can buy fewer goods for their personal
consumption. This shows that the standard of living of farmers who
solely depend on crop/farm income has worsened. Although the terms of
trade with respect to producer prices and consumer prices were not in
favour of the farmers, the rise in production and larger sales volumes
due to increase in productivity have let the farmers maintain their farm
incomes. The real per capita farm incomes have shown a modest rise.
There were some years during which real per capita rural income did not
increase and even decreased.
If the farmers sell their products in the international market
under unrestricted trade scenario (and assuming that the developed
countries continue to provide agricultural subsidies to their farmers)
then the farmers would face a further decline in their purchasing power
and a deterioration in their living standards due to falling producer
prices. The fall, however, would not be very significant if the Pakistan
Rupee continues to depreciate. It is worth mentioning that, if the
developed countries remove the agricultural subsidies they provide to
their farmers, the prices in the international market would rise giving
greater margins to Pakistani farmers. The consumer prices of
agricultural commodities would then increase. The subsidies provided by
the developed countries to their farmers have distorted the
international prices and there is a continuous decline in international
prices. The declining producer prices in the international market have
also affected the profitability of the farmers. In the domestic market
also the input prices have increased more than the output prices. Except
for three years from 1997 to 2000, the domestic terms of trade with
respect to input prices have remained below the base year. One of the
main reasons of rising input prices is that the government has gradually
removed the subsidies on the inputs. The profitability for the farmers
has declined in the crop sector. This establishes a very strong argument
that because of the declining profitability in the crop sector the
farmers are now looking for other means of income, for instance
livestock, to meet their consumption requirements. The rising domestic
demand for livestock and the trend among farmers to adopt it as a second
means of income has resulted in a significant increase in livestock
value added.
Since, there is not any significant increase in real per capita
rural income over the last two decades because of sluggish growth in
crop prices, and the profitability in the sector has also not improved,
the farmers depending only on crop income must have become victims of
rising poverty. Although we have not established any direct link of
terms of trade with poverty but it seems that the worsening terms of
trade are contributing to rising poverty. However, this must be kept in
mind that these analysis cover only the crop sector and for a
comprehensive analysis other sources of income shall also be considered.
If developed countries cut down their subsidies on agricultural
products, the competitiveness of Pakistani agricultural products would
improve and Pakistani farmers can fetch better prices for their products
in the international market.
As far as the government policies regarding agricultural subsidies
and prices are concerned it can be suggested that if the government
reduces or removes the input subsidies it must increase the support
prices or explore new avenues so that the farmers are not further
marginalised.
Authors' Note: We have benefited from valuable suggestions
from Mr Haroon Jamal, Principal Economist at SPDC, and Mr Kalim Hyder,
Senior Economist at SPDC. We are also grateful to Mr Muhammad Ashiq of
the Agricultural Prices Commission, Islamabad, for his valuable comments
on the paper.
REFERENCES
Afzal, M. (1977) Parity Pricing as an Approach to Price Support
Programmes: A Policy Analysis. The Pakistan Development Review 16:3,
123-134.
Brown, Gilbert T. (1978) Agricultural Pricing Policies in
Developing Countries. In Theodore W. Shultz (ed.) Distortions of
Agricultural Incentives. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
Chaudhry and Chaudhry (1997) Pakistan's Agricultural
Development since Independence: Intertemporal Trends and Explanations.
The Pakistan Development Review 36:4, 593-612.
Cheong, Kee Cheok, and Emmanuel H. D'Silva (1984) Prices,
Terms of Trade and the Role of Government in Pakistan's
Agriculture. World Bank. Washington, D.C. (World Bank StaffWorking Paper
No. 643).
Chishti, Anwar F., and Waqar Malik (2001) WTO's Trade
Liberalisation, Agricultural Growth, and Poverty Alleviation in
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 40:4, 1035-1052.
Lewis, Stephen R. Jr. (1968) Effect of Trade Policy on Domestic
Relative Prices: Pakistan 1951-64. American Economic Review 58:1.
Lewis, Stephen R. Jr., and S. Mushtaq Hussain (1967) Relative Price
Changes and Industrialisation in Pakistan 1951-1964. (Monograph No. 16
in the Economics of Development.)
Qureshi, Sarfraz K. (1985) Domestic Terms of Trade and Public
Policy for Agriculture in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review
24:3-4, 363-384.
Zahid, N. Shahid, and S. Sajjad Hyder (1986) Pakistan's
Agricultural Terms of Trade: 1973-74 to 1983-84. Pakistan Journal of
Applied Economics. Applied Economics and Research Centre, University of
Karachi.
