Financial market linkages in South Asia: evidence using a multivariate GARCH model.
Khalid, Ahmed M. ; Rajaguru, Gulasekaran
1. INTRODUCTION
The economic and social benefits of more openness and
internationalisation are well supported by both academics and
policy-makers. Many countries are also trying to become part of the
world trade bloc such as the World Trade Organisation (WTO) or AFTA.
Efforts are also made to strengthen the existing regional economic and
trade coordination or establish new regional economic and financial
integration. Unfortunately, at the time (during the 1980s and 1990s)
when many emerging economies in East Asia were involved in openness,
internationalisation and regional economic and financial integration,
the South Asian countries wasted their resources in dealing with
political crisis (such as Bangladesh), internal conflicts (such as Sri
Lanka) or border issues (such as India and Pakistan). It is only
recently that regimes have realised that a peaceful economic environment
is essential to attract foreign investment, pursue a pro-growth policy
and achieve a sustainable growth. The recent dialogue between Pakistan
and India and some progress in SAARC consultation are a few steps
towards these goals. (1)
Another important and related argument of the emerging
globalisation and the new financial architecture is to enhance currency
coordination among developed and emerging economies in the global world.
Some leading international finance economists such as Robert Mundell [Mundell (2003)] and Larry Sjaastd, suggests that the world will
gradually converge to a tri-polar regime where US dollar, euro and
Japanese yen will dominate the currency market in the world. Obviously,
most of the countries in the American region to link their currency with
the US dollar while euro is already dominating the Europe. Japanese yen
is expected to lead the Asian region under this scenario. Pound sterling
is expected to serve as an anchor currency for some African and Asian
countries. These researchers anticipate that 60 percent of the world
currencies will converge to euro within the next two decades. Whatever
the outcome might be, this will be a return to some kind of Bretton
Woods system with three anchor currencies ruling the world rather than
US dollar under the old system.
If these perceptions are true, then the emerging economies in the
South Asian region such as India, Pakistan, Bangladesh, and Sri Lanka
will have to make a choice for an anchor currency for their financial
dealings and transactions. Some academics are already working on the
feasibility of a single currency for Southeast Asia. Their research
focus is whether Southeast Asian countries particularly ASEAN provides a
basis for an optimum currency area (OCA) which is a pre-requisite and an
essential argument for any discussion on a 'single currency'
arrangement. There is no doubt that the Southeast Asian region presents
a reasonable degree of economic and financial interdependence. (2) The
simultaneous fall of most of the regional currencies during the 1997
Asian financial crisis is an evidence of the how closely the currencies
of this region are interlinked. Whether South Asia provides a similar
common economic and financial environment is not so obvious.
Given these regional developments, it is imperative to initiate
academic research to help design and implement medium to long-term
economic policies to establish some regional economic and financial
integration. The issue of regional economic and financial integrations
has a wide research spectrum and cannot be covered in one paper. At this
point, we do not investigate whether the South Asian region qualifies as
an OCA or look into complete economic and financial integration or the
trade interdependence. We leave these important issues to be
investigated in a separate research paper. In this paper, we only look
into the possibility of regional currency integration. Such an analysis
is important in view of an anticipated tri-polar regime. Any future
economic policies will be dependent on the choice of an anchor currency
for an individual country or for the region as a whole. In this paper,
our focus is to investigate the currency integration within South Asian
region. With this as the main objective of this paper, we use a sample
of four South Asian countries, namely, India, Pakistan, Bangladesh and
Sri Lanka to investigate any possible currency integration within this
region. We try to answer three important questions. One, are there any
currency linkages within the currencies of the sample countries. Two,
how are these currencies linked to their major trading partners. And
three, is there any single major currency that influences currencies of
the region and may provide a basis for an anchor currency. For
analytical purposes, we use high frequency data (daily observations) and
apply some recently developed econometric tests (Multivariate GARCH model).
The remainder of the paper is organised in the following manner.
Section 2 provides a brief overview of the recent currency market
reforms and developments in the sample countries. Section 3 details the
methodology and the data. Section 4 discusses the results of the
empirical tests. Finally, Section 5 concludes the report.
2. CURRENCY MARKET REFORMS AND DEVELOPMENTS IN SOUTH ASIA
A close look at the economic performance of the four sample
countries since independence suggest that all four countries being
studied in this paper embarked on some significant economic and
financial sector reform policies in the early 1990s [see Ariff and
Khalid (2005)]. Although, the pace and sequence of these reforms varies
across countries, these reforms were expected to have some positive
effect on these economies. A summary of economic performance of the four
countries is provided in Table 1 and gives an idea of how these
economies have grown over the last 5 decades. In this section, we
exclusively look at the currency market reforms and developments in each
of the South Asian countries being studied in this paper. A summary of
these reforms is provided in Table 2.
2.1. India (3)
Exchange rate policy was the leading candidate for reform initiated
in 1991. Reforms to the multiple exchange rates and controls on
producers and individuals were lifted after a massive devaluation of the
rupee by 23 percent in 1991. Steps soon followed to unify the multiple
exchange rates into one in 1992. By March 1993, further reforms were put
in place to remove controls on restrictions on producers holding foreign
exchange. The managed exchange rate adopted against a basket of
currencies has led to greater stability of currency. The exchange rate
in early 2004 was Rupee 41 = US$1.00, a gain of 3 percent per year on
the average over three years.
India has followed a fixed adjustable exchange rate regime, which,
when adjusted frequently by the authorities, reflected the market rates
quite closely. The Indian rupee declined systematically against the
dollar over the decades except in 1985, 1987 and 1997 when it rose by
small amounts. The real rate of interest was 6.5 percent (relative to
much lower real deposit rates in the United States). However, the high
demand for foreign exchange on account of the deficits in fund to the
tune of 3.6 percent of GDP, the need for foreign debt servicing, and the
generally lower productivity levels (figures not available) drove the
rupee down over the years.
