首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月07日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Decomposition of changes in poverty measures: sectoral and institutional considerations for the poverty reduction strategy paper of Pakistan.
  • 作者:Khan, Aliya H. ; Azhar, Ali Shan
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2003
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:Two extremely significant empirical questions on the relationship between growth, distribution and poverty have remained the focus of attention for researchers and academicians. First, how does a change in aggregate poverty reflect intrasectoral gains/losses versus intersectoral shifts in population? Second, how much of an observed change in poverty can be attributed to the changes in the distribution of income, as distinct from growth in average incomes? Standard inequality measures like the Gini coefficient can be misleading in this context. At any rate, the change in an inequality measure can be a poor guide to its quantitative impact on poverty.

Decomposition of changes in poverty measures: sectoral and institutional considerations for the poverty reduction strategy paper of Pakistan.


Khan, Aliya H. ; Azhar, Ali Shan


This paper aims at developing a better understanding of the measured changes in aggregate poverty in Pakistan between 1979 and 1998-99 to explore the fundamental premises of an appropriate poverty reduction strategy for Pakistan. In devising an effective approach to anti-poverty policy, the Pakistan government's Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper, PRSP, is taken as the starting reference. The paper utilises certain theoretical advances in poverty decomposition. The "sectoral decomposition" of changes in poverty decomposes the changes in poverty in Pakistan into intrasectoral effects, intersectoral population shifts and their interaction. The "growth-equity decomposition" of a change in poverty quantifies the relative contribution of growth versus redistribution to changes in poverty measures. The quantitative significance of the sectoral impact of poverty on the rural population from the sectoral poverty decomposition technique strongly suggests the need for more targeted interventions for combating rural poverty. Notwithstanding the importance of redistributional measures, the growth-equity poverty decomposition technique emphasises the relatively greater importance of consumption growth in poverty alleviation. The paper acknowledges that the approach of the PRSP is well focused. However, a more comprehensive and coordinated strategy for addressing rural poverty in Pakistan is outlined in the study. The paper also stresses the necessity to overcome the prevailing governance crisis to lay the foundation of a successful poverty reduction strategy in Pakistan. In this context, it argues that the key problem areas that have emerged in the implementation of Pakistan's new "Devolution Plan" are related to the lack of funds, capacity and systems.

I. INTRODUCTION

Two extremely significant empirical questions on the relationship between growth, distribution and poverty have remained the focus of attention for researchers and academicians. First, how does a change in aggregate poverty reflect intrasectoral gains/losses versus intersectoral shifts in population? Second, how much of an observed change in poverty can be attributed to the changes in the distribution of income, as distinct from growth in average incomes? Standard inequality measures like the Gini coefficient can be misleading in this context. At any rate, the change in an inequality measure can be a poor guide to its quantitative impact on poverty.

Ravallion and Huppi (1991) proposed decomposition formulae to throw light on the contributions of sectoral gains and population shifts (on the one hand) and economic growth and changes in inequality (on the other) to aggregate changes in poverty. They found that both population shifts and gains to the urban and rural sectors alleviated aggregate poverty in Indonesia over the 1984-87 period. In addition, they obtained estimates of the relative contributions of growth and greater equity to poverty alleviation in Indonesia. Datt and Ravallion (1992) extended the analysis to study poverty in Brazil and India during the 1980s. Kakwani (1993) explored the relation between economic growth and poverty for Cote d'Ivoire from 1980-85. He developed his own methodology to measure separately the impact of changes in average income and income inequality on poverty. Kakwani (2000) applied the same methodology to analyse changes in poverty in Thailand covering the period from 1988-94. Recently, Contreas (2003) examined the evolution of poverty and inequality in Chile between 1990 and 1996. Using the "Datt-Ravallion decomposition", he computed that economic growth accounted for over 85 percent of the poverty reduction in Chile.

Over the last decade, we have witnessed some pioneering work on the relationship between growth, poverty and inequality in Pakistan. Amjad and Kemal (1997) identified economic indicators, which can best capture the major correlates of poverty. Their finding is that the overall poverty levels in Pakistan (1963-1993) are positively correlated with the Gini coefficient and negatively correlated with real per capita GNP. Ali and Tahir (1999) analysed the long-run relationship between growth, poverty and inequality in Pakistan. They estimated the long-run elasticities of poverty with respect to growth and inequality.

