Pro-poor growth and policies: the Asian experience.
Pasha, Hafiz A. ; Palanivel, T.
The objective of this paper is to assemble on a systematic basis
the available data on Asian countries and then analyse the relationship
between growth and poverty reduction in a long-term perspective, as well
as the impact of different macroeconomic variables on the intensity of
this relationship. The results indicate that there is not only a strong
positive relationship between growth