The average depreciation of the rupee against the dollar was some
10.6 percent per year over the decade to 1991. In ten years, the
currency declined in value by half.
Depreciation halved to about 4 percent during 1992-99. The partial
free-float of the rupee in March 1993 sent it to its all-time low as it
corrected the past misalignment with the market and partly also on
account of the current account crisis just prior to that reform. Since
1996, this depreciation has slowed, and the rupee started to appreciate
from about 1998. Another often-quoted problem at the root of the
inflation, and hence the depreciation of the currency, was the high
level of monetary expansion caused by the Keynesian deficit budgeting
for years under the import substituting policies. The rupee declined by
some 19.66 percent in 1993, but subsequently stabilised against the
dollar. Contrary to expectations before the reforms, the Rupee held
steady against the dollar, and on several occasions in the second half
of the 1990s the RBI had to intervene to keep the Rupee from
appreciating. One report said that the RBI spent US$ 1,000 million
protecting the rupee in the first half of 1994: see RBI reports. RBI
interventions have occurred whenever inflows through portfolio
investments and export receivables surged. As part of exchange rate
reforms, authorised dealers in foreign exchange have now been permitted
to write cross-currency options to provide customers a hedge on their
foreign exchange exposure.
The rupee is expected to stabilise, given the open current and
capital accounts, against the dollar, and is not expected to appreciate.
On the other hand, the experience on exchange rate management in other
countries suggests that unless productivity improves in the economy
along with a low inflation rate with high external reserve to support
the currency, it is unlikely that the currency can halt the downward
moves. But, the depreciation of the currency since 1993 has been about
1.4 percent, which is a vast improvement. The RBI is pursuing a monetary
policy based on sterilising the inflationary effect through foreign
exchange swap operation. This is also helpful.
2.2. Pakistan (4)
During the 1991-92 reforms, the authorities announced bold measures
to eliminate the black market for domestic currency and provided
incentives to attract foreign direct investment. The country moved
gradually to capital and current account convertibility. The State Bank
of Pakistan (SBP) also issued US dollar denominated bearer certificates
with a rate of return of quarter of a percent over the prevailing LIBOR.
Restrictions on holding foreign currency and operating foreign currency
accounts were abolished. Liberalised rules governing private
sector's foreign borrowing came into effect. Authorities authorised
dealers to operate and trade in foreign currencies.
These policies worked well and resident and non-residents opened
foreign currency accounts. However, the confidence was completely lost
when the government decided to freeze all foreign currency accounts in
May 1998, when the country reached near bankruptcy as a result of
economic sanctions for test firing an atomic device. Initially, the SBP
fixed the exchange rate at R46 per US dollar while the open market rate
reached R70. This was probably the highest difference between the
official and open market rates since 1973 when the country switched to a
floating rate regime. Foreign reserves fell to their lowest level, just
equivalent to two weeks of imports. This was an alarming situation in
itself. During closing two years of the last century, the IMF agreed to
extend partial loans and reserve the situation slightly. In 1999, the
government relaxed foreign currency restriction for exporters and
travellers. At the same time, in order to discourage the black market
for US dollars and to reduce the gap between the official and open
market rates, the SBP devalued the currency and fixed it at R50 to one
dollar. The currency touched a record tow level of R62 to one dollar in
2001. Later, the global factors in the post September 11 scenario
changed this trend. In 2002, for the first time in history, the currency
gained some value in the foreign exchange market with the rupee
appreciating by almost 4 percent against the US dollar. Since then, the
currency movement seems to have stabilised.
2.3. Sri Lanka (5)
Sri Lanka started with a fixed exchange rate regime where rupee was
100 percent pegged in 1948 to the pound sterling: this was similar to
the policies followed in most neighbouring countries. Until 1966, the
regime managed to keep the rupee-sterling parity without any
devaluation, though the rupee was devalued against the US dollar. This
resulted in overvaluation of domestic currency and losses were visible
in the trade and current account balances. The first devaluation of 20
percent against pound sterling took place in 1967 triggered by a
widening trade deficit and declining export prices. In 1968, the
government introduced Foreign Exchange Entitlement Certificate Scheme
(FEECS), which meant a dual exchange rate system with one official
exchange rate applicable to essential imports and non-traditional
exports while the other rate, a bit higher, was applied to the trade
related transactions. This dual exchange rate system continued until
1977 when the government decided to de-link the rupee from the pound
sterling. Eventually, in November 1977, the exchange rate was unified
with a managed float system. The US dollar was made the intervention
currency and the rupee was devalued by a huge 46 percent. Sri Lankan
rupee faced further devaluation during the 1990s. The currency market
has shown some signs of stability since 1999.
2.4. Bangladesh (6)
The exchange rate has declined continually under the fixed exchange
rate regime in force over most of the 23 years. The exchange rate was
about 15 Taka in 1976-80 period. In the recent years, 1996-97, it takes
45 Taka to buy one US dollar, in 1999, it was Taka 48.50. The rate of
decline of about 10 percent per year was rapid. The exchange value has
declined to a third of its level 20 year ago. The fixed exchange rate
regime was sustained with a system of multiple administered rates. These
rates were unified in 1994, a year after India freed the exchange rate
from controls. The secondary market in exchange rates was abolished and
the rates were unified. Though accepting IMF Article 8 conditions, the
exchange rate is determined by a system of daily fixing of the Taka, the
currency, against the US dollar. The fix is done on the basis of the
currency's real effective exchange rate, REER, a status measured on
a trade weighted basket of currencies of 15 major trading partners. In
this, it is a managed float of the type that is followed by almost all
managed floaters.
Introduction of this managed float based on the REER led to a
steadying of the exchange rate. There were continuing depreciations but
at half the previous rate of declines in exchange rate in real terms
even after the 1994 change. But the exchange rate improved for a little
while during October 1994 and March 1995 before resuming its decline
thereafter. However, the volatility in the currency market has improved
since 2000.
3. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY AND DATA
Unit Roots and Co-integration
It is well known that the data generating process for most
macroeconomic time series are characterised by unit roots, which puts
the use of standard econometric methods under question. Therefore, it is
important to analyse the time series properties of the data in order to
avoid the spurious results generated by unbounded variances of
parameters estimates due to unit roots in the data. To ensure the
robustness of the test results, three most commonly used unit-root tests
are applied here, namely the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF),
Phillips-Perron (PP) and KPSS unit root tests on the relevant variables.
The departing feature of these three test procedures is that the null
hypothesis in ADF and PP is the alternative hypothesis in KPSS. In
particular, while the former (ADF and PP) is derived under the null
hypothesis of unit roots the latter (KPSS) is obtained under stationary
null hypothesis. If all variables are I(1) then the linear combination
of one or more of these series may exhibit a long-run relationship. The
multivariate co-integration test based on the Johansen-Juselius (1990)
method is used to test for these long-run relationships. The maximum
eigenvalue test and trace test are employed to establish the number of
co-integrating vectors. If the exchange rates are co-integrated then the
Multivariate GARCH model within Error Correction framework will be
estimated to examine the nature of the mean transmission (Granger
Causality) between these variables. However, in the absence of
co-integration the Multivariate GARCH model in differenced form within
VAR framework will be employed to establish the relationships (Granger
Causality) between exchange rates. As we shall see latter in Section 4,
the variables of exchange rates are not co-integrated and hence the
multivariate GARCH in VAR framework is employed to establish the
linkages among exchange rates.
Multivariate GARCH Models
Time-varying volatility properties of univariate economic time
series are widely analysed-through autoregressive conditional
heteroskedasticity (ARCH) and generalised autoregressive conditional
heteroskedasticity (GARCH) models. While the univariate GARCH models
examines the time-varying nature of economic time series its
multivariate extension, commonly known as multivariate GARCH (MGARCH)
models, analyses the time-varying conditional cross moments. In this
paper, we analyse the linkages between the exchange rates of South Asian
countries of India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka and Bangladesh with their
major trading partners through vector autoregressive MGARCH models. The
departing feature of this technique is that it not only analyses the
linkages between first moment of the variables of interest through VAR
representation but also the volatility transmission between the exchange
markets though GARCH specifications.
Consider the following mean equation of the VAR-MGARCH model,
[Y.sub.t] = [alpha] [p.summation over (i=1)
[[PHI].sub.i][Y.sub.t-i] + [[epsilon].sub.t] ... (1)
Where [Y.sub.t] is an n x 1 vector of changes in daily exchange
rates at time t, [[epsilon].sub.t] ~ N (0, [[SIGMA].sub.t]) and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The n x 1 vector [alpha] represents the long-term drift
coefficients. The error term [[epsilon].sub.t] denotes the n x 1 vector
of innovation at each market at time t with its corresponding n x n
conditional variance covariance matrix [[SIGMA].sub.t]. The elements of
the matrix [[PHI].sub.i]'s are the degree of mean spillover effect
across markets and measures the transmission in mean from one market to
another. Bauwens, et al. (2003) provides the survey of various MGARCH
models with variations to the conditional variance covariance matrix of
equations. In particular, in this paper, we adopt the model by Baba,
Engle, Kraft and Kroner (hereafter BEKK), whereby the
variance-covariance matrix of system of equations at time t depends on
the squares and cross products of innovation [[epsilon].sub.t-1] and
volatility [[SIGMA].sub.t-1] for each market [see Engle and Kroner
(1995) and Bauwens, et al. (2003) for more details]. The BEKK
parameterisation of MGARCH model is given by:
[[summation].sub.t] = B'B + C'[[epsilon].sub.t-1]
[[epsilon].sub.t-1]C + G'[[summation].sub.t-1]G ... (2)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The elements [c.sub.ij] of the n x n symmetric matrix C measures
the degree of innovation from market i to j. The elements [g.sub.ij] of
the n x n symmetric matrix G measures the persistence in conditional
volatility between market i and market j. The model represented by
Equations (1) and (2) are estimated through maximum likelihood
estimation procedures.
The log-likelihood for MGARCH model under Gaussian errors is given
by
L([theta]) = - TN/2 + ln(2p) - 1/2 [summation](ln[absolute value of
[[summation].sub.t]] + [[epsilon].sub.t]]'[absolute value of
[[summation].sup.-1.sub.t]][[epsilon].sub.t]) ... (3)
where T represents the effective sample size, n is the number of
markets and [theta] is the vector of parameters defined in (1) and (2)
to be estimated. As in traditional approach, we use Berndt, Hall, Hall
and Hausman (hereafter BHHH) algorithm to produce the maximum likelihood
parameters and the corresponding standard errors. The Q-statistic
developed by Ljung-Box is used to test the randomness of residuals of
the estimated MGARCH model.
Granger Causality Tests
The linkages between the exchange markets are analysed using
Granger causality tests. For example, the null of Granger non-causality
from variable 2 to variable 1 is examined by estimating the restricted
system of equations represented by (1) and (2). The null and alternative
hypotheses are given by
[H.sub.0] : [[phi].sup.(1).sub.12] = [[phi].sup.(21).sub.12] =
[[phi].sup.(p).sub.12] = 0 (i.e., Granger non-causality from variable 2
to variable 1).
[H.sub.1] : [[phi].sup.(i).sub.12] [not equal to] 0 for some i =
1,2, ..., p (there exists a causality from variable 2 to variable 1).
The likelihood ratio test statistic to test the above hypothesis is
given by LR = -2([l.sub.R] - [l.sub.U]), where [l.sub.R] and [l.sub.U]
represents the maximised values of the log-likelihood function, denoted
by (3), of the restricted and unrestricted system of equation specified
by (1) and (2) respectively. Under [H.sub.0], the LR statistic has an
asymptotic [chi square] with degrees of freedom equal to the number of
restrictions p.
