Impact of changing profile of rural land market in Pakistan on resource allocation and equity.
Qureshi, Madeeha G. ; Qureshi, Sarfraz Khan
I. INTRODUCTION
An attempt is made to determine the nature of land market as to how
far it approximates the ideal of competitive market. It also reviews the
farm size, efficiency and productivity relationship. The paper is
organised in four sections. After the introductory section, the
literature on past research on land markets in Pakistan and other
countries is brought together in Section II. Description of land market
institutions and changes in the structure of land markets including the
pattern of ownership and the operational distribution of land and trends
in different facets of land markets are the subject matter of Section
III. Summary and conclusions are presented in the concluding section.
II. REVIEW OF LITERATURE
The literature on rural land markets focuses on a wide variety of
issues including: the relationship between farm size and productivity;
land rights; constraints faced by small farms; land reforms; land
fragmentation; transaction costs; the relationship between rent and land
prices. To begin with, the debate on the subject of farm size and
productivity relationship started with Sen's (1962) seminal work using India's Farm Management Survey Data. Afterwards, a
significant number of studies have been completed proving or rejecting
the claim of the inverse relationship between farm size and land
productivity in South Asia and some other developing countries. The
studies using Indian data, which found inverse relationship are Sen
(1962); Masumdar (1965); Rao (1966); Saini (1971); Bharadwaj (1974);
Chaddha (1978); Ghose (1979); Bhalla (1979); among others. The studies
which did not find inverse relationship or had inconclusive results are
Rao (1967); Bhattacharya and Saini (1972); Khan and Tripathy (1972); Rao
(1975); Dasgupta (1977); Chattopadhyay and Rudra (1976); Saini (1980);
Bagi (1981); Deolalikar (1981); Rao and Chotigeat (1981); Roy (1981);
among others.
Studies of the type done in India are relatively scarce in other
developing countries. The few studies conducted in other countries have
also come up with mixed results. In the case of Egypt, Radwan and Lee
(1986) support the inverse relationship, while Commander (1987) finds no
consistent association. Dyer (1991) states that the relation may hold in
a relatively backward agriculture but it breaks down with the
advancements in technology. Hossain (1977); Berry and Cline (1979) and
Herdt and Mandac (1981) found that the inverse relationship holds in the
case of Indonesia, the Philippines and Bangladesh, respectively.
Studies using efficiency analysis in developing countries also show
mixed results of the kind found in studies discussed above that have
used the size-productivity relationship to resolve the debate. In case
of India agriculture, Khusro (1964); Sahota (1968); Sidhu (1974); Ray
(1985); Huang and Bagi (1984) and Kalirajan (1981) concluded that
productive efficiency did not differ across different farm size
categories. Yotopoulos, Lau and Sonel (1970); Lau and Yotopoulos (1971);
Yotopoulos and Lau (1973) and Bagi (1987) found negative relationship
between farm size and efficiency. Squire and Tabor (1991); Bravo-Ureta
and Evenson (1994) and Pinheiro (1992) found no relationship between
farm size and efficiency in agriculture sectors of Indonesia, Paraguay
and the Dominican Republic, respectively.
In spite of the pertinent nature of the policy debates, the
analysis of the relationship between farm sizes and productivity did not
attract much attention of the researchers in Pakistan. However, a few
studies have been conducted in the past dealing with this issue. The
first is that of Khan (1979) using 732 irrigated farms in the Indus
Basin for the year 1974 and a production function technique
incorporating a farm size dummy variable concluded that the large
farmers get higher output per acre. The study further indicates that per
acre use of non-traditional inputs-fertiliser, hired labour and farm
machinery--is higher on large farms than on small farms. The observed
difference is a result of market distortions induced by public policy.
The second study by Khan and Maki (1980) uses the same 1974 data set. It
conducts analysis for wheat and rice crops only. It found no significant
farm size-based difference in efficiency. However, they reported the
existence of increasing returns to scale.
Ali and Flinn (1989) using the profit frontier approach found an
average economic efficiency of 69 percent for the Basmati rice farmers
in Punjab, based on the data from Gujranwala district. Farmers'
education, lack of credit facility, late application of fertilisers, and
irrigation constraints were considered to be the factors accounting for
low efficiency. All and Choudhry (1990) found average technical
efficiency of about 84 percent with some regional level variations.
Battese, et al. (1993) using wheat data from Faisalabad, Attock, Badin
and Dir found that technical inefficiencies exist in three of these
districts that are Faisalabad, Badin and Dir. The study suggests that
the adoption of new technology and a good agricultural extension system
are required to enhance the efficiency of the wheat farmers. Parikh and
Shah (1994) found average technical efficiency of about 96 percent in
NWFP. The farm level technical efficiency was found dependent upon
farmers' education, credit, age and the extent of land
fragmentation. Parikh, Ali and Shah (1995) using cost function found an
average inefficiency of about 12 percent. The study also concluded that
the small farmers were more efficient than the large farmers in the
study area. The authors suggested that providing rural education,
extension service and credit could reduce inefficiency.
It was the evidence of inverse relationship (between farm size and
per acre productivity) that provided an empirical support to the
policy-makers for reforming the agricultural sector in various
countries. Pakistan faces tremendous problems on various fronts
including social, cultural, institutional and economic. These problems
continued to affect the achievable potential growth of the agriculture
sector keeping it down to its minimum through their depressing effects
on land productivity and economic efficiency.
The solution considered for increasing land productivity was to
reform the feudal land tenure system inherited by Pakistan.
