Exchange rate misalignment in Pakistan: evidence from purchasing power parity theory.
Qayyum, Abdul ; Khan, Muhammad Arshad ; Khair-u-Zaman 等
1. INTRODUCTION
Exchange rate provides a key link between the domestic and world
markets for goods and assets. Therefore, a proper and detailed analysis
of the behaviour of exchange rate is required. There is also growing
agreement that prolonged and substantial exchange rate misalignment can
create severe macroeconomic disequilibria and the correction of external
balance will require both exchange rate devaluation and demand
management policies. Thus the policy-makers have used PPP theory as a
guide to represent the external competitiveness of a country, and as a
benchmark against which floating exchange rates are judged to be
misaligned. Developments in 1990s and 2000s show that cost associated
with exchange rate misalignment is Very high. Hence, the analysis of
exchange rate determination in the presence of exchange rate
misalignment is crucial for the policy purpose because of its role as a
component of an early warning system [Berg, et al. (2000)].
It is not easy to set nominal exchange rate in its intended path.
There are conceptual and empirical issues that what exactly the value of
long-run equilibrium exchange rate. In the literature, there are at
least three broad definitions of misalignment [Williamson (1994);
Miles-Feretti and Raziun (1996) and Hinkle and Monteil (1999)]. First,
Price-based criteria, such as purchasing power parity (PPP) and its
variants. Second, model-based criteria, based on the formal models of
nominal exchange rates. Third, solvency and sustainability-based
criteria, which make reference to trends in the current account and the
external debts to GDP ratio. It turns out that the economic relevance of
each criterion is inversely related to the difficulty of implementing
it. Price-based criteria are relatively easy to implement and has strong
operational advantages. (1) Therefore, in this study a more modest goal
of implementing the price-based criteria is set forth.
Purchasing power parity constitutes one of the fundamental building
block in modeling the modern theories of exchange rate determination.
(2) This theory was originally advanced by Cassel (1916, 1918), asserts
that under the conditions of free trade (3) the nominal exchange rate
between two countries is equal to the ratio of the two countries price
level. This approach assumes that equilibrium real exchange rates remain
constant over time and therefore, the nominal exchange rate movement
tends to offset relative price movements. (4) The PPP hypothesis
postulates that exchange rates adjust to price differentials in open
economies to restore international commodity market equilibrium.
Basically, PPP theory relies on law of one price (LOP) (5) in an
integrated, competitive product market with an implicit assumption of a
risk-neutral world. The concept is based on a flow theory of exchange
rates (6) where the demand for currency is to pay for exports and the
supply is to pay for imports. Despite the fact that the theory has been
known for centuries, PPP remains controversial as ever. (7)
An extensive research has been carried out, inter alia, by Taylor
(1988); Giovannetti (1989); Patel (1990); Nachane and Chrissanthaki
(1991); Crowder (1992); Sarantis and Stewart (1993); MacDonald (1993);
Cooper (1994); Corbae and Ovliaris (1988); Ardeni and Lubin (1991);
Dornbusch (1988) and Moosa and Bhatti (1996) investigating the validity
of PPP theory during the current system of floating exchange rates. But
these studies have not found evidence in support of the hypothesis as a
long-run hypothesis. (8) As far as Pakistan is concerned, Bhatti (1996);
Liew, et al (2004); Tang and Butiong (1994) and Ahmed and Khan (2002)
found supportive evidence while Chishti and Hasan (1993) found evidence,
which does not support the PPP hypothesis.
The main objective of the study is to test the validity of PPP
theory of exchange rate determination and to evaluate whether PPP is
valid criteria for calculating misalignment in Pakistan for 1982Q2 to
2002Q4. The study is organised in the following manner. In Section 2,
the price-based measure of misalignment is described. Section 3
discusses the theoretical model of PPP. Data, econometric methodology
and empirical evidence are discussed in Section 4. Exchange rate
misalignment is calculated in Section 4, while some concluding remarks
are given in the final section.
2. PRICE-BASED CRITERIA OF EQUILIBRIUM EXCHANGE RATE
Purchasing power parity theory of exchange rate determination
asserts that the exchange rate between two currencies over any period of
time is determined by the changes in the two countries price levels.