Data
The focus of this paper is to investigate a linkage among exchange
rates of the four South Asian countries. As discussed elsewhere in this
paper, we link these exchange rates to their major trading partner and
try to answer three questions raised in Section 1 of this paper. Based
on each country's trade statistics, we include a sample of selected
countries within Asian regions, Europe, and the middle east (for imports
of oil) in the VAR to test for Granger causality. Besides, India,
Pakistan, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka, the other countries included in the
sample are Singapore, China, Belgium, Germany, Honk Kong, Saudi Arabia,
United Arab Emirates (UAE), Japan, and the United Kingdom (UK). We use
WM/Reuters closing spot rates against US dollar for the above sample
countries. Sample period spans from 1 January 1996 to 31 December 2003,
daily observations (5-day week), a total of 2080 observations. All
exchange rates are obtained from Datastream database and all variables
are in log form.
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Before using MGARCH model to test the Granger causality in VARs, we
look at the cross correlations of the log of exchange rates (with one
lag) for the sample countries. These cross correlations are reported in
Table 3 and suggest a strong positive correlation among exchange rate of
all sample countries. This preliminary test provides an indication of
some currency market linkage. A more sophisticated multivariate GARCH
will show if these preliminary tests are robust or not. The univariate
time series properties of the relevant data series are analysed through
ADF, PP and KPSS unit root test procedures. The results reported in
Table 4 shows that all variables which are in logarithmic form are
non-stationary. The test result based on first-differenced series also
reaffirms that all variables are I(1) and the linear combination
(cointegrating vectors) of one or more of these series may exhibit a
long-run relationship. The maximum eigenvalue and trace test results to
establish the numbers of co-integrating vectors are reported in Table 5.
The results show that there does not exist a long run relationship among
exchange rates and hence the Multivariate GARCH model in differenced
form within VAR framework is estimated.
In order to examine the linkages between the exchange rate markets,
we consider two competitive models. In the first model, the lag length p
is justified by AIC and SC criteria and it suggests the parsimonious representation of lag 1 in the VAR representation described by (1). In
the second model, we restrict the lag length to be 4. In both models,
the volatility equation described by (2) is restricted to GARCH (1,1)
specification. For brevity, the estimated coefficients for the mean
equations with lag 1 and lag 4 are not reported here. However, these
results are available from the first author upon request. And the
corresponding Granger causality test results are presented in Table 6
and Table 7, respectively. Obviously, Table 6 and Table 7 are of more
interest for the purpose of this paper. We therefore focus our
discussion on the Granger causality results. The results of Table 6 are
less supportive to a case for currency integration. The results suggest
that Chinese yuan is the only currency that influences Indian rupee.
Pakistan rupee is not influenced by any currency in the sample. Sri
Lankan rupee is affected by changes in Chinese yuan and Japanese yen
while Bangladesh is only affected by Japanese yen. The results do not
find any cause or effect within four South Asian currencies. The results
in Table 7 are more interesting. These results suggest that Indian rupee
is affected by changes in Singapore dollar, yen and pound sterling.
Given that Singapore has made significant investment in India during the
late 1990s to early 2000s and that the Singapore dollar has been
volatile during the period under study, this result is not surprising.
Pakistan rupee is also influenced by Singapore dollar, yen, the pound
sterling and Bangladesh taka. Although, Singapore does not have much
investment in Pakistan, but has been one of the major trading partner in
the region. Japan is a major import market for Pakistan. Pakistan also
receives aid and loans from Japan. These two factors may exert
sufficient influence on the currency, especially, given Pakistan's
high indebtedness. The currency in Sri Lanka is influenced by changes in
Chinese yuan and Japanese yen, while Bangladesh taka is only affected by
Chines yuan.
Table 7 also looks into how the four South Asian currencies affect
the other currencies in the sample. The results suggest that Indian
rupee has some effect on Chinese yuan, Hong Kong dollar, and Saudi
Arabian riyal. It should be noted that India has developed as one of the
major software market in the world. They have also taken up a big share
in meeting world's demand for floppies and disks. They are, in a
way, a competitor to China in this industry. Saudi Arabia is a major oil
exporter for India and provides a basis for some currency links. With
the same token, Saudi riyal does not affect Pakistan rupee. Changes in
Pakistan rupee causes Hong Kong dollar, yen and pound sterling to
change. This could be due to huge external borrowing of the country
which poses a high risk to the creditors and hence may exert some effect
on their currencies. Although, Saudi Arabia is a major oil exporter to
Pakistan, the riyal does not seem to affect the Pakistan rupee. This
probably is due to the concessional oil import arrangements Pakistan
enjoys with Saudi Arabia. Singapore dollar is the only currency caused
by Sri Lankan rupee. Bangladesh taka only affect Pakistan rupee.
Surprisingly, we could not find any empirical support of a close link
among the four South Asian currencies expect some weak support between
Pakistan rupee and Bangladesh taka.
Moving our attention to the next important question. If the world
currency market converges to a try polar regime, as predicted by some
economists, which currency would be is a good candidate to be an anchor
currency in the South Asian region. Germany and Belgium represent euro
in our sample. The empirical findings of this paper did not find any
cause or effect between the four currencies and the euro. The results
suggest that a change in pound sterling would affect only Indian and
Pakistani rupee. However, yen turns out to be a strong link for all four
countries. Another interesting observation is the cross linkages of
these currencies. It is evident from our empirical results reported in
Table 7 that yen has a strong influence on other currencies such as
Singapore dollar, Hong Kong dollar and euro. Interestingly, both
Singapore dollar and Hong Kong dollar are also influenced by euro and
pound sterling. We also found a bi-directional causality between
Singapore dollar and Hong Kong dollar. (7) Finally, Singapore dollar
seems to have significant influence on both Indian and Pakistani rupee.
Summarising these results, it is evident that yen has strong
influence on the four currencies and causes movement in the exchange
rates of these countries. This could mean that if these countries have
to choose one currency, yen, probably, would be the best choice.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The recent developments in the international currency markets
indicate that in the next decade or two, the world's exchange rate
regimes will converge to three major currency regions.