Consequently, two land reforms, 1959 and 1972, took place. The land
reforms have to serve three purposes; increased production, efficiency
and equity through redistribution of land and security of tenure.
However, these reforms did not succeed in changing the status quo in
Pakistan and thus had no significant impact on production [Naqvi, et al.
(1989)].
The following explanations have been cited by various studies to
account for the negative relationship between land size and
productivity:
* Factor prices so vary between large farms and small farms, that
the effective prices of land and capital are low for the large farms
while the price for labour is cheaper for small farms. Thus, small farms
are more labour intensive i.e. they have high labour to land ratios
whereas large farms use labour and land less intensively.
* Small farms with a lower opportunity cost of labour, can exploit
more marginal land, cultivate a larger proportion of their land, and as
a result, achieve higher output and yields. The point regarding the
factor price differentials between large and small farms is derived from
Sen's (1) labour market dualism framework where the supply price of
family labour is the average product of labour and not the marginal
product. The marginal product of labour (MPL) on the small farms will be
lower than on the large farms. The main qualification to this is where
the opportunity cost of labour is high (due to the availability of
off-farm employment). However, the market wage may be discounted for
risk and search costs, or the family may try to hire out labour but
family preferences or unwillingness to share output with the hired-out
worker, will keep the MPL less than the wage. (2)
* The effective land price may be higher for the small farms
because small plots of land may have higher unit costs (a greater
potential market and inconvenience for landowners). Secondly, since land
purchase needs credit and that large farm owners have better ratings
they have cheaper access to credit. The real price of land is therefore
lower. Differentials in price of land reinforce labour cost
differentials and lead to labour intensive cultivation and a higher
output per acre for small farms.
* Capital market imperfections reinforce low labour use on the
large farms. A low effective price of capital leads to substitution of
machines for labour. The main influence of mechanisation is on
substituting for labour rather than raising yields. (3) Studies show
markedly lower labour to land ratios on the large farms and this is
taken to mean that capital and land market imperfections complement the
effects of labour market dualism or are not strong enough to counteract
them.
* The holding of land for asset price speculation or for reasons of
social prestige and or political power is also counted as a possible
explanation for lower productive activity on the large farms.
Khan (1979) focuses on productivity differences due to farm size.
Using farm size data, the study suggests that in Pakistan large farms
are relatively more productive because of their greater use of
"non-traditional" inputs. The input intensity of large farms
derives from market distortion induced by public policy. Agricultural
policy should therefore concentrate on eliminating market distortions,
by measures like ceiling on land holdings and a wider diffusion of farm
extension services and credit.
Chaudhry, et al. (1985) focus on the size-productivity relationship
in Pakistan during Seventies in the wake of the Green Revolution. The
study concludes that the traditional inverse relationship between farm
size and productivity exists in Pakistan precluding the possibility of a
positive relationship. The analysis of the study shows that the rate of
growth of productivity in the seventies was more pronounced in the case
of small farmers as compared to the large farmers. The authors are of
the view that the reasons why the traditional inverse relationship
remains intact are higher labour input, more intensive land use, greater
manorial application, high rates of adoption of HYVs and greater
irrigated area of the small farmers in relation to the large ones.
The study concludes, firstly, that in Pakistan the Green Revolution
technology has basically been scale-neutral in its effects on various
classes of farmers. Although tractors and tubewells may be physically
indivisible, the practice of selling tubewell water and the institution
of contract-ploughing make them quite divisible in terms of flow of
their services. Due to this scale-neutrality, the authors recommend that
the government should increase the emphasis on propagating the cause of
these technologies. Secondly, it has been argued that the unequal
distribution of appropriate technologies into social, physical and
political environments have been biased against the small producers.
Given the high levels of productivity of small farmers, it is difficult
to underestimate the economic importance of a redistributive land
reforms programme to a rapid growth of agricultural output and the
changing of the environment in favour of the small farmers. Thirdly, the
propagation of the Green Revolution technologies and their effects on
various classes of farmers depends on the prevailing price policy of the
key agricultural inputs and agricultural commodities. An adequate supply
of the cheap agricultural inputs would suit the needs of the small
farmers and would lead to the rapid growth of agricultural output.
Mahmood and Haque (1981) explore the relationship between farm size
and output per acre in Pakistan. The study concludes that the observed
negative or positive correlations between land productivity and the farm
size in the case of Pakistan are the result of over-aggregation. Land
productivity curve is U-shaped; the productivity is high on small farms
due to intensive labour and irrigation use and on largest farms due to
capital-intensive inputs. The derived U-shaped curve entails that the
smallest and largest farm sizes have the highest land productivities,
while the middle farmers are relatively inefficient.
As summarised in World Bank's study of Rural Factor Markets
(2004), recent econometric evidence in Pakistan suggests relatively
small diseconomies of scale in physical production. Plot-level
regressions of productivity, correcting for plot characteristics and
some household characteristics (such as tractor ownership and number of
household workers) suggests a doubling of operated area leads to 10
percent lower wheat yields (and 13 percent lower rice yields), [World
Bank (2002)]. Controlling for access to credit, Jacoby and Mansuri
(2004) find that as doubling of plot area leads to a 12 percent
reduction in gross productivity (controlling here for access to credit).