This theory signals out changes in price levels as the overriding
determinant in the determination of exchange rate. According to this
theory, exchange rate may diverge from its PPP level in the short-run.
There are several reasons that why deviations from PPP occur. Firstly,
there may be restrictions on trade and capital movements, which will
distort the relationship between home and foreign prices. Secondly,
speculative activities and official intervention may create a PPP
disparity. Thirdly, the productivity bias when there is a relatively
faster productivity growth in the tradable sector than the non-tradable
sector will result in systematic divergence of internal prices [Balassa
(1964) and Chinn (2000)]. Fourthly, the prices are sticky and do not
move rapidly enough to offset frequently changes in nominal exchange
rates. Lastly, the apparent non-stationarity of real exchange rate will
be consistent with prevalence of real shocks in the economy. Moreover,
an important shocks during the past two decades include large commodity
price changes, innovations in the financial sector, imbalance in
government budget, differentials in productivity growth among major
industrial countries, etc. [Arndt and Richardson (1987)] also generate
short-run deviations from PPP.
3. PURCHASING POWER PARITY: THEORETICAL MODEL
The purchasing power parity theory serve as equilibrium condition
in the theory of exchange rate determination and in exchange rate
policy. This theory is still frequently used to determine the link
between exchange rate and relative prices. (9) The building block of PPP
is the law of one price. For any good, in the absence of quotas, tariffs
and other impediments to trade, trade and effective arbitrage in goods
markets should ensure identical price across countries. The law of one
price is stated as:
[P.sub.i] = S.[P.sup.*.sub.i] ... (1)
Here [P.sub.i] is the price of good i expressed in domestic
currency, [P.sup.*.sub.i] is the price of good i expressed in foreign
currency and S is the nominal exchange rate expressed in unit of local
currency per one unit of foreign currency. When aggregated over all
goods, the law of one price yields the purchasing power parity, which is
stated as
[P.sub.t] = [S.sub.t] x [P.sup.*.sub.t] ... (2)
Here P is the price level in the home country and [P.sup.*] is the
price level in the foreign country. Equation (2) is known as absolute
PPP. It is known that transportation costs, tariffs and non-tariff
barriers will entail market segmentation and create a wedge among price
across countries. However, if these factors remain constant over time,
PPP can be restated, using a positive constant B (10), as:
[P.sub.t] = B[([SP.sup*]).sub.t] ... ... ... ... ... ... (3)
In logarithmic form it can be expressed as
[p.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [s.sub.t] + [p.sup.*.sub.t] ... ...
... ... ... ... (4)
Rearranging Equation (4) gives the strong or absolute form of the
PPP
[s.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [(p - [p.sup.*]).sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t]
... ... ... ... ... (5)
Where [s.sub.t], [p.sub.t] and [p.sup.*.sub.t] are the natural log
of nominal exchange rate, domestic and foreign price indices
respectively while [[micro].sub.t] is the error term. (11) This version
of PPP is based on the law of one price, which states that the price of
a common basket of goods in the two countries, measured in a common
currency will be the same at all time because of costless spatial
arbitrage.
The testable version of PPP is expressed as:
[s.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] [(p -[p.sup.*]).sub.t]
+ [[micro].sub.t] ... ... ... ... ... (6)
Where [[beta].sub.0] is the logarithm of the exchange rate observed
in the base period. In Equation (6), the presence of a constant term
[[beta].sub.0] is justified by Krichene (1998) on two grounds. First,
since transportation costs, tariff and non-tariff barriers entail
markets segmentation and create a wedge among prices across countries.
Second, the use of a constant also necessary when prices are in terms of
indices.
PPP holds in the long-run if the restrictions ([[beta].sub.0],
[[beta].sub.1]) =(0,1) cannot be rejected. Moreover, an equilibrium
relationship exists when exchange rate and relative prices are
cointegrated. Further, if exchange rate changes over time but is
stationary ARIMA (p, q) process, then the deviations from parity are
largely temporary and are expected to disappear through time. Although,
one-to-one proportionality restrictions seem to be implausible and
unrealistic in practice when transport costs, other trade impediments
and measurement errors are allowed. Taylor (1988) and Sercu, et al.