A number of recent studies indicate that poverty, which declined rapidly in the 1970s and 1980s, returned to Pakistan in the late 1980s. In the late 1980s, government fiscal deficits (which had previously helped fuel growth but which were no longer tenable) had to be drastically cut to avert financial collapse, accompanying structural reforms (1) and these along with declining remittances combined to not just slow down but reverse the decline in poverty [Amjad and Kemal (1997)]. The increasing incidence of poverty in Pakistan since the late 1980s and continuing throughout the 1990s has severely damaged the growth potential of the economy through a variety of channels. Not least is the manifestation of poverty through the emergence of lawlessness, sectarianism and ethnic conflicts, which have collectively jaundiced the investment climate in Pakistan.

The renewed focus on poverty reduction as the principal goal of Pakistan's development policy framework emphasises the increasing need to quantify the relative contribution to changes in poverty measures of growth versus redistribution on one hand and the role played by intrasectoral gains/losses versus intersectoral shifts in population on the other. The present study contributes to the existing literature on the relationship between growth, poverty and inequality in Pakistan by rigorously quantifying the contribution of distributional changes to poverty alleviation, controlling for growth effects, and the contribution of growth, controlling for relevant distributional changes. The study also provides a decomposition of the changes in poverty in Pakistan into intrasectoral effects, intersectoral population shifts and their interaction.

The plan of the paper is that Section II discusses the decomposition of a measured change in aggregate poverty into constituent parts that indicate intrasectoral gains versus intersectoral shifts in population. Empirical results for Pakistan are also presented. Section III briefly reviews and uses the "Datt-Ravallion decomposition" to try to better understand the sources of the measured change in aggregate poverty in Pakistan. Finally, the last section concludes the paper and suggests broad policy measures, specifically in the context of the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP) of Pakistan.

II. SECTORAL DECOMPOSITION OF CHANGES IN POVERTY

The "sectoral decomposition" of changes in poverty aims at assessing the relative gains to the poor within specific sectors and the contribution of changes in the distribution of the population across these sectors. Suppose that we have poverty measures (P) for each of two dates t and t+n (say), and two sectors, i (i = u and r for urban and rural). The change in aggregate poverty between the two dates can be decomposed into intrasectoral effects, population shifts and interaction effects, as follows:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)

Where [P.sub.i,t] denotes measured poverty in sector i at date t with corresponding population share [n.sub.i,t]. Intuitively, the "intrasectoral effects" is the contribution of gains/losses to the poor within the urban sector and the rural sector corresponding to the change in aggregate poverty. The "population shift effect" shows how changes in the distribution of the population across sectors contributed to the change in aggregate poverty. The "interaction effect" can be interpreted as a measure of the correlation between the population shifts and the intrasectoral changes in poverty.

Estimation results of Equation 1 in Table 1 give the urban-rural sectoral decomposition of the aggregate poverty changes in Pakistan over the 1979--1987-88 period. We find that both population shifts and gains to the urban and rural sectors alleviated aggregate poverty. These improvements were dampened slightly by the negative "interaction effect". The gains to the rural sector accounted for the vast majority of aggregate poverty alleviation and clearly more than the sector's population share. Gains to the urban sector and population shifts from the rural to the urban sector did contribute to poverty alleviation, but were quantitatively less important than the direct gains to the rural poor.

Table 2 provides a sectoral decomposition for the 1987-88--1998-99 period for Pakistan. Both the urban and rural sectors contributed to the increase in aggregate poverty. Though the "interaction effect" and the "population shift effect" alleviated poverty, the overall impact was negligible. The quantitative importance of the sectoral loss to the rural population is notable. A whopping 86.3 percent of the poverty increase in Pakistan from 1987-88--1998-99 can be attributed to the rural sector.