Many theoretical and empirical studies suggest that insecure rights
to land adversely affects production and investment incentives. However,
strong evidence linking rights to production and investment is scarce
for South Asia despite significant regional variation within the
Subcontinent. Lin (1992) shows that the dominant source of output growth
in Chinese agriculture during 1978-1984 was the change from
collective-team large farms to individual household-based farming
(despite the often small size of household plots). Feder, et al. (1988)
demonstrated a link between title ownership on the one hand, and access
to credit and land improvements on the other. Strong evidence for the
South Asian case is provided by Banerjee and Ghatak (1996). Using
district-level data, they show that a programme of voluntary tenant
registration, with registration giving the tenant certain rights, had
dramatic effects on productivity in West Bengal from the late 1970s
onwards.
The evidence that land rights may affect investment incentives is
more speculative, though there are abundant theoretical reasons to
believe that this is the case. Besley (1996) presents three reasons why
insecure land rights should effect investment incentives: fear of
expropriation, credit access and collateral (the key mechanism in the
Feder, et al., study), and lack of trading opportunities. Basley
presents evidence that land rights are positively related to investment
in two samples from Ghana. Evidence of the influence of land rights on
investment is scarce in the South Asian case; without such evidence we
cannot weight the relative importance of land rights and wealth in
constraining investment. Besley (1996) notes an additional possibility:
that land rights may be endogenous. Farmers may invest in land over
which they have insecure title, in order to solidify their claim. If
this is the case, farmers may find it difficult to make such investments
if their incomes are low, weakening their claim to title. It is
important that investment be interpreted broadly to include the notion
of sustainability; to the extent that ongoing deterioration in the
quality of a field can be traced to private actions (as opposed to
externalities such as drainage), this should be considered as
disinvestments in the field. South Asian agriculture is experiencing an
array of environmental problems and we have little evidence on the role
that the allocation of land rights plays in these problems.
The literature on constraints faced by small farms argues that
despite greater apparent efficiency of small farmers, they face greater
difficulty in raising their profitability or expanding their holding
size. Credit constraints appear to be the biggest single obstacle but a
discriminatory policy regime and poverty have also played a major role.
If smallholders are more efficient than farmers with large holdings in
most circumstances, the question then is: why does the land market not
reallocate land to farmers with smaller holdings? We can also ask why
marginal farms continue to exist throughout South Asia: one would expect
a marginal farmer to either expand his plot or exit the agriculture
sector completely. It is often stated that smallholders face a daunting array of problems; from inadequate farm size, access to inputs and
services etc.
The leading constraint faced by smallholders is access to financial
markets. The evidence from South Asia indicates while there was a vast
expansion in institutional credit provision to agriculture, little of
this credit reached smallholders and most disbursement is concentrated
on very large farms. This is typically attributed to difficulties in
collateralising holdings with insecure title (transfer rights), or
smallholders inability to appropriate the rents from rationed card. It
is smallholders lack of access to financial markets that underlies their
greater degree of risk aversion in Binswanger's study. Binswanger
finds that the inability of smallholders to diversify risk is manifested
in the choice of non-profit maximising portfolios; in this sense,
smallholders are less efficient than farmers with large holdings. An
increase in the assets of smallholders (e.g. land) would enhance their
ability to absorb risk, and would improve their efficiency. This
argument has been used to support the case for land reform but of course
(other policies (such as improved credit market access) could have a
similar impact.
Credit market imperfections can be overcome by interlinked
transactions. Bell and Srinivasan (1989) find that interlinked
transactions are an important characteristic of agriculture even in
commercialised Punjab, where the "feudal" view of such
transactions is presumably least tenable. In particular, transactions
between a farmer and the trader or commission agent to whom he sells his
product were very common. A related area which ties together land and
labour interactions as well as constraints faced by smallholders is that
of land and demographic interactions. South Asia is generally
characterised by large family size amongst small-holders and the
landless.
Shearer, et al. (1990) point out that the type of farm that has
tended to emerge in the liberalised agricultural sectors of Latin
America is the capitalised family farm; large enough to overcome capital
market constraints but small enough to have efficient labour
supervision. These farms tend to have high capital-land and
capital-labour ratios and thus absorb little outside labour. Whether
this reflects the truly efficient outcome or the continued existence of
distortions that favour large farms is not clear. Kevane (1996) study,
presents a model featuring imperfections in land rental markets, credit
markets, insurance and labour markets and shows that there is a
possibility of a positive relationship between wealth or size and yields
even when a supervision constraint alone would favour small farms. The
mechanism is as follows: wealthier farmers have less need to engage in
off-farm labour, so the amount of labour available for agricultural
production is higher. However, because of rental market imperfections,
they are unable to fully match this labour with additional land, so that
labour input per unit land rises for wealthier farmers. He finds that
the predicted positive relationship between wealth and productivity is
indeed present in a village in Sudan.
Hirashima (1996) examines the land market behaviour in South Asia,
taking the most technological advanced Punjab (both Pakistan and India)
as an example. According to this study, land market behaviour in terms
of the rent-land price ratio or the profitability of investment in land
cannot be explained by the conventional rent theory. To address this
issue, the paper explains the market behaviour by incorporating the
asset effects in addition to the technological effects in agricultural
production. The main findings of this study can be summarised as
follows. First, throughout the British period, the R/P ratio had been
declining. The movement of the ratio even after the post independence
period can be regarded as an extension of the one observed during the
pre-independence period. Second, the analysis confirms the fact that
land price has not been the discounted value of the rent as the
conventional rent theory asserts. The recognition as well as
understandings of the asset affects in land price formation seems to be
crucial. The magnitude of the asset effects is hypothesised as a
function of the accumulation of social over-head capital and the private
capital formation of the non-agricultural sectors in the region. And
highly likely that the asset effects would be much stronger in land
price formation than technological effects in agricultural production at
least in the long run.