(1995) demonstrates that in the presence of transport costs and
measurement errors in the price variables, the proportionality may still
hold, but it will not necessarily equal to unity (i.e. [[beta].sub.1]
[not equal to] 1).
4. DATA, ECONOMETRIC METHODOLOGY, AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
We utilised quarterly data ranging from 1982Q2-2002Q4. The exchange
rate ([s.sub.t]) was the end of period nominal rate measured in terms of
units of domestic currency per US dollar. Data on relative prices [(p -
[p.sup.*]).sub.t] were calculated on the basis of wholesale price index
(12) and were obtained from the IFS CD-ROM. Before conducting the
analysis of long-run relationship between exchange rate and relative
prices, we first test the order of integration of the stochastic variables by employing the augmented Dickey-Fuller (1979) unit root
tests. Table 1 reports the augmented Dickey-Fuller test results. (13)
These results indicate that the series [s.sub.t] and [(p -
[p.sup.*]).sub.t] are I (1) in their log-level and I (0) in their
log-first difference. Since both series, which would enter the PPP
formulation, are integrated of the same order, hence it is possible to
test for the presence of cointegration.
The test for the presence of cointegration is performed using
Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) multivariate
cointegration method. Two lags were selected for VAR following the
Likelihood ratio statistic adjusted for degrees of freedom. Moreover,
the VAR model includes restricted intercepts and no trend. Table 2
reports the maximal eigenvalue ([lambda] - max) and trace ([lambda] -
trace) statistics of the underlying VAR.
It may be noted that the exchange rate and price series reveal
strong evidence of cointegration using either of the two statistics. The
results also indicate the existence of a unique cointegrating vector.
The presence of a single cointegrating vector confirms the long-run
relationship between the nominal exchange rate and relative prices over
the sample period 1982Q2-2002Q2. Thus, we set a considerable support for
the so-called weak-form PPP, which purports that exchange rate, and
price levels are cointegrated to produce stationary residuals. In order
to examine the strong form of PPP, the maximum likelihood estimates of
the normalised cointegrating vector was obtained by imposing
exactly-identifying restrictions on the identified cointegrating vector.
Moreover, imposing over-identifying restrictions on the parameters has
also tested the proportionality restriction. (14) The results are
presented in Table 3.
These results indicate that all the coefficients possess expected
signs and are significant at the 5 percent level of significant.
Furthermore, the results of the coefficient restrictions test reveal
that PPP hold reasonably well; lend strong support for the validity of
PPP hypothesis as a long-run relationship. Our results are consistent
with the previous results obtained by Bhatti (1996) and Tang and Butiong
(1994) for Pakistan. Further, the adjustment coefficients (panel C,
Table 2) for nominal exchange rate and the relative price level are
negative and significant, indicating that both variables adjust to
correct the deviations from long-run equilibrium position. However,
exchange rate is adjusted faster than the changes in relative prices
towards the long-run equilibrium.
Panel B of Table 3 present the results of testing jointly the
existence of a single cointegrating vector and long-run weak exogeneity
of the variables [s.sub.t] and (p [p.sup.*]), for the parameters in the
PPP equation, which are constrained for the long-run proportionality of
the exchange rate and relative prices. This implies a single row in the
[beta]' matrix and a single column in the [alpha] matrix of the
form (*, 0, 0). The restrictions do not accepted by the data at the 5
percent level of significant. This result implies that both variables
adjust to correct the deviations from long-run equilibrium position.