III. GROWTH-EQUITY DECOMPOSITION OF CHANGES IN POVERTY

We can decompose the change in poverty into the change in the mean consumption level of a given distribution, and a change in the distribution of consumption around the mean. We may call this the "growth-equity decomposition" of a change in poverty. For this decomposition, we confine attention to poverty measures which can be fully characterised in terms of the poverty line, the mean income of the distribution, and the Lorenz curve representing the structure of relative income inequalities. The poverty measure [P.sub.t] at date t is written as

[P.SUB.t] = P (z/[[mu].sub.t], [L.sub.t]) (2)

Where, z is the poverty line, [[mu].sub.t] is the mean income/consumption and [L.sub.t] is a vector of parameters fully describing the Lorenz curve at date t. The level of poverty may change due to a change in the mean income/consumption [[mu].sub.t] relative to the poverty line or due to a change in relative inequalities [L.sub.t].

The "growth component" of a change in the poverty measure is defined as the change in poverty due to a change in the mean while holding the Lorenz curve constant at some initial level. The "redistribution component" is the change in poverty due to a change in the Lorenz curve while keeping the mean income constant at some initial level. To resolve the issue empirically, let [P.sub.1+n.sup.*] denote the poverty level that would have occurred at date t+n if the change in mean consumption since date t had not been associated with any change in relative consumption levels. In other words, [P.sub.t+n.sup.*] is obtained by applying the mean at date t+n to the Lorenz curve at date t. Similarly, let [P.sub.t+n.sup.**] denote the poverty level that one would have found at date t+n if only the Lorenz curve had shifted since date t, leaving the mean unchanged; that is, [P.sub.t+n.sup.**] is computed by applying the Lorenz curve at date t+n to the mean at date t. The observed change in poverty over dates t and t+n can then be decomposed as follows:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)

The two simulated poverty measures, [P.sub.t+n.sup.*] and [P.sub.t+n.sup.**] are calculated by econometrically estimating parametric specifications of the Lorenz curves and deriving the poverty measures as functions of those parameters and of the mean income and the poverty line. The non-zero residual in Equation (3) exists whenever the poverty measure is not additively separable between u and L, i.e., whenever the marginal effects on the poverty index of changes in the mean (Lorenz curve) depend on the precise Lorenz curve(mean). Hence, the residual is the difference between the distributionally neutral growth effect given the Lorenz curve at date t+n and that evaluated at the Lorenz curve at date t.

In general, the residual does not vanish. It will vanish if either (i) the distributionally neutral growth effect on poverty is independent of the Lorenz curve (or equivalently, if the distributional effect is independent of the mean) i.e. the poverty measure is additively separable between u and L or (ii) the changes in one or both the mean u and Lorenz curve are infinitesimally small. This does not hold for the poverty measures and Lorenz curve parameter estimates considered in this study, nor does it appear likely to ever hold for any plausible Lorenz curve. Infact, most poverty measures used in practice are not separable into the mean and the Lorenz curve. A residual will thus arise, given that one has fixed the Lorenz curve (in measuring the growth component) and the level of the mean (when measuring the distribution component). Moreover, the residual cannot be apportioned between the growth and redistribution components. Such an exercise will be arbitrary and convey a false impression that the decomposition is exact. Infact, the residual can be of considerable interest in its own right. In particular, it can be interpreted as the contribution to aggregate poverty of the interaction effects between growth and distributional changes. (2)

Table 3 gives the estimates of the decomposition of changes in total poverty in Pakistan between 1979 and 1993-94 using the methodology in Equation 3. The table gives the increments in percentage points, both in the aggregate and by components and sub-periods. It is observed that the shifts in the Lorenz curve contributed to poverty alleviation for the period 1979--1987-88. However, the majority of the reduction in poverty can be attributed to higher mean consumption for a given distribution of consumption. Between 1987-88 and 1993-94, we find that both the growth and redistribution components contributed to the increase in poverty, though the former factor was quantitatively more important. The residuals in the decomposition vary in size.

Our results suggest that it would be hazardous to assume the residual is zero, or simply lump it into the components.

To facilitate comparisons, Table 4 and Table 5 provide the estimates of the relative contributions to poverty changes in Pakistan of changes in mean consumption and distributional shifts. The distributional effects (12.3 percent) contributed to the alleviation of poverty in Pakistan between 1979 and 1987-88. However, growth in mean consumption accounted for the bulk of the improvement (84.9 percent). The growth component again dominated the redistribution component in Pakistan for the period 1987-88 to 1993-94. Changes in distribution (25.42 percent) reinforced the adverse effect of the decrease in mean consumption (61.11 percent). The above results complement the evidence obtained from the "sectoral decomposition" of poverty in Pakistan and may indeed have a strong bearing on the sectoral shares of poverty.