Third, if this argument is valid, it can further be hypothesised
that the disparity between the rent payers and rent receivers, and even
among rent receivers with different landownership, and the disparity
between regions with different accumulation of public and private
capital may not be reduced only with technological innovation within the
agricultural sector through market. Fourth, the R/P ratio in
contemporary Punjab has gone down to the extent that it is no more
possible to buy land for those who do not have initial capital. It
follows, therefore, that only those who can afford to wait for the asset
effects to be captured in the long-run, without expecting much return in
the short-run, can participate in land market. In this situation, the
income from the outside sector seems to be the only means for the small
and marginal farmers or landless non-farm households in villages in
Punjab to participate in land market. Fifth, with respect to the policy
implication of our findings, the following four points may be relevant.
First, it is important to recognise that the disparity question cannot
be answered neither in flow terms (income), nor stock terms (asset)
alone, but in the dynamic relationship between the two. Second, one of
the key areas for reducing disparity is the pattern and direction of
public investment in social overhead capital in the region. Therefore,
public investment should be redirected, if necessary, to minimise the
growing disparity among regions. Third, it seems to be important to
prevent the capital gain from land holding to grow by introducing
appropriate land tax policy. Fourth, the effort has to be made to
collect land price data systematically and make them accessible to the
public.
The author is of the view that since the land price data are not
published after independence both in Pakistan and India, it is difficult
to confirm whether or not the observed trend of declining rent-land
price ratio can be observed after independence. The study is based upon
the scattered field survey data. Two sets of field survey data are
available for the Pakistan Punjab. One is the data collected by the
author in 197172 from four villages [Hirashima (1978)], and the other by
Renkow for the period 1968-89 [Renkow (1991)]. According to the former
study, the average R/P ratio came to be 4.1 percent in the case of rent
in kind, and 3.5 percent in cash rent. The ratio based on the shadow
price of land (marginal productivity of land) was 5.3 percent. It is
noted that these ratios are ones in the midst of the green revolution in
Pakistan Punjab, which might have pushed the short-run R/P ratio
somewhat upward. Nevertheless, it can be argued that these ratios are
more or less in line with the R/P ratios observed during the British
period. The author presumes that the effects have been positive and
increasing, thereby reducing the R/P ratio much lower than the market
interest rate. The study raises questions with respect to the direction
of public investment, land tax policy, and the growing disparity between
rent receivers and rent payers. Another study by Renkow covers the
period 1960-89. In this study, the land price data were collected from
37 irrigated villages and 42 rainfed villages in the Pakistan Punjab
which were away from the urban centres in order to avoid urban
influence. The data on rent were not collected from the surveyed
villages, but borrowed from the Punjab Economic Research Institute
(PERI) data collected in other villages. Therefore, the R/P ratios are
not strictly comparable. The study shows that the R/P ratio in the
rainfed villages had declined from 2.85 percent in 1960 to 1.98 percent
in 1989, and from 3.93 percent to 2.59 percent in the irrigated
villages. The study confirms the faster increase of land price than rent
in general, and the faster increase of rent than land price during the
green revolution period (1976-86). The study also found out that the 70
percent of the incremental portion of land price was explained by the
technological innovation, and that the disparity between rainfed and
irrigated villages has been narrowed mainly due to influence of
remittance money from the oil producing countries in the rainfed
villages.
Pakistan has had numerous attempts at carrying out land reforms.
Most observers, however, are unanimous that these reforms failed to
achieve the desired goals. A political economy approach is essential for
understanding the failure of land reform efforts and distortions in
agricultural input and output markets. South Asia features an asymmetry
between small and large farmers in the political as well as the economic
sphere. Indeed, it is access to political power that has upset the
functioning of key markets (notably land and water) in South Asia, and
markets cannot be studied in isolation from these political
considerations. Policy distortions or market imperfections can create a
bias towards large farms, allowing them to persist as such, despite
their inefficiency. Several examples can be cited here. First, price
policy or farm subsidies may favour large farmers. Second, concentrated
landownership may reduce the amount of land available for sale at any
time. A feature of Pakistan more so than other South Asian countries is
highly concentrated landownership and an associated "feudal"
social structure. Large inefficient farm persist because their owners
have little interest in profit-maximisation. Land is instead held for
political power or prestige, and, if sold at all, is sold in large
parcels to other large landowners.
Land fragmentation, as distinguished from farm size, has also been
considered as a source of productivity loss, but these losses have not
been quantified, and reasons for the persistence of fragmentation are
poorly understood. It seems clear in principle that land fragmentation
would lower productivity by raising transports costs between fields, and
preventing the realisation of economies of scale. Additionally, the
hedges or other boundaries between plots may result in a significant
loss of arable land. However, Binswanger (1994) cautions that the
influence of fragmentation on productivity can be overstated.
Consolidation by sale to someone outside the family is complicated by
the right of pre-emption or right of first refusal which family members
enjoy on inherited land. Equally important, transaction costs may
inhibit the transfer of small plots, even when all parties would be
willing to carry out the transaction. Finally for reasons already
outlined, land markets may be extremely thin. An offer to sell land may
result in a large fall in the price of land; the opposite holds with an
offer to buy. Once we acknowledge the presence of transaction costs,
than the past history of land distribution becomes relevant for
understanding the current situation. There are a variety of reasons why
a history of community landownership may have resulted in fragmented
plots which has not been undone even if land rights are now allocated
individually [Heston and Kumar (1983)].