(1) Although poverty is not directly discussed, yet the answers to
the research questions will be helpful for deriving useful conclusions
about poverty in rural areas.
(2) These commodities were wheat, rice, maize, bajra, jowar,
barley, sugarcane, cotton, gram, moong, mash, masoor, onion, potato,
tomato, mango, banana, apple, guava and citrus.
(3) The use of average annual wholesale prices overestimates the
real value received by the farmers for their products. But because of
lack of data on the government procurement and support prices and the
changes in government policies regarding such prices, it was convenient
to take wholesale prices. It must also be kept in mind that under the
new emerging trade scenario the importance of market prices has
increased. Also, the data for average annual wholesale prices is more
reliable.
(4) The commodities selected for international prices received by
farmers were rice, wheat, cotton, jowar, citrus fruits, banana, barley,
and maize. The prices taken were producer prices.
Abdul Aleem Khan is a Research Officer at the Social Policy and
Development Centre (SPDC), Karachi, and Qazi Masood Ahmed is Head of
Research at the Institute of Business Administration, Karachi.
Table 1
Domestic Terms of Trade (Consumer Goods Price Index in Denominator)
Terms of Index of Index of
Period Trade Producer Prices Consumer Prices
1983-84 100.00 100.00 100.00
1984-85 97.22 102.73 105.67
1985-86 94.63 104.35 110.27
1986-87 93.92 107.29 114.24
1987-88 96.49 117.17 121.43
1988-89 96.28 129.05 134.04
1989-90 92.32 131.22 142.l4
1990-91 92.09 147.47 160.13
1991-92 95.13 166.99 175.53
1992-93 93.94 180.16 191.78
1993-94 98.91 210.89 213.21
1994-95 95.69 230.37 240.76
1995-96 92.18 245.90 266.76
1996-97 97.46 290.65 298.23
1997-98 100.71 323.83 321.54
1998-99 103.95 353.37 339.96
1999-00 101.01 355.74 352.17
2000-01 96.61 355.22 367.68
2001-02 97.13 369.76 380.70
2002-03 99.61 390.96 392.50
Table 2
Real per Capita Income Terms of Trade (Domestic Prices)
Terms of
Trade of Real per
Domestic Capita
Quantum Index Prices Income
of Agricultural Index of Received Terms of
Production Rural by Farmers Trade
Period (Domestic) Population and CPI (Domestic)
1983-84 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00
1984-85 115.03 102.23 97.22 109.40
1985-86 122.69 104.51 94.63 111.10
1986-87 126.66 106.84 93.92 111.34
1987-88 129.71 109.22 96.49 114.59
1988-89 136.13 111.66 96.28 117.38
1989-90 138.44 114.15 92.32 111.96
1990-91 143.95 116.69 92.09 113.61
1991-92 162.01 121.35 95.13 127.01
1992-93 146.60 123.86 93.94 111.18
1993-94 151.92 126.32 98.91 118.96
1994-95 160.42 128.75 95.69 119.22
1995-96 173.70 131.25 92.18 121.99
1996-97 168.95 133.86 97.46 123.00
1997-98 179.60 136.63 100.71 132.38
1998-99 180.31 140.70 103.95 133.21
1999-00 197.23 143.73 101.01 138.61
2000-01 186.33 147.00 96.61 122.46
2001-02 177.58 150.18 97.13 114.85
2002-03 185.63 153.26 99.61 120.64
Table 3
Terms of Trade Using International Crop Prices
(with Consumer Goods Price Index in Denominator)
Terms Index Index
of of International of
Period Trade Producer Prices Consumer Prices
1983-84 100.00 100.00 100.00
1984-85 98.83 104.43 105.67
1985-86 88.40 97.48 110.27
1986-87 79.09 90.35 114.24
1987-88 83.98 101.97 121.43
1988-89 96.55 129.42 134.04
1989-90 115.65 164.38 142.14
1990-91 105.34 168.68 160.13
1991-92 96.37 169.15 175.53
1992-93 93.44 179.20 191.78
1993-94 91.66 195.42 213.21
1994-95 97.80 235.46 240.76
1995-96 109.78 292.85 266.76
1996-97 119.89 357.54 298.23