IV. IMPLICATIONS OF EMPIRICAL RESULTS FOR THE PRSP

This paper aims at providing insight to policy-makers into a framework for action, which is needed to effectively reduce poverty in all its dimensions in Pakistan. In this regard, it will be befitting to take as starting reference the Pakistan government's own Draft Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper, PRSP (2003a) so as to base the recommendations on the experience of existing programmes and initiatives in Pakistan. The PRSP specifies five main goals of policy in the years ahead: accelerating economic growth and maintaining macroeconomic stability, investing in human capital, augmenting targeted interventions, expanding social safety nets and improving governance. While the approach of the PRSP is well focused, there is a need to deepen the understanding that underpins some areas of reform identified by it.

A vitally critical area of intervention for which the PRSP has not laid out a comprehensive approach is rural poverty. Our study reinforces other findings that poverty in Pakistan is overwhelmingly rural. An effective strategy for rural development will have immense bearings on the incidence of poverty in Pakistan. The strategy for addressing rural poverty in Pakistan will require the implementation of mutually consistent, mutually reinforcing, multi-faceted packages of programmes and strategies. The most effective approach will entail a combination of certain critical elements. Lipton and Ravallion (1995) point out that the policies pursued by most LDCs have been biased against the rural sector in various ways. Three sources of bias can be identified.

(1) The direct effect of sector-specific pricing policies, appearing as a wedge between domestic producer prices and border prices for agricultural outputs.

(2) The direct effect of non-price, sector-specific, policies, such as public spending on roads, schools, services and research.

(3) The indirect effect on the farm sector of economy-wide distortions operating through exchange rate and external trade policies.

In most LDCs, there are prospects for reducing poverty by removing these biases. In addition, cross-sectoral spillover effects also strengthen the case for a pro-rural bias, with or without other distortions. Such spillover effects can arise in a number of ways, including migration across regions and trade. (3) Ravallion and Dart (1994) found strong evidence of a significant response of urban poverty measures to rural consumption growth in India. The reverse was not true; that is urban growth did not reduce rural poverty controlling for the rural mean. Their investigation clearly established the quantitative importance of fostering rural economic growth for poverty reduction in both rural and urban/India.

The World Bank (2002) proposes a coordinated strategy for addressing rural poverty in Pakistan. In regards to constraints on productivity in the farm sector, there is first a need to improve household access to assets, in particular land. Historically poor outcomes of land and tenancy reforms, examined in light of some new initiatives, hint at the importance of improving not only the distribution of land but also the complementary access to agrarian inputs and credits. Improving credit allocation generally requires moving away from supply driven mechanisms, and improving and broadening micro-credit practices. Programmes that promote investments in the non-farm sector should be further encouraged since diversification out of agriculture has been shown to mitigate rural vulnerability and poverty. Particularly in view of Pakistan's growing drought problem, we need programmes that improve access to rural infrastructure, focusing on improved efficiency of the irrigation system. Increased public investment is warranted here, but some successes to date stress the importance of local governance reforms, particularly in the form of more community participation in local land and resource management. All these measures have to be designed and implemented in a coordinated fashion, due to considerable interrelationships among the various constraints addressed.

The PRSP has very appropriately emphasised the importance of good governance in the context of fighting poverty in Pakistan. The lack of institutional capacity and strength in Pakistan to withstand the rigors of an effective poverty eradication programme has often been highlighted. World Bank (2000) stressed the imperative of "facilitating empowerment" and "enhancing security" to generate the dynamics for sustainable poverty reduction. "Empowerment" implies the enhancement of the poor's capacity to influence the state institutions that affect their lives. This can be made possible by strengthening the participation of the poor people in political processes and local decision-making. Hence, "empowerment" of the poor people is part of the broader agenda of sound governance and accountability of state institutions to their citizens. In "enhancing security" the issue once again is whether public interventions and institutions work well--and in the interests of poor people. So, access to information and participation are again vital to address the menace of vulnerability to risks (e.g., ill health and economic shocks) faced by the poor people. Infact, sound and inclusive governance is central to creating an enabling environment for eradicating poverty. Good governance demands well-functioning and accountable public and private institutions. It is a prerequisite to mobilise social capital for sustained action against poverty.