High transaction costs are viewed as a significant impediment to
the functioning of land markets. Transfers of land rights are
complicated in South Asian land markets by lack of explicit title to
land, and informal and customary rights. This hypothesis can be seen as
either an independent hypothesis or as a by-product of the others, which
are indicative of substantial barriers to access to land in South Asia.
However, recent evidence does point to some dynamism in South Asian land
markets. Recent trends in Pakistan and India indicate that middle-sized
farms are taking in land from those at each end of the distribution.
Informal rights should not necessarily be seen as an impediment to a
well-functioning land market. Indeed, a potential problem relating to land rights in the liberalised environment is that the customary rights
on which farmers depend may be eroded. South Asian agriculture has a
considerable array of customary rights (many of which protect small
farmers), which are not always recognised in common law.
III. A PROFILE OF CHANGING LAND MARKET IN PAKISTAN
The discussion in the previous section had highlighted the role of
ownership and tenancy relationships for the productivity--land size
relationships in rural Pakistan. Despite land reforms introduced since
1947, weak implementation of such reforms measures has not changed
drastically the defacto agrarian relations on the ground although dejure
agrarian relationships have undergone a drastic change as a result of
land reforms introduced in independent Pakistan. Informal relationships
between land owners and land users are important determinants of
resource use efficiency.
(i) Tenurial Relations
Pakistan had inherited two main land-tenure systems with some
regional variations between different provinces. Locus of landownership
and extent of inequitable distribution of land distinguish the two
systems from each other. The samindari system and the peasant-proprietor
land systems were the two systems. The intent of the land reforms
measures was to move towards the later system with protection of rights
for the tenants who were the actual cultivators of land.
Under the samindari system, there were two sub-systems. Jagirdars
were given revenue-free land estates by the government. The land owned
by Jagirdars was generally cultivated by tenants and share-croppers.
Tenants were of two kinds i.e. occupancy tenants or tenants-at-will. The
occupancy tenants had permanent, heritable and transferable rights to
cultivate the Jagir lands. Tenants-at-will had no such legal rights. The
second group ofzamindars had to pay land tax to government. They used to
engage both occupancy tenants and tenants-atwill for cultivation of
their land. Sindh was the province where this system was generally
prevalent with dominant category of tenants being tenants-at-will. These
tenants are called haris in local language. The tenancy reforms
introduced in 1950 had given protection to tenants-at-will.
Implementation of these laws has been very weak.
The other land-tenure system is that of peasant-proprietorship. The
peasants enjoy landownership rights and cultivate land mostly on their
own account by employing family labour and/or hired labour.
In the zamindari system, landlords owned and controlled the use of
their land. Tenants had no legal rights. Most zamindars had parceled out
land in small lots to tenants for cultivation. Zamindars used to hire a
supervisor for looking after their land affairs. The tenants provided
their labour and a pair of oxen for cultivation of land. 50 percent of
produce was given to the landlords as rent of the land. Contracts were
mostly verbal and lasted for no more than a year at a time. Landlords
used to shift around the tenants on their lands so that no individual
was listed on a particular plot for more than one year. In Punjab and
NWFP, occupancy tenants had legal protection. Tenants-at-will will had
no effective protection. In addition to paying half of produce as rents,
tenants had also to provide some services to the landlord free from any
remuneration of their labour.
In Table 1, we provide information on the relative importance of
owner-operated and tenanted area by farm size. This table also provides
information on the tenancy contracts i.e. being share-cropped, leased on
fixed rent and on other terms for the census years of 1990 and 2000. The
share of operated area increased from 76.2 percent in 1990 to 81.4
percent in 2000. The dominant form of tenancy contracts is that of
share-cropping. Fixed leases are about 25 percent of the total tenancy
contracts. There are some minor variations between provinces but the
picture described above persists for all provinces. The increasing
importance of owner-operation and the reliance on sharecropping are two
well-established tendencies. The tendency for self-cultivation is due to
fear of further land reforms and the increasing spread of capitalist
farming. The persistence of share-cropping is mainly explained in terms
of protection against risks.
(ii) Pattern of Landownership
Landownership in Pakistan and its provinces is highly skewed. The
inequality in landownership has increased over time. Table 2 presents
the Gini coefficient of ownership holdings for four years i.e. 1972,
1980, 1990 and 2000.
The Gini coefficient increases from 0.66 in 1972 to 0.75 in 2000
for Pakistan. A sharp increase in inequality is found for two provinces
of Punjab and NWFP. In the case of Sindh and Balochistan, the Gini
coefficient decreases slightly. However, it should be noted that the
extent of inequality in landownership in all provinces and Pakistan is
quite high. There is also a difference in the pattern of land
distribution over time. The Gini coefficient for Pakistan remains
constant till 1990 and increased sharply in 2000. In Sindh and
Balochistan, the fall in the coefficient is sustained throughout the
period.
(iii) Trends in Operated Area by Tenure and Farm Size
The Gini coefficients given in Table 3 show a high degree of
inequality in the distribution of operational holdings. However, the
concentration in access to land use is less concentrated than is the
case for landownership. But for all tenurial classes taken together, the
distributions in the NWFP and Balochistan are more unequal those in
Sindh, the Punjab and overall Pakistan. The distribution of operational
holdings worsened somewhat between the 1972-2000 period.
Among the different tenurial classes, the distribution of farm area
among farms of various sizes has been relatively more unequal under
owner-operated farms. Among the different tenurial classes, the
distribution of farm area among farms of various sizes has been
relatively more unequal under owner-operated farms.