5. AN ESTIMATION OF EQUILIBRIUM EXCHANGE RATE
Recently, a huge literature has been developed around testing
equilibrium exchange rate relationship [see Williamson (1994); MacDonald
(1995); Hinkle and Monteil (1999) and MacDonald (2000)]. Increasingly,
both practitioners and policy-makers have been using such relationship
to address the issue of exchange rate misalignment. Chinn (2000); Husted
and MacDonald (1999) and La Cour and MacDonald (2000) assessed whether
some currencies are overvalued or undervalued against US dollar or
Japanese Yen before the 1997 Asian crisis. In this study, the exchange
rate misalignment is calculated as deviations of the nominal exchange
rate from the level implied by PPP. If the actual rate is above (below)
the level implied by PPP then the domestic currency is overvalued
(undervalued). Figure 1 reports the implied misalignment for the period
1995Q1 to 2002Q4. These results indicate that throughout the period
Pak-rupee appeared to undervalue against US-dollar. However, the
magnitude of under-valuation varies over time and depending upon the
estimation of equilibrium rate. As of 2002Q4, the Pak-rupee is seemed to
be undervalued about 2.3 percent. The average percentage deviations over
the period 1982Q2-2002Q4 are 0.08 percent, which means that the
misalignment is corrected in about 3 years, while the maximum and
minimum values of the deviations are respectively +10.2 percent and
-5.11 percent.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
6. CONCLUSIONS
In this study we have tested the validity of purchasing power
parity hypothesis and exchange rate misalignment for Pakistan over the
period 1982Q2-2002Q4. From the empirical analysis we can say that
nominal exchange rate is cointegrated with WPI ratio. The cointegration
coefficient between nominal exchange rate and the WPI-based price ratio
is close to one. Furthermore, the coefficient restrictions are tested
using maximum likelihood ratio statistic, lend support for the validity
of the long-run PPP. Pakistan has been pursuing trade and exchange rate
liberalisation policies from the late 1980s. Through these reforms,
Pakistan has successfully eliminated most price controls and liberalised
trade. These trade and exchange liberalisation policies allowed the law
of one price to work more efficiently as shown by the supportive
evidence of PPP. Moreover, the short-run deviation from PPP has
frequently occurred, but the long-run validity of absolute PPP could not
be rejected. The adjustment coefficient is negative and significant.
However, the size of this coefficient is small indicating that the speed
of adjustment is very slow. Even though long-run PPP holds, the speed of
adjustment is rather slow, implying that misalignment is eliminated in
the absence of shocks but only after a substantial period of time. The
exchange rate remained undervalued vis-a-vis US dollar since the
adoption of managed floating exchange rate system. Finally, the
predictive power of these findings implies that exchange rate
misalignment relative to PPP would eventually be corrected through
commensurate movements in nominal exchange rates.
From the above discussions we can derive the following policy
implications.
* First: macroeconomic and structural policies should help to
converge along the same line as those of its partners. The economic
reforms help to enhanced economic efficiency and trade. Moreover, the
elimination of tariff and non-tariff barriers also helps to foster
private sector development and enhance economic growth.
* Second: there is a close relationship between the monetary
approach to the balance of payments and PPP. By managing real exchange
rates and reestablish international competitiveness reversing losses in
foreign exchange reserves and even rebuild these reserves to comfortable
levels.
* Third: the findings tend to confirm the notion of WPI-based PPP
as a long-term anchor; namely, nominal exchange rate will tend to adjust
to inflation differentials. Hence, the apparent validity of long-run PPP
might warrant testing more elaborate exchange rate models that allow for
a well-specified role of main macroeconomic variables, including real
income and money supply. In order to control the exchange rate
misalignment, the authorities should take appropriate measures to
contain the inflation rates.
REFERENCES
Ahmed, Eatzaz, and Farzana Naheed Khan (2002) Short Run Dynamics in
Purchasing Power Parity: A Case of Selected Asian Countries. The Middle
East Business and Economic Review 14:2.
Ardeni, P., and D. Lubian (1991) Is There Tend Reversion in
Purchasing Power Parity. European Economic Review 35, 1035-1055.
Arndt, S. W., and D. J. Richardson (1987) Real Financial Linkages
Among Open Economies. London: Cambridge: MIT Press.
Balassa, B. (1964) The Purchasing Power Parity Doctrine: A
Reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy 72, 584-596.
Berg, A, E. Borensztein, G. M. Milesi-Ferretti, and C. Pattillo
(2000) Anticipating Balance of Payments Crises, the Role of the Early
Warning Systems. IMF, Washington, D. C. (IMF Occasional Paper 186.)
Bhatti, R. H. (1996) A Correct Test of Purchasing Power Parity: The
Case of Pak Rupee Exchange Rates. The Pakistan Development Review 35:4,
671-682.