The PRSP recognises that poverty in Pakistan is highly conditioned by governance factors. Addressing the governance component of the poverty reduction strategy requires major transformation of governance structures and systems, as well as of political and organisational culture, especially at the local level. It is in this spirit, that Pakistan's new "Devolution Plan", finalised in August 2000, seeks to restructure the administrative setups at the district, tehsil and union levels. The plan envisages the creation of full-fledged district governments with legislative and financial powers, serving below federal and provincial levels.

To date major steps have been taken towards the implementation of the "Devolution Plan". The "Local Government Ordinance 2001" paved the way for nation-wide elections to local governments. Administrative structures at the district level now function under the Zila Nazim. (4) The District Coordination Officer (DCO) is responsible for coordinating the activities of eleven groups of offices each headed by an Executive District Officer (EDO). Municipal services have been reorganised under the Tehsil/Town Nazim. The Tehsil/Town Municipal Officer (TMO) and Tehsil/Town Officers function under the Tehsil/Town Nazims. At the union level, the union administration operates under the Union Nazim. The Tehsil/Town Municipal Administrations have been assigned the responsibility for planning and developing municipal services (local roads, water supply, street lighting, markets, urban amenities, etc.). The union administrations plan and execute small community development projects in addition to their major role of monitoring the services and facilities. Deconcentration of functions in the revenue and police hierarchies has taken place. Now coordination, revenue and magisterial functions are not concentrated in one post. Likewise police investigation has been separated from watch and ward.

Unfortunately, there have been myriad problems in the series of fundamental transformations to overcome the governance crisis and lay the foundation of a successful poverty reduction strategy in Pakistan. The main issue has been to overcome the opposition of vested interests determined to hold on to the old system characterised by institutional decay and breakdown. Apart from that, three key problem areas that have emerged in the implementation of decentralisation reform are related to the lack of funds, capacity and systems.

First and foremost, devolution is a costly business. It requires new offices, equipment and manpower. Fiscal decentralisation entails providing local governments with significant locally generated resources. The question of how to mobilise these resources remains unresolved. There has hardly been any devolution of taxes to the local levels or improvement in the collection/recovery mechanism of the local taxes. It must be realised that local resource mobilisation is an important activity for the sustainability of local governments. Without fiscal decentralisation, political decentralisation is meaningless. Adequate service delivery and poverty reduction can only be achieved through a combination of grassroots participation and grassroots spending.

Second, the full implementation of the district government system requires the political leadership, administrative personnel and other stakeholders to comprehend in entirety what their particular roles/responsibilities are and how best they can be performed. To date, they lack that understanding in wake of the massive scale of reforms introduced. There is a pressing need for capacity building across all three newly created tiers of government and across the political leadership and civil service divide. The PRSP has appreciated the requirement of civil service reform to adapt the public administration to the new reality of devolution to render them more responsive to citizen demands.

Third, in certain cases there is acute need for new systems to reflect and accommodate the altered political, fiscal and administrative realities. For instance, Provincial Finance Commissions (PFCs) have been constituted in each province to ensure equitable and transparent distribution of resources. The local governments are primarily dependent upon these fiscal transfers from provincial governments for meeting their expenditure requirements. These fiscal transfers have been far from reliable and predictable. The systems for direct fund transfers to local governments are not fully in place. Similarly, the "Local Government Ordinance 2001" separated the functions of accounting and audit. But special structures have not yet been created to implement these measures.

Overall, this paper has described some tools for statistical analysis to decompose observed changes in aggregate poverty in Pakistan, so as to assess their sectoral and distributional composition. The recommendations that derive from the empirical analysis in this paper are broadly consistent with the poverty reduction strategy outlined in the PRSP, though they also suggest a need for a strengthening of this strategy.

The Government of Pakistan has formulated a new Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (2003b) which includes a concrete and well-classified "Rural Development Strategy". Keeping in view the policy message of this study, it is sincerely hoped that the Rural Development Strategy incorporated in the new PRSP, will be adequately pursued and implemented in letter and spirit.

Comments

The paper highlights the need for careful empirical analysis as the basis for effective poverty reduction strategy formulation.