The first will be dominated by the US dollar, the second, with euro
and the third with Japanese yen, with a small fraction still using Pound
sterling as the anchor currency. These widely anticipated developments
will have important implications for some emerging economies such as the
South Asian region. In this paper, we focus on four South Asian
economies, namely, India, Pakistan, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka. Besides
providing a comprehensive overview of the reforms and developments that
took place in the currency markets of the four during the last 55 years,
we provide some empirical evidence to the questions raised in this paper
using high frequency data and recently developed econometrics test
procedure to investigate any causal relationship among regional
currencies. The empirical evidence found in this paper are not very
conclusive to support a close interlink among the regional currencies.
However, these results single out Japanese yen to serve as the main link
among the four currencies. These findings may have important
implications for future policy design.
However, the empirical tests performed in this paper have some
limitations. We did not include US dollar in this analysis. A more
meaningful exercise would be to include US dollar and then compare the
results. To make a strong case for financial market integration, one
should also extend this research to include other indicators such as
stock prices and interest rate. Another possible avenue is to identify
some specific shocks and then see the responses on these four markets.
Some of these extensions are underway by the authors and will be
presented at a later stage. Nevertheless, this paper serves as an
initial step to investigate some important issues in the South Asian
context and have important implications for any future policy design.
This is an important contribution of this research.
REFERENCES
Ariff, Mohamed, and Ahmed M. Khalid (2005) Liberalisation and
Growth in Asia: 21st Century Challenges. London: Edward Elgar Publishing
Co. (forthcoming).
Ariff, Mohamed, and Ahmed M. Khalid (2000) Liberalisation, Growth
and Asian Financial Crisis: Lessons for Developing and Transitional
Economies. London: Edward Elgar Publishing Co. May, 544 p.
Bauwens, Luc, and Pierre Giot (2003) Asymmetric ACD Models:
Introducing Price Information in ACD Models. Empirical Economics 28:4,
709-31.
Eichengreen, B., and T. Bayoumi (1996) Is Asia an Optimum Currency
Area? Can it Become One? Regional, Global and Historical Perspectives on
Monetary Relations. University of California, Berkeley, (CIDER Working
Paper No. C96- 081).
Engle, Robert F., Kenneth F. Kroner, Yoshihisa Baba, and Dennis F.
Kraft (1993) Multivariate Simultaneous Generalised ARCH. Department of
Economics, University of California, San Diago. (Working Paper Series).
Engle, Robert F., and Kenneth F. Kroner (1995) Multivariate
Simultaneous Generalised ARCH. Econometric Theory 11:1, 122-50.
Hall, Bronwyn H., Zvi Griliches, and Jerry A. Hausman (1986)
Patents and R and D: Is there a Lag? International Economic Review 27:2,
265-83.
Hindustan Times (2004) India Calls for Single SAARC Currency,
Unified Tariff. January 4. Hindustan Times. com.
International Monetary Fund (1999) World Economic Outlook. Various
Issues, IMF, Washington, D.C., October, 66-87.
Johansen, S., and K. Juselius (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation
and Inference on Co-integration with Application to Demand for Money.
Oxford Bulletin for Economics and Statistics 52, 169-210.
Khalid, Ahmed M., and Masahiro Kawai (2003) Was Financial Market
Contagion the Source of Economic Crisis in Asia? Evidence Using a
Multivariate VAR Model. Journal of Asian Economics 14:1, 133-159.
Khan, Saleem M., and Zahira S. Khan (2003) Asian Economic
Integration: A Perspective on South Asia. Journal of Asian Economics 13:
767-85.
Kohli, Renu (2003) Real Exchange Rate Stabilisation and Managed
Floating: Exchange Rate Policy in India, 1993-2001. Journal of Asian
Economics 14, 369-87.
Kwack, Sung Yeung (2004) An Optimum Currency Area in East Asia:
Feasibility, Coordination, and Leadership Role. Journal of Asian
Economics 15, 153-69.
Mundell, Robert (2003) Prospects for an Asian Currency Area.
Journal of Asian Economics 14, 1-10.
Stevenson, Adlai E. (2004) Regional Financial Cooperation in Asia.
Journal of Asian Economics 15, 837-841.
Wang, Yunjong (2004) Financial Cooperation and Integration in East
Asia. Journal of Asian Economics 15, 939-955.
World Bank (1999) Appendix 1 Regional Economic Prospects: South
Asia, www.worldbank.org
(1) Reader may refer to Khan and Khan (2003) and Stevenson (2004)
for more discussion on regional cooperation.
(2) See Eichengreen and Bayouni (1996); Hindustan Times (2004);
Kwack (2004) and Wang (2004) for more details on regional currency
integration.
(3) Exchange rate reforms in India are discussed in detail in Ariff
and Khalid (2005), Chapter 4, and Kohli (2003).
(4) See Ariff and Khalid (2005), Chapter 8, for a detailed
discussion on currency market reforms in Pakistan.
(5) Currency market reforms and developments in Sri Lanka are
discussed on detail in Ariff and Khalid (2000), Chapter 15.
(6) Exchange rate reforms in Bangladesh are discussed in detail in
Ariff and Khalid (2000), Chapter 11.
(7) Such bi-directional causality between the two currencies is
also supported by Khalid and Kawai (2003).
Ahmed M. Khalid and Gulasekaran Rajaguru are both based at the
Faculty of Business, Bond University, Gold Coast, Australia.