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The study was intended to provide a description and analysis of
different facets of land market and identify the major constraints in
the proper functioning of this market. The study was based mainly on the
previous studies. The data from different Agricultural Censuses were
used to profile the pattern of land distribution and land use. The major
findings of the study are briefly summarised.
First, the relationship between farm size and productivity measured
through the profit frontier approach or through simple regression equation between farm size and production per acre is found to vary
between different studies. The inverse relationship between farm size
and output per acre is a recurrent feature found in data. This is
apparently due to land-labour interactions. Small farmers have a lower
opportunity cost of labour, can exploit more marginal land, cultivate a
larger proportion of their land and as a result achieve higher output
and yields. On the other hand, small farmers are more credit-constrained
and large farmers less so. A low effective price of capital for large
farmers leads to substitution of machines for labour. The large farmers
use capital intensive inputs. Depending on which effect is dominant, one
can get inverse relationship, positive relationship or a U-shaped curve.
The review of studies provides examples of each relationship. One needs
to be cautious in drawing public policy implications for land reforms of
the redistributive type. The impact of land distribution on production
and equity would depend on the complementary policies for the supply of
modern inputs and their interface with the land distribution.
Second, the importance of secure titles to land as well as
protection of the tenants for their prescribed share in inputs and
outputs is obvious. However, we did not find much empirical work on
these aspects in Pakistan. The importance of sharecropping as the most
preferred farm of tenancy emerges clearly from the data. The literature
on factors responsible for this result is patchy, however.
Third, the participation in land market is by and large excluded
for tenants, landless and small farmers. These groups are excluded from
the land market due to severe credit constraints they face to buy land.
They do not have enough savings of their own and do not have suitable
collateral to pledge for getting access to credit. Insecurity of land
tenure arrangements and almost zero probability of buying land has
reduced this segment of rural population to be condemned to the lower
strata in rural areas. The only course left for them is to turn to the
labour market--with or without skill development or to engage in
activities like animal raising which are not land-based but are
labour-intensive for the landless households.
Fourth, the concentration of land was high at the time of creation
of Pakistan. Despite few attempts at land distribution, the Gini
coefficient for ownership holdings has gone up from 0.66 in 1972 to
00.75 in 2000. It has increased for the provinces of Punjab and NWFP
considerably but has shown a modest decline in Sindh and Balochistan.
This outcome is due to the unequalising nature of land distribution
through private land market.
Fifth, misguided land reforms which had fixed a ceiling on land
holdings and the lowering of this ceiling over time in three land
reforms of 1959, 1972 and 1977 had made tenancy unattractive to land
owners. Land was split between members of the family to avoid giving
land to government and land previously sharecropped was resumed by
landlords for self-cultivation. This was accompanied by
capital-intensive farming resulting in lesser employment opportunities
for landless labour.
Last but not the least, the study spells out the key aspects of the
nature of land market in Pakistan's context. In view of the fact
that the ongoing interest rate is generally higher than the rate of
return on land investment as long as the land is used for farming, it is
not possible for the prospective farmers, without initial capital at
hand, to participate in the land market. In other words, land markets
are open only for those who are enjoying excess liquidity in the form of
rental income. The higher growth rate of land value than productivity
growth implies that the land value is no longer the discounted value of
rent as postulated in the conventional theory. This land-rent
relationship has assured the continuous flow of capital gains for rent
receivers and continuously squeezed the rent payers out of the land
market.
Authors' Note: We are grateful to Dr Musleh-ud Din, Dr Ijaz
Ghani, and Mr Kalbe Abbas for help in the preparation of the paper.
REFERENCES
Ali, M., and J. C. Flinn (1989) Profit Efficiency Among Basmati
Rice Producers in Pakistan. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71, 303-310.
Ali, M., and M. A. Chaudhry (1990) Inter-regional Farm Efficiency
in Pakistan's Punjab: A Frontier Production Function Study. Journal
of Agricultural Economics 41, 62-74.
Bagi, F. S. (1981) Relationship between Farm Size and Economic
Efficiency: An Analysis of Farm Level Data from Haryana (India).
Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 29, 317-326.
Bagi, F. S. (1987) Farm-level Technical Efficiency of Individual
Crops. Department of Rural Development, Tennessee State University, USA.
(Unpublished Paper.)
Banerjee, Abhijit, and Maitreesh Ghatak (1996) Empowerment and
Efficiency: The Economics of Tenancy Reform. MIT. (Working Paper.)
Battese, G. E., S. J. Malik, and S. Broca (1993) Production
Functions for Wheat-farmers in Selected Districts of Pakistan: An
Application of Stochastic Frontier Production Function with Time-varying
Inefficiency Effects. The Pakistan Development Review 32:2, 233-268.
Bell, Clive, and T. N. Srinivasan (1989) Interlinked Transactions
in Rural Markets: An Empirical Study of Andhra Pradesh, Bihar and
Punjab. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 51:1, 73-84.
Besley, Timothy (1996) Property Rights and Investment Incentives:
Theory and Evidence from Ghana. Journal of Political Economy 103:5,
903-937.
Bhalla, S. (1979) Farm Size Productivity and Technical Change in
Indian Agriculture. In R. A. Berry and W. R. Cline (eds.) Agrarian
Structure and Productivity in Developing Countries. Baltimore: John
Hopkins Press. 141-193.
Bharadwaj, K. (1974) Notes on Farm Size and Productivity. Economic
and Political Weekly 9:13, A 11-A24. Bhattacharya, N., and G. R. Saini
(1972) Farm Size and Productivity: A Fresh Look. Economic and Political
Weekly 7:26, A63-A72.