Bilson, J. F. O. (1978) The Monetary Approach to Exchange Rate:
Some Empirical Evidence. IMF Staff Paper 25, 48-75.
Cassel, G. (1916) The Present Situation of Foreign Exchange.
Economic Journal 26, 62-65.
Cassel, G. (1981) Abnormal Deviations of International Exchanges.
Economic Journal 28, 413-415.
Chinn, M. D. (1999) Measuring Misalignment: PPP and East Asian
Currencies in the 1990s. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C.
(IMF Working Paper WP/99/120.)
Chinn, M. D. (2000) The Usual Suspects: Productivity and Demand
Shocks and Asian-Pacific Exchange Rates. Review of International
Economics 8:1, 20-43.
Chishti, S., and M. A. Hasan (1993) What Determines the Behaviour
of Real Exchange Rate in Pakistan? The Pakistan Development Review 32:4,
1015-1028.
Clark, Peter, Leonardo Bartolini, Tamim Bayoumi, and Steven
Symansky (1994) Exchange Rates and Economic Fundamentals: A Framework
for Analysis. Washington, D.C. (IMF Occasional Paper No. 115.)
Cooper, J. C. B. (1994) Purchasing Power Parity: A Cointegration
Analysis of Australian, New Zeland and Singaporean Currencies. Applied
Economic Letters 1, 167-171.
Corbae, C., and S. Ovliaris (1988) Cointegration and Test of
Purchasing Power Parity. Review of Economies and Statistics 70, 508-521.
Crowder, W. J. (1992) Purchasing Power Parity Over the Modern
Float: An Application in Higher Order Cointegration. Economic Letters
40, 313-318.
Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller (1979) Distribution of the
Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Journal of
the American Statistical Association 74, 427-431. Dornbusch, R. (1988)
Exchange Rate and Inflation. Cambridge: MIT press.
Dornbusch, R. (1976) Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics.
Journal of Political Economy 84, 1161-1176.
Frankel, J. A. (1979) On the Mark: A Theory of Floating Exchange
Rates Based on Real Interest Differentials. American Economic Review 69,
601-622. Frankel, J. A. (1993) On Exchange Rate. Cambridge, Mass: MIT
Press.
Frenkel, J. (1978) Quantifying International Mobility in 1980s. in
Bernheim and Shoven (eds.) National Saving and Economic Performance.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 227-260.
Frenkel, Jacob A. (1976) A Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate:
Doctrinal Aspects and Empirical Evidence. Scandinavian Journal of
Economics 78:2, 200-224.
Giovannetti, G. (1989) Testing Purchasing Power Parity as a Long
Run Equilibrium Condition. Giornale Degli Economisti 46, 491-508.
Hinkle, L. E. and P. J. Montiel (1999) Exchange Rate Misalignment.
World Bank, New York: Oxford University Press.
Husted, S. and R. R. MacDonald (1999) The Asian Currency Crash:
Were Badly Driven Fundamentals to Blame? Journal of Asian Economics 10,
537-550 Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating
Vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control 12, 231-254.
Johansen, S. (1991) Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegrating Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models.
Econometrica 59, 1551-1580.
Johansen, S., and K. Juselius (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation
and Inference on Cointegration with Application to the Demand for Money.
Oxford Bulletin of Economic and Statistics 52: 2, 169-210.
Krichene, N. (1998) Purchasing Power Parity in Five East African Countries: Burundi, Kenya, Rowanda, Tanzania and Uganda. (IMF Working
Paper No. 148.)
La Cour, L., and R. MacDonald (2000) Modeling the ECU-US Dollar
Exchange Rate: A Structural Monetary Interpretation. Journal of Business
Economics and Statistics 18:4.
Levich, R. M. (1998) International Financial Markets--Prices and
Policies. New York: McGraw Hill.
Liew, Venus, Khin-Sen, Ahmed Zubaidi Baharumshah, and Terence
Tai-Leung Chong (2004) Are Asian Real Exchange Rates Stationary?
Economic Letters 38, 313-316.
MacDonald, R. (2000) Concepts to Calculate Equilibrium Exchange
Rates: An Overview. Economic Research Group of the Deutsche Bundesbank.