Table 1
Basic Economic Indicators of Development (1961-2002)
1961- 1971- 1981-
Indicators 70 80 90
India
GDP Growth (%) 4.11 3.06 4.72
Per Capita GDPC (US$) 97.82 167.70 314.56
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP -- 22.3 21.9
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 14.8 16.98 20.78
Inflation (per Year) 6.36 8.16 8.88
M2/GDP 22.40 30.23 42.11
Fiscal Balance/GDP -4.15 -4.29 -7.43
Trade Balance/GDP -- -- -2.26
Current Account
Balance/GDP -- -- -1.77
Debt/GDP -- -- 47.89
Pakistan
GDP Growth (%) 3.35 4.81 6.19
Per Capita GDP (US$) 138.86 180.18 327.06
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP -- 13.81 13.83
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 15.37 15.38 16.96
Inflation (per Year) 3.51 12.42 6.98
M2/GDP 36.14 41.76 41.25
Fiscal Balance/GDP -5.17 -7.41 -6.74
Trade Balance/GDP -- -8.06 -9.31
Current Account
Balance/GDP -- -5.35 -2.91
Debt/GDP 33.91 61.96 64.15
Bangladesh
GDP Growth (%) 4.15 4.01
Per Capita GDP (US$) 164
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 11.22
Inflation (per Year) 2.95
M2/GDP 26.60
Fiscal Balance/GDP
Trade Balance/GDP -9.42
Current Account Balance/GDP -3.28
Debt/GDP
Sri Lanks
GDP Growth (%) 8.83 4.39 4.65
Per Capita GDP (US$) 153 241 382
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 15.17 17.53 24.91
Inflation (per Year) 2.95 8.91 12.36
M2/GDP 26.39 24.65 30.49
Fiscal Balance/GDP -6.32 -8.63 -10.14
Trade Balance/GDP -- -- -9.34
Current Account Balance/GDP -- -- -6.43
Debt/GDP -- -- 87.25
1991- 1996-
Indicators 95 2000
India
GDP Growth (%) 6.71 5.73
Per Capita GDPC (US$) 348.37 441.20
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP 23.1 24.1
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 27.0 21.9
Inflation (per Year) 12.29 7.61
M2/GDP 54.23 50.34
Fiscal Balance/GDP -6.68 -5.14
Trade Balance/GDP -1.7 -2.42
Current Account
Balance/GDP -1.46 -1.1
Debt/GDP 59.83 51.43
Pakistan
GDP Growth (%) 4.85 3.07
Per Capita GDP (US$) 404.85 438.82
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP 14.81 13.29
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 18.07 15.41
Inflation (per Year) 11.20 7.30
M2/GDP 43.39 46.63
Fiscal Balance/GDP -7.67 -6.91
Trade Balance/GDP -5.15 -3.73
Current Account
Balance/GDP -4.49 -3.17
Debt/GDP -- --
Bangladesh
GDP Growth (%) 4.39 5.21
Per Capita GDP (US$) 281 329
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 17.93 21.51
Inflation (per Year) 5.37 5.11
M2/GDP 26.68 31.01
Fiscal Balance/GDP
Trade Balance/GDP -4.51 -4.37
Current Account Balance/GDP 0.07 -0.95
Debt/GDP
Sri Lanks
GDP Growth (%) 5.55 5.07
Per Capita GDP (US$) 607 816
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 24.71 25.74
Inflation (per Year) 10.29 9.15
M2/GDP 32.83 37.78
Fiscal Balance/GDP -7.61 -7.34
Trade Balance/GDP -8.06 -4.90
Current Account Balance/GDP -5.46 -3.79
Debt/GDP 96.03 92.19
Indicators 2000 2001 2002
India
GDP Growth (%) 4.20 5.49 4.4
Per Capita GDPC (US$) 467.23 478.20 --
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP 23.4 24.0 24.5
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 21.9 21.7 23.9
Inflation (per Year) 4.01 3.69 4.39
M2/GDP 55.57 58.22 --
Fiscal Balance/GDP -5.17 -4.71 -7.4
Trade Balance/GDP -2.6 -2.6 --
Current Account
Balance/GDP -0.90 0.3 0.6
Debt/GDP 55.30 57.31 --
Pakistan
GDP Growth (%) 4.26 2.72 4.41
Per Capita GDP (US$) 426.64 380.40 439
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP 14.4 14.60 13.6
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 14.37 14.29 12.33
Inflation (per Year) 4.37 3.15 3.29
M2/GDP 46.92 48.30 51.74
Fiscal Balance/GDP -5.47 -4.71 -4.62
Trade Balance/GDP ?.4 -2.3 -0.5
Current Account
Balance/GDP -0.14 3.41 4.50
Debt/GDP 90.00 -- --
Bangladesh
GDP Growth (%) 5.95 5.27 4.80
Per Capita GDP (US$) 331 324
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 23.02 23.09 23.16
Inflation (per Year) 3.90 1.10 6.79
M2/GDP 34.71 37.22 39.39
Fiscal Balance/GDP
Trade Balance/GDP -3.64 -4.51
Current Account Balance/GDP -0.67 -1.18
Debt/GDP
Sri Lanks
GDP Growth (%) 6.58 -1.45 3.53
Per Capita GDP (US$) 844 820 --
Gross Domestic Savings/GDP
Fixed Capital Formation/GDP 28.04 22.03 22.47
Inflation (per Year) 6.18 14.16 9.55
M2/GDP 38.18 39.22 --
Fiscal Balance/GDP -9.46 -9.87 --
Trade Balance/GDP -6.39 -3.53 --
Current Account Balance/GDP -6.39 -1.69 --
Debt/GDP 96.90 -- --
Source: Ariff and Khalid (2005).
Note: '-' not available.