The paper presents the application of the Ravallion and Huppi (1991) decomposition methodology to data for the period 1987-88 to 1998-99, using urban and rural level of aggregation. It makes significant observations. It is quite encouraging to see that researchers and academics are making meaningful contributions to facilitate the policy-makers and to improve public policy paradigm further. However, there are a few comments.

It is important to note that disaggregating the analysis by agro-climatic zones and by provinces should have very different implications that are missing in the paper. For example, Sindh is much more urbanised than Balochistan. There is a possibility that it might have been covered else where in the dissertation.

Empirical Studies [for example Ravallion (1994) and Malik (1992)] show the enormous biases that affect poverty estimates comparison over time and place. The paper under review does not indicate how these biases have been controlled or treated in the estimates from 1987 to 1999 while deriving the conclusions.

The decomposition of the change in poverty measures is restricted to growth and equity component but the paper does not answer the apparent paradox of reasonably good agriculture growth rate and the rising rural poverty in Pakistan.

The empirical analysis reflected in the paper does not provide linkage, direct or specific, to the policy part of the paper, which presents a summary of the existing strategy measures.

It seems that some of the observations made regarding Government of Pakistan's Poverty Reduction Strategy in the Paper are possibly based on old version of PRSP. The Rural Development Strategy has been embedded into the full PRSP, released very recently, focusing on areas that have direct linkage with the rural poverty; such as agriculture, livestock, dairy, fisheries, irrigation, infrastructure for the poor including farm to market roads, rural electrification, works under Khushal Pakistan Programme and Tameer-e-Watan programme, micro-credit, etc. apart from generally covering the rural sector for human development and governance.

Likewise, governance section has been strengthened and appropriately expanded to reflect various concerns expressed in the paper, such as devolution, fiscal decentralisation, access to justice, police reforms, civil service reforms, capacity building, anti-corruption, public sector procurement reforms, freedom of information, statistics improvement, etc.

To conclude, the paper needs to have a fresh look on the methodology and conclusions to address some of the issues highlighted above and to establish a link between findings of empirical analysis with the policy part of the paper. The authors may wish to update their observations with reference to PRSP in the context of Full PRSP released very recently.

The PRSP Secretariat would welcome meaningful suggestions to address rural poverty including the non-farm sector.

Abdul Wajid Rana

PRSP Secretariat, Ministry of Finance, Islamabad.

REFERENCES

Ali, Salman Syed, and Sayyid Tahir (1999) Dynamics of Growth, Poverty and Inequality in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 38:4, 837-858.

Amjad, Rashid, and A. R. Kemal (1997) Macroeconomic Policies and their Impact on Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 36:1, 39-68.

Contreas, D. (2003) Poverty and Inequality in a Rapid Growth Economy: Chile 1990-96. The Journal of Development Studies 39:3, 181-200.

Datt, G. and M. Ravallion (1992) Growth and Redistribution Components of Changes in Poverty Measures: A Decomposition with Applications to Brazil and India in the 1980s. Journal of Development Economics 38, 275-295.

Kakwani, N. (1993) Poverty and Economic Growth with Application to Cote D'Ivoire. Review of Income and Wealth 39:2, 121-139.

Kakwani, N. (2000) On Measuring Growth and Inequality Components of Poverty with Application to Thailand. Journal of Quantitative Economics 16:1, 67-79.

Lipton, M., and M. Ravallion (1995) Poverty and Policy. In J. Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan (eds.). Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. III. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Pakistan Government of (1979) HIES: Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1979. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.

Pakistan, Government of (1987-88) HIES: Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1987-88. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.

Pakistan Government of (1993-94) HIES: Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1993-94. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.

Pakistan Government of (2003) Economic Survey 2002-03. Islamabad: Economic Advisor's Wing, Ministry of Finance.

Pakistan Government of (2003a) Draft PRSP. Islamabad: PRSP Secretariat, Ministry of Finance.

Pakistan Government of (2003b) Accelerating Economic Growth and Reducing Poverty: The Road Ahead. PRSP, Government of Pakistan. Islamabad: PRSP Secretariat, Ministry of Finance.

Population Census Organisation (1984) 1981 Census Report of Pakistan. Islamabad: Statistics Division. (Report No. 69.)

Population Census Organisation (2001) 1998 Census Report of Pakistan. Islamabad: Statistics Division. (Census Publication No. 160.)