Binswanger, Hans P. (1994) Agriculture and Rural Development:
Painful Lessons. Presented to the 32nd Annual Meeting of the South
African Agricultural Economics Association.
Bravo-Ureta, B. E., and R. E. Evenson (1994) Efficiency in
Agricultural Production: The Case of Peasant Farmers in Eastern
Paraguay. Agricultural Economics 10, 27-37.
Chaddha, A. N. (1978) Farm Size and Productivity Revisited: Some
Notes from Recent Experience of Punjab. Economic and Political Weekly
13:39, A82-A96.
Chattopadhyay, M., and A. Rudra (1976) Size-productivity Revisited.
Economic and Political Weekly 11:39.
Chaudhry, M. G., Manzoor A. Gill, and G. Mustafa Chaudhry (1985)
Size-productivity Relationship in Pakistan's Agriculture in the
Seventies. The Pakistan Development Review 24:3&4, 349-361.
Commander, S. (1987) The Sate and Agricultural Development in Egypt
Since 1973. London: Overseas Development Institute.
Dasgupta, B. (1977) Agrarian Change and the New Technology in
India. Geneva: United Nations Research Institute.
Deolalikar, A. (1981) Inverse Relationship between Productivity and
Farm Size: A Test Using Regional Data from India. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 63, 275-279.
Dyer, G. (1991) Farm Size-farm Productivity Re-examined: Evidence
from Rural Egypt. The Journal Peasant Studies 19, 59-92.
Feder, Gershon, Tonroj Onchan, Yongyuth Chalamwong, and Chitra
Hongladarom (1988) Land Policies and Farm Productivity in Thailand.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.
Ghose, A. K. (1979) Farm Size and Land Productivity in Indian
Agriculture: A Reappraisal. The Journal of Development Studies 16,
27-49.
Herdt, R. W., and A. M. Mandac (1981) Modern Technology and
Economic Efficiency of Philippines Rice Farmers. Economic Development
and Cultural Change 29, 375-399.
Heston, Alan, and Dharma Kumar (1983) The Persistence of Land
Fragmentation in Peasant Agriculture: An Analysis of South Asian Cases.
Explorations in Economic History 20:2 (April), 199-220.
Hirashima, S. (1978) The Structure of Disparity in Developing
Agriculture. Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economics.
Hirashima, S. (1996) Asset Effects in Land Price Formation in
Agriculture: The Experience from South Asia. The Pakistan Development
Review 35:4, 963-976.
Hirashima, S. (2000) Issues in Agricultural Reforms: Public
Investment and Land Market Development. Economic and Political Weekly,
October.
Hossain, M. (1977) Farm Size, Tenancy and Land Productivity: An
Analysis of Farm Level Data in Bangladesh Agriculture. Bangladesh
Development Studies 5, 285-348.
Huang, C., and F. S. Bagi (1984) Technical Efficiency on Individual
Farms in Northwest India. Southern Economic Journal 51, 108-15.
Jacoby, Hanan G., and Ghazala Mansuri (2004) Agricultural Credit
and Farm Performance: Evidence from Pakistan. Background paper prepared
for the Pakistan Rural Factor Markets Study. (Manuscript.)
Kalirajan, K. P. (1981) An Econometric Analysis of Yield
Variability in Paddy Production. Canadian Journal of Agricultural
Economics 29, 283-294.
Khan, M. H. (1979) Farm Size and Land Productivity Relationships in
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 18:1, 69-77.
Khan, M. H., and D. R. Maki (1980) Relative Efficiency by Farm Size
and the Green Revolution in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review
19:1, 51-64.
Khan, W., and R. N. Tripathy (1972) Intensive Agriculture and
Modern Inputs: Prospects of Small Farmers--A Study in West Godavari
District. Hyderabad: National Institute of Community Development.
Khusro, A. M. (1964) Returns to Scale in Indian Agriculture. Indian
Journal of Agricultural Economies 19, 51-80.
Lau, L. J., and P. A. Yotopoulos (1971) A Test for Relative
Efficiency and Application to Indian Agriculture. American Economic
Review 61, 92-109.
Masumdar, D. (1965) Size of Farm and Productivity: A Problem of
Indian Peasant Agriculture. Economica 32, 161-173.
Naqvi, S. N. H., M. H. Khan, and M. G. Chaudhry (1989) Structural
Change in Pakistan's Agriculture. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics.
Pakistan, Government of (2001-02) Household Integrated Economic
Survey. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Parikh, A., and K. Shah (1994) Measurement of Technical Efficiency
in the North West Frontier Province of Pakistan. Journal of Agricultural
Economies 45, 132-138.
Parikh, A., F. Ali, and M. K. Shah (1995) Measurement of Economic
Efficiency in Pakistan's Agriculture. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 77, 675-685.
Pinheiro, A. (1992) An Econometric Analysis of Farm Level
Efficiency of Small Farms in the Dominican Republic. M.S. Thesis,
University of Connecticut, Storrs, USA.
Radwan, S., and E. Lee (1986) Agrarian Change in Egypt: An Anatomy
of Rural Poverty. Geneva: ILO.
Rao, C. H. H. (1966) Alternative Explanations of the Inverse
Relationship between Farm Size and Output per Acre in India. The Indian
Economic Review 1, 1-12.
Rao, C. H. H. (1975) Technological Change and the Distribution of
Gains in Indian Agriculture. New Delhi: Macmillan.
Rao, V., and T. Chotigeat (1981) The Inverse Relationship between
Size of Land Holdings and Agricultural Productivity. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 63, 571-574.