Table 2
Major Currency Reforms in South Asia--1960-2002
Date of
Reforms Liberalisation Policies Implemented
India * India operated a fixed exchange rate regime despite
most countries choosing managed floats in the late
1970s and early 1980s; during this phase, India's
currency depreciated at an annul late of about l0
percent
* 1991: currency crisis led to a 23 percent devaluation
of the currency
* 1993: Foreign exchange controls on producers and
individuals were slowly relaxed
* 1994: Currency was free floated satisfying the IMF
article 8 conditions
* Capital controls on producers removed substantially
* Exchange controls on individuals eased for travel and
education
* Further easing of capital controls shelved in the
face of the 1997 Asian financial crisis
* Insurance sector is the next one to be reformed;
limited reforms being introduced in this sector by
easing entry barriers
Pakistan * 1 July 1994: Pakistan rupee made convertible on
current international transactions
* 1996-97: Residents allowed to open and maintain
Foreign Currency Accounts Authorised Dealers,
Development Financial Institutions and Housing Finance
Institutions allowed to extend local currency credit to
non-resident nationals in real estate sector
* 19 May 1999: Market based unified exchange rate
system adopted
* 1 December 2000: SBP introduced spot value convention
for all foreign exchange and foreign currency money
market transactions
* l8 Apri1 2001: SBP authorised all bank branches to
purchase or sell foreign currency notes, coins,
travellers' cheques and foreign demand drafts
* l3 February 2002: Authorised Dealers allowed to issue
foreign currency travellers' cheques to foreign and
Pakistan nationals against foreign exchange in cash
Bangladesh * Article VIII conditions accepted. Multiple exchange
rates unified 1994
* Daily fixing of rate on real effective exchange rate
suggested by a 15 country trading partners' exchange
rates. Volatility reduced, but not depreciation
Sri Lanka * No controls on holding or trading in foreign
currencies
* 1977: Relaxation of Exchange Controls
* Dual Exchange Rate system abolished and a unified
Exchange Rate system adopted fixed exchange rate system
replaced by Floating Rate system
* 1979: Foreign Currency Banking Units (FCBUs)
established
* 1994: Remaining restrictions on current international
transactions removed
Sources: Ariff and Khalid (?000) and Arid and Khalid (2005).
Table 3
Asian Exchange Rates (Levels)
(1st March 1994 to 31 December 1999)
ERHON ERIDN ERJAP ERMLY ERPHI ERSIN
ERHON 1.00
ERIDN 0.69 1.00
ERJAP 0.38 0.66 1.00
ERMLY 0.63 0.93 0.59 1.00
ERPHI 0.70 0.97 0.66 0.94 1.00
ERSIN 0.57 0.87 0.58 0.91 0.91 1.00
ERKOR 0.64 0.95 0.73 0.89 0.95 0.85
ERTAI 0.68 0.97 0.77 0.92 0.96 0.85
ERTHA 0.66 0.93 0.70 0.90 0.96 0.86
ERIND 0.79 0.89 0.69 0.85 0.89 0.72
ERPAK 0.80 0.86 0.71 0.84 0.87 0.71
ERKOR ERTAI ERTHA ERIDD ERPAK
ERHON
ERIDN
ERJAP
ERMLY
ERPHI
ERSIN
ERKOR 1.00
ERTAI 0.95 1.00
ERTHA 0.95 0.95 1.00
ERIND 0.84 0.93 0.84 1.00
ERPAK 0.84 0.90 0.85 0.97 1.00
Table 4
Unit Root Test Results
Levels
ADF PP KPSS
India -0.04 -0.18 1.02 ***
Pakistan -0.82 -0.71 1.12 ***
Singapore -1.35 -1.29 1.03 ***
Sri Lanka -1.12 -1.07 0.52 ***
Bangladesh -2.07 -2.18 0.80 ***
China -1.79 -1.81 0.99 ***
Belgium -0.l9 -0.19 0.99 ***
Germany -0.19 -0.28 0.99 ***
HK -1.85 -1.92 0.69 ***
Saudi Arabia -1.39 -1.24 0.55 ***
UAE -2.49 -2.48 0.34 ***
Japan -1.97 -2.18 0.34 ***
UK -0.64 -0.73 0.66 ***
Differences
ADF PP KPSS
India -40.26 *** -40.56 *** 0.11
Pakistan -45.88 *** -45.88 *** 0.05
Singapore -47.58 *** -47.96 *** 0.04
Sri Lanka -42.47 *** -43.49 *** 0.12 *
Bangladesh -45.31 *** -45.39 *** 0.03
China -54.22 *** -54.81 *** 0.07
Belgium -44.85 *** -44.31 *** 0.10
Germany -44.93 *** -44.90 *** 0.11
HK -51.34 *** -51.32 *** 0.06
Saudi Arabia -24.21 *** -24.42 *** 0.05
UAE -18.39 *** -19.31 *** 0.06
Japan -44.28 *** -44.15 *** 0.06
UK -42.77 *** -43.12 *** 0.16 **
Notes:
(1.) *, ** and *** denote 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent
levels of significance respectively.
(2.) The lag length for ADF is justified by Akaike's Information
Criterion (AIC) and Schwartz Criteria (SC).
(3.) The trend characteristics are not reported here and can
obtained from authors.
Table 5
Trace/Maximum Eigenvalue Tests for Cointegration
Trace Test
Hypothesis Test Statistic
r = 0 751.59 ***
r [less than or equal to] 1 358.11
r [less than or equal to] 2 305.91
r [less than or equal to] 3 246.72
r [less than or equal to] 4 190.06
r [less than or equal to] 5 145.85
r [less than or equal to] 6 104.06
r [less than or equal to] 7 72.91
r [less than or equal to] 8 49.79
r [less than or equal to] 9 31.08
r [less than or equal to] 10 19.17
r [less than or equal to] 11 7.81
r [less than or equal to] 12 0.05
Maximum Eigenvalue Test
Hypothesis Test Statistic
r = 0 393.48 ***
r = 1 52.20
r = 2 59.19
r = 3 56.66
r = 4 44.21
r = 5 41.79
r = 6 31.15
r = 7 23.13
r = 8 18.70
r = 9 11.91
r = 10 11.36
r = 11 7.76
r = 12 0.05
Notes: (1.) * ** and *** denote 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent
levels of significance respectively.
(2.) The lag length (4) is justified by Akaike's Information
Criterion (AIC) and Schwartz Criteria (SC). Both criteria
lead to similar conclusion.