(Discussion Paper Series 3/00.)
MacDonald, R. (1993) Long-run Purchasing Power Parity: is it for
Real? Review of Economic and Statistics 75:4, 690-695.
MacDonald, R. (1995) Long-run Exchange Rate Modeling: A Survey of
the Recent Evidence. IMF Staff Paper 43:3, 437-489.
Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., and A. Razin (1996) Current Account
Sustainability: Selected East Asian and Latin American Experiences.
(NBER Working Paper No. 5791.)
Moosa, I. A., and R. H. Bhatti (1996) Does Purchasing Power Parity
Hold between Japan and Other Asian Countries. Journal of International
Economic Studies 10, 85-94.
Nachane, D. M., and A. Chrissanthaki (1991) Purchasing Power Parity
in the Short and the Long-Run: A Reappraisal of the Post- 1973 Evidence.
Applied Economies 23, 1257-1268.
Officer, L. H. (1976) The Purchasing Power Parity Theory of
Exchange Rates: A Review Article. IMF Staff Paper 23, 1-60.
Officer, L. H. (1984) Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate.
JAI Press.
Patel, J. (1990) Purchasing Power Parity as a Long-Run Relation.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 5, 367-379
Pesaran, M. Hashem, Yongcheol Shin, and Rechard J. Smith (2000)
Structural Analysis of Vector Error Correction Models with Exogenous I
(1) Variables. Journal of Econometrics 97, 293-343.
Sarantis, N., and C. Stewart (1993) Sea-Sanality, Cointegration and
the Long-run Purchasing Power Parity: Evidence for Sterling Exchange
Rates. Applied Economics 25, 243-250.
Sercu, P., Raman U., and C. Van Hulle (1995) The Exchange Rate in
the Presence of Transaction Costs: Implication s for Tests of Finance.
50, 1309-1319.
Shoven (eds.) (1981) The Collapse of Purchasing Power Parity During
1970s. European Economic Review 16, 145-165.
Tang, Min and Ronald Q. Butiong (1994) Purchasing Power Parity in
Asian Developing Countries: A Cointegration Test. Asian Development
Bank, Manila (Philippines), 1979. (Report No. 17).
Taylor, M. P. (1988) An Empirical Examination of Long-run
Purchasing Power Parity Using Cointegration Techniques. Applied
Economics 20, 369-1381.
Williamson, J. (ed.) (1994) Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates.
Institute for International Economics. Washington, D.C.
(1) The implementation of model-based and sustainability-based
criterion requires more detailed analysis. Especially, the
sustainability-based measures are very difficult to calculate, as they
require a fully fleshed out macroeconomic model. PPP-based analysis can
be used to make initial diagnoses and for identifying hypothesis for
analysing more detailed models.
(2) The flexible-price monetary exchange rate model developed by
Frenkel (1976) and Bilson (1978) presumes that PPP hold continuously,
the Dornbusch's (1976) Sticky-price and the Frankel (1979) real
interest rate differential models assumes that PPP hold in the long-run
only. However, the poor performance of these models required the
analysis of their underlying components, including PPP, to be tested for
validity [Bbatti (1996)].
(3) Transaction costs, capital flows and speculative expectations
are absent.
(4) Although the assumption of free trade, absence of transport
costs and speculative flows are unrealistic in the real world and the
exchange rate may deviate from its PPP level and real exchange rate from
its mean values.
(5) Law of one price states that when measured in a common
currency, free traded commodities should cost the same everywhere under
perfect market setting assumption (i.e. no transaction costs, no tax,
homogeneous goods and complete certainty). If the prices deviate from
each other, then the commodity arbitragers would capitalise by buying in one market and selling in another until the profitable opportunities
cease to exist.
(6) PPP is called the flow model since it traces the flow of goods
and services through the current account to determine the exchange rate.
(7) Much of the theory is reviewed and discussed by Officer (1984);
Dornbusch (1988) and Levich (1998).
(8) It must be noted that the majority of studies conducted to data
have been on developed countries and a limited number on high inflation
developing countries.