Ray, S. (1985) Measurement and Test of Efficiency of Farms in
Linear Programming Models: A Study of West Bengal Farms. Oxford Bulletin
of Economics and Statistics 47, 371-86.
Renkow, Mitch (1991) Land Price, Land Rents, and Technological
Change: Evidence from Pakistan. Mexico: CIMMYT (Economic Working Paper
90/01).
Roy, P. (1981) Transition in Agriculture: Empirical Indicators and
Results. Journal of Peasant Studies 8, 212-241.
Sahota, G. S. (1968) Efficiency of Resource Allocation in Indian
Agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 50, 584-605.
Saini, G. R. (1971) Holding Size, Productivity and Some Related
Aspects of Indian Agriculture. Economic and Political Weekly 26,
A79-A85.
Saini, G. R. (1980) Farm Size Productivity and Some Related Issues
in India's Agriculture: A Review. Agricultural Situation in India
34:11, 777-783.
Sen, A. K. (1962) An Aspect of Indian Agriculture. Economic Weekly
14, 243-246.
Shearer, Eric B., Susana Lastarria-Cornhiel, and Dina Mesbah (1990)
The Reform of Rural Land Markets in Latin America and the Caribbean:
Research, Theory, and Policy Implications. Land Tenure Centre,
University of Wisconsin. (Paper No. 141.)
Sidhu, S. S. (1974) Economics of Technical Change in Wheat
Production in the Indian Punjab. American Journal of Agricultural
Economic 56, 217-226.
Squires, D., and S. Tabor (1991) Technical Efficiency and Future
Production Gains in Indonesian Agriculture. The Developing Economies 29,
258-70.
World Bank (2002) Pakistan Poverty Assessment: Poverty in Pakistan:
Vulnerabilities, Social Gaps, and Rural Dynamics. Washington, D. C.: The
World Bank.
World Bank (2004) Pakistan Rural Factor Markets: Policy Reforms for
Growth and Equity. Washington, D. C.: The World Bank.
Yotopoulos, P. A., and L. J. Lau (1973) A Test for Relative
Economic Efficiency--Some Further Results. American Economic Review 63,
214-223.
Yotopoulos, P. A., L. J. Lau, and K. Sonel (1970) Labour Intensity
and Relative Efficiency in Indian Agriculture. Food Research Institute
Studies in Agricultural Economics, Trade, and Development 0, 43-55.
(1) Amartya Sen (1962) An Aspect of Indian Agriculture. Economic
amt Political Weekly 14, 243-246.
(2) Berry and Cline: Agrarian Structure and Productivity in
Developing Countries (1979).
(3) Binswanger (1984).
Madeeha G. Qureshi is Staff Economist and Sarfraz Khan Qureshi was
Director at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Distribution of Operated Area by Ownership and Tenancy Contracts,
Pakistan
% Rented Out
Owner- Share-
Sharecropping operated cropping
Operated Area (Acres) 1990 2000 1990 2000
<5 77.3 80.7 17.4 14.5
5-<12.5 65.3 75.2 27.5 18.6
12.5-<25 68.6 75.9 22.9 17.2
25-<50 73.7 81.0 18.0 12.9
50-<150 82.0 85.2 10.3 10.0
<150 90.4 90.1 4.1 4.7
Total 76.2 81.4 16.7 13.0
% Rented Out
Sharecropping Leased Other
Operated Area (Acres) 1990 2000 1990 2000
<5 4.8 4.5 0.5 0.3
5-<12.5 6.6 5.8 0.6 0.3
12.5-<25 8.1 6.5 0.5 0.4
25-<50 7.8 5.6 0.5 0.5
50-<150 7.1 4.4 0.6 0.4
<150 4.8 3.9 0.7 1.3
Total 6.5 5.1 0.6 0.5
Source: Data from Census of Agriculture, Ministry of Food,
Agriculture and Livestock, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad.
Table 2
Gini Coefficient for Ownership Holding
1972 1980 1990 2000
Pakistan 0.66 0.65 0.66 0.75
Punjab 0.63 0.62 0.62 0.71
NWFP 0.68 0.69 0.65 0.86
Sindh 0.69 0.63 0.63 0.67
Balochistan 0.69 0.68 0.70 0.68
Source: Government of Pakistan (Various Issues) Agriculture
Census Reports.
Table 3
Gini Coefficient for Operated Area, by Mode of Tenancy
Total Owner-
Operated Owner- tenant Tenant-
Type of Tenancy Area operated operated operated
1972
Pakistan 0.52 0.61 0.47 0.40
Punjab 0.49 0.58 0.43 0.40
NWFP 0.64 0.62 0.58 0.61
Sindh 0.43 0.57 0.46 0.32
Balochistan 0.64 0.68 0.61 0.47
1980
Pakistan 0.53 0.60 0.47 0.40
Punjab 0.51 0.58 0.44 0.40
NWFP 0.64 0.65 0.61 0.53
Sindh 0.47 0.54 0.47 0.33
Balochistan 0.62 0.65 0.55 0.42
1990
Pakistan 0.61 0.62 0.49 0.44
Punjab 0.55 0.59 0.47 0.44
NWFP 0.61 0.62 0.55 0.50
Sindh 0.51 0.57 0.51 0.34
Balochistan 0.63 0.66 0.52 0.44
2000
Pakistan 0.61 0.61 0.46 0.47
Punjab 0.57 0.58 0.47 0.49
NWFP 0.63 0.63 0.57 0.48
Sindh 0.56 0.59 0.56 0.46
Balochistan 0.65 0.67 0.63 0.46