Table 6
Parsimonious Model: Granger Causality Test Results
VAR(l)-MGARCH(1,1)
Effect Sri
Cause India Pakistan Singapore Lanka
India 34.21 *** 1.47 0.02 0.13
Pakistan 0.19 0.01 0.02 0.02
Singapore 1.14 2.11 6.54 *** 0.39
Sri Lanka 0.87 1.65 0.03 4.57 ***
Bangladesh 0.41 1.08 0.36 0.51
China 2.71 * 1.91 0.47 2.69 *
Belgium 0.92 0.40 1.77 1.34
Germany 0.83 0.43 1.61 1.25
HK 0.01 0.05 0.07 *** 1.31
Saudi
Arabia 0.02 0.68 9.28 0.05
UAE 0.44 0.01 0.55 0.42
Japan 0.16 0.30 0.19 5.58 ***
UK 0.03 0.70 4.11 *** 1.09
Effect
Cause Bangladesh China Belgium Germany
India 0.07 5.17 *** 0.39 0.32
Pakistan 2.24 * 0.26 0.14 0.18
Singapore 1.02 1.32 0.19 0.19
Sri Lanka 0.08 0.19 0.79 0.78
Bangladesh 0.23 0.27 1.43 1.49
China 0.46 60.58 *** 0.90 0.99
Belgium 0.36 0.84 0.19 3.08 *
Germany 0.36 0.87 0.08 2.58 *
HK 0.29 0.03 0.44 0.42
Saudi
Arabia 0.27 0.26 0.03 0.01
UAE 0.76 3.62 ** 0.69 0.98
Japan 3.24 * 0.14 3.63 ** 3.51 **
UK 0.40 0.17 0.96 0.83
Effect Saudi
Cause HK Arabia UAE
India 3.57 ** 0.07 0.02
Pakistan 0.44 0.90 0.23
Singapore 5.68 *** 0.03 1.01
Sri Lanka 0.00 0.06 0.00
Bangladesh 0.17 0.02 0.04
China 0.00 0.29 0.01
Belgium 0.37 0.01 19.15 ***
Germany 0.40 0.01 19.44 ***
HK 29.47 *** 0.45 0.04
Saudi
Arabia 5.41 *** 2.64 * 1.77
UAE 0.23 0.30 586.24 ***
Japan 7.12 8.30 *** 0.13
UK 3.33 * 0.57 L95
Effect
Cause Japan UK
India 0.14 0.00
Pakistan 0.29 1.58
Singapore 10.72 *** 0.16
Sri Lanka 0.08 2.24 *
Bangladesh 0.65 1.43
China 0.28 0.47
Belgium 1.17 1.85
Germany 1.12 1.46
HK 0.94 1.23
Saudi
Arabia 2.70 * 0.29
UAE 0.01 5.06 ***
Japan 8.85 *** 0.12
UK 0.40 2.18 *
*, ** and *** represents rejection of the Granger non-causality
at 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent respectively.
Table 7
VAR(4)-MGARCH(1,1): Granger Causality Test Results
Effect Sri
Cause India Pakistan Singapore Lanka
India 42.5 *** 2.2 1.7 0.7
Pakistan 3.6 7.4 * 2.0 2.6
Singapore 12.4 *** 9.3 ** 17.8 *** 1.0
Sri Lanka 1.2 2.5 6.7 * 10.9 **
Bangladesh 5.1 8.1 * 0.8 4.3
China 4.1 2.6 l.4 9.1 **
Belgium 3.5 0.7 6.4 * 2.9
Germany 3.9 0.5 6.4 * 2.7
HK 4.3 0.3 12.9 *** 4.6
Saudi Arabia 0.3 3.1 74.6 *** 0.3
UAE 1.7 3.7 0.7 1.1
Japan 11.0 ** 9.9 ** 6.7 * 6.4 *
UK 6.6 * 7.0 * 14.3 *** 1.5
Effect
Cause Bangladesh China Belgium Germany
India 2.8 14.3 *** 1.6 1.4
Pakistan 3.2 0.4 3.2 3.0
Singapore 1.9 2.5 7.3 * 7.6 *
Sri Lanka 0.3 0.7 1.4 1.3
Bangladesh 1.5 2.0 5.6 5.8
China 2.3 72.1 *** 1.7 1.8
Belgium 2.7 4.l 2.0 4.2
Germany 3.1 4.0 2.1 3.9
HK 0.6 2.7 2.6 2.2
Saudi Arabia 0.5 0.3 2.7 2.7
UAE 1.7 7.2 * 2.7 2.8
Japan 6.1 * 0.9 9.4 ** 9.6 **
UK 1.3 3.1 5.5 5.2
Effect Saudi
Cause HK Arabia UAE
India 8.4 * 16.6 *** 1.5
Pakistan 8.4 * 0.7 3.4
Singapore 13.6 *** 14.9 *** 2.3
Sri Lanka 2.2 2.5 0.4
Bangladesh 0.4 1.4 3.9
China 2.3 0.8 14.9 ***
Belgium 4.9 1.6 16.9 ***
Germany 36.9 *** 1.8 4.2
HK 13.5 *** 13.6 *** 1.1
Saudi Arabia 4.8 356.2 *** 118.7 ***
UAE 10.7 ** 13.2 *** 448.9 ***
Japan 12.2 *** 0.9 1.4
UK 8.4 * 2.6 0.9
Effect
Cause Japan UK
India 2.2 1.6
Pakistan 13.1 *** 7.9 *
Singapore 5.2 7.8 *
Sri Lanka 3.4 4.5
Bangladesh 4.9 2.8
China 0.2 8.8 *
Belgium 4.8 2.8
Germany 5.5 2.5
HK 4.7 1.2
Saudi Arabia 11.5 ** 12.2 ***
UAE 11.8 *** 0.3
Japan 5.4 5.9
UK 9.8 ** 9.2 **
*, ** and *** represents rejection of the Granger non-causality
at 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent respectively.