Ravallion, M., and G. Datt (1994) How Important to India's Poor is the Urban-Rural Composition of Growth? Washington, D.C.: World Bank. (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1399.)

Ravallion, M., and M. Huppi (1991) Measuring Changes in Poverty: A Methodological Case Study of Indonesia during an Adjustment Period. The Worm Bank Economic Review 5:1, 57-82.

World Bank (2000) World Development Report: Attacking Poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.

World Bank (2002) Pakistan Poverty Assessment: Poverty in Pakistan--Vulnerabilities, Social Gaps and Rural Dynamics. Islamabad: The World Bank in Pakistan. (Report No. 24296-PAK.)

(1) Structural reforms included privatisation and loss of employment for redundant workers, cut in subsidies, and increase in sales tax.

(2) For further discussion on the interpretation of the residual, see Datt and Ravallion (1992).

(3) Cross-sectoral linkages through migration and trade can readily create multiplier effects, which enhance sector-specific policy impacts on the poor.

(4) The divisional level where there were administrative structures and no corresponding political dispensation has been abolished.

Aliya H. Khan and Ali Shan Azhar are respectively Associate Professor and MPhil student at the Department of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Table 1
Decomposition of Change in Poverty into Intrasectoral Effects,
Intersectoral Population Shifts, and their Interaction between 1979
and 1987-88, Pakistan (Percentaee of Total Povertv Reduction)

 Components of Poverty Alleviation

 Intrasectoral
 Effects Intersectoral
Poverty Population Interaction
 Measure Urban Rural Shifts Effect

Headcount 22.78 76.68 1.03 -0.51
 Index

Source: Authors' calculations based on Amjad and Kemal (1997) and
Census Report of Pakistan, 1981 and 1998.

Table 2
Decomposition of Change in Poverty into Intrasectoral Effects,
Intersectoral Population Shifts, and their Interaction between 1987-
88 and 1998-99, Pakistan (Percentage of Total Poverty Increase)

 Components of Poverty Alleviation

 Intrasectoral
 Effects Intersectoral
Poverty Population Interaction
 Measure Urban Rural Shifts Effect

Headcount 13.33 86.30 -0.28 -0.87
 Index

Source: Authors' calculations based on Amjad and Kemal (1997);
Economic Survey 2002-03 and Census Report of Pakistan, 1981 and 1998.

Table 3
Decomposition of Changes in Poverty into Growth and Redistribution
Components, Pakistan, 1979--1993-94
(Perrentape Points)

 Growth Redistribution Change in
Period Component Component Residual Poverty

 Householdcount Index

1979 to 87-88 -7.59 -1.10 -0.25 -8.94

1997-88 4.40 1.83 0.97 7.20
 to 93-94

Source: Authors' calculations based on HIES, 1979, 1987-88 and
1993-94 and Ali and Tahir (1999).

Table 4
Decomposition of Changes in Poverty into Consumption Growth and
Redistribution Effects, Pakistan, 1979-1987-88
(Percentage of Total Poverty Reduction)

 Higher Mean Change in
 Consumption Distribution
Poverty Measure (a) (b) Residual

Householdcount 84.9 12.3 2.8
 Index

Source. Authors' calculations based on HIES, 1979 and 1987-88 and Ali
and Tahir (1999).

Note: (a.) ([P.sup.*.sub.87] - [P.sub.79])/([P.sub.87] - [P.sub.79]).

(b.) ([P.sup.**.sub.87] - [P.sub.79])/([P.sub.87] - [P.sub.79]).

Table 5
Decomposition of Changes in Poverty into Consumption Growth and
Redistribution Effects, Pakistan, 1987-88-1993-94 (Percentage of Total
Poverty Increase)

 Lower Mean Change in
 Consumption Distribution
Poverty Measure (a) (b) Residual

Householdcount 61.11 25.42 13.47
 Index

Source: Authors' calculations based on HIES, 1987-88 and 1993-94 and
Ali and Tahir (1999).

Note: (a.) ([P.sup.*.sub.93] - [P.sub.87])/([P.sub.93] - [P.sub.87]).

b. ([P.sup.**.sub.93] - [P.sub.87])/([P.sub.93] - [P.sub.87]).
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有