(9) Many countries undertake corrective measures of their exchange
rates based on inflation differentials with partner countries. While
fundamental equilibrium exchange rates (FEERs), derived from medium term
internal/external macroeconomic balance conditions, are becoming more
and more attractive for detecting misalignment in a country's real
exchange rate [Clark, et al. (1994)], PPPs remain much easier to
compute. Moreover, deviations between FEERs and PPPs have not yet been
analysed in empirical studies.
(10) In contrast, relative PPP refers to the relationship between
relative change in nominal exchange rate and the differential in
relative changes in price levels, that is, [DELTA]s/s = [DELTA]p/p -
[DELTA]p/[p.sup.*], or in logartithmic
form
[DELTA]s = [DELTA]p - [[DELTA]p.sup.*]
(11) Logarithm of constant B is [[beta].sub.0].
(12) We used (WPI) whole sale price indices (1995=100) for both
Pakistan and U.S. because the relative prices based on the consumer
price indices (CPI) seems to be 1 (2) i.e. [(p-[p.sup.*]).sub.1], ~ I
(2) while the exchange rate [s.sub.t] ~ I (1).
(13) These unit root test results carried out by including linear
trend and constant and constant only.
(14) These restrictions have been tested by employing Johansen
(1988, 1991) maximum likelihood ratio test.
Abdul Qayyum is Associate Professor, Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad. Muhammad Arshad Khan is Associate
Professor, Government Post-graduate College, Muzaffarabad, Azad Jammu
and Kashmir. Khair-u-Zaman is Professor, Gomal University, D. I. Khan.
Table 1
Unit Root Tests
Log-Level Log-first Difference
Series C C & T C C & T
[S.sub.t] -0.4692(0) -2.443(0) -8.485(0) ** -8.432(0) **
[(p-p*).sub.t] -0.7231(3) -1.502(3) -3.743(2) ** -3.570(2) *
Critical Values
1% -3.52 -4.08
5% -2.9 -3.47
** and * indicate significant at 1 percent and 5 percent levels
respectively.
C&T are respectively represents constant and trend.
Table 2
Cointegration Analysis of the PPP Hypothesis Series [[s.sub.t]
[(p - p*).sub.t] and lags = 2
Eigenvalues 0.31534 0.050444
Hypothesis r=0 r<=1
[lambda] - max 31.06(0.000) ** 4.24(0.388)
[lambda] - trace 35.31(0.000) ** 4.24(0.389)
[lambda] - max(T - nm) + 29.55(0.000) ** 4.04(0.418)
[lambda] - trace(T - nm)+ 33.59(0.000) ** 4.04(0.419)
Panel B: Standardised Eigenveetor([beta]')
[S.sub.t] 1.0000 -0.85630
[(p - p*).sub.t] -1.1031 1.0000
Constant -3.9206 3.0597
Panel C: Standardised Adjustment Coefficient (a)
[S.sub.t] -0.072218 0.050583
[(p - p*).sub.t] -0.026476 -0.046840
** Indicate 99 percent level of significant. The critical values
are taken from Pesaran, et at. (2000).
+ The [lambda]-max and [lambda]-trace are maximum eigenvalue and
trace statistics, adjusted for degrees of freedom.
Table 3
Testing for Coeff cients Restrictions
Panel A: Coefficients and Coefficient Restrictions
[[beta].sub.0] 3.9206
(0.0615)
[[beta].sub.1] 1.1031
(0.0844) **
Log-likelihood Ratio 393.5807
[chi square] ([[beta].sub.0] = 0) 4.4805 **
[chi square] ([[beta].sub.1] = 1) 0.9134
[chi square] ([[beta].sub.0], 4.8021
[[beta].sub.1] = 1) (0, 1)
Panel B: Coefficient Restrictions and Weak Exogeneity
(Standardised f eigenvectors and [alpha] = A[theta] coefficients)
[(p-p*)
[s.sub.t] .sub.t] constant
[beta]' 1.0000 -1.0000 0.0000
[alpha] -0.0061597 0.0000 0.0000
(0.0014462) **
LR-Test of Restrictions, Rank=1: [chi sqaure](3)= 16.316 (0.0010) **
** Indicate significant at the 99 percent level. Figures in
parentheses indicate standard errors.