1997-98 101.72 327.07 321.54
1998-99 95.74 325.48 339.96
1999-00 89.59 315.50 352.17
2000-01 93.16 342.54 367.68
2001-02 100.49 382.56 380.70
2002-03 96.26 377.81 392.50
Table 4
Real Per Capita Income Terms of Trade (International Prices)
Terms of
Trade of
International Real per
Quantum Index Prices Capita Income
of Agricultural Index of Received by Terms of Trade
Production Rural Farmers (International
Period (International) Population and CPI Prices)
1983-84 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00
1984-85 126.06 102.23 98.83 121.87
1985-86 141.07 104.51 88.40 119.33
1986-87 143.24 106.84 79.09 106.04
1987-88 150.50 109.22 83.98 115.72
1988-89 156.72 111.66 96.55 135.51
1989-90 157.89 114.15 115.65 159.97
1990-91 167.17 116.69 105.34 150.90
1991-92 193.61 121.35 96.37 153.75
1992-93 166.94 123.86 93.44 125.94
1993-94 163.03 126.32 91.66 118.30
1994-95 172.64 128.75 97.80 131.13
1995-96 190.51 131.25 109.78 159.34
1996-97 182.77 133.86 119.89 163.69
1997-98 189.72 136.63 101.72 141.25
1998-99 184.67 140.70 95.74 125.66
1999-00 218.84 143.73 89.59 136.40
2000-01 204.58 147.00 93.16 129.66
2001-02 194.85 150.18 100.49 130.38
2002-03 198.10 153.26 96.26 124.41
Table 5
Domestic Terms of Trade (with Respect to Domestic Input Prices)
Terms Index Index
of of of
Period Trade Producer Prices Input Prices
1983-84 100.00 100.00 100.00
1984-85 90.76 102.73 113.20
1985-86 93.50 104.35 111.61
1986-87 92.67 107.29 115.77
1987-88 94.69 117.17 123.74
1988-89 97.38 129.05 132.52
1989-90 85.96 131.22 152.64
1990-91 85.46 147.47 172.57
1991-92 95.94 166.99 174.06
1992-93 98.75 180.16 182.43
1993-94 96.68 210.89 218.14
1994-95 92.76 230.37 248.35
1995-96 98.52 245.90 249.59
1996-97 98.56 290.65 294.88
1997-98 104.16 323.83 310.90
1998-99 106.02 353.37 333.32
1999-00 104.62 355.74 340.02
2000-01 99.21 355.22 358.04
2001-02 95.85 369.76 385.79
2002-03 95.14 390.96 410.93
Table 6
Terms of Trade Using International Prices
(w.r.t Domestic Input Prices)
Period Terms of Trade
1983-84 100.00
1984-85 92.26
1985-86 87.34
1986-87 78.04
1987-88 82.41
1988-89 97.66
1989-90 107.69
1990-91 97.75
1991-92 97.18
1992-93 98.23
1993-94 89.59
1994-95 94.81
1995-96 117.33
1996-97 121.25
1997-98 105.20
1998-99 97.65
1999-00 92.79
2000-01 95.67
2001-02 99.16
2002-03 91.94
Table 6.1
Indices of International Prices of Output and Domestic Input Prices
Index
of Index
Producer of
Period Prices Input Prices
1983-84 100.00 100.00
1984-85 104.43 113.20
1985-86 97.48 111.61
1986-87 90.35 115.77
1987-88 101.97 123.74
1988-89 129.42 132.52
1989-90 164.38 152.64
1990-91 168.68 172.57
1991-92 169.15 174.06
1992-93 179.20 182.43
1993-94 195.42 218.14
1994-95 235.46 248.35
1995-96 292.85 249.59
1996-97 357.54 294.88
1997-98 327.07 310.90
1998-99 325.48 333.32
1999-00 315.50 340.02
2000-01 342.54 358.04
2001-02 382.56 385.79
2002-03 377.81 410.93
Table 7
Real per Capita Income, Terms of Trade,
and Real per Capita Rural Income
Real per Capita Index of
Income Terms Real per Capita
of Trade Income (Based
(Based on 20 on
Selected all Crops
Period Commodities) Production)
1983-84 100.00 100.00
1984-85 109.40 111.12
1985-86 111.10 115.01
1986-87 111.34 114.87
1987-88 114.59 113.98
1988-89 117.38 119.77
1989-90 111.96 118.65
1990-91 113.61 121.99
1991-92 127.01 131.38
1992-93 111.18 114.75
1993-94 118.96 117.55
1994-95 119.22 124.72
1995-96 121.99 129.24
1996-97 123.00 123.23
1997-98 132.38 130.66
1998-99 133:21 128.54
1999-00 138.61 135.36
2000-01 122.46 122.38
2001-02 114.85 117.60
2002-03 120.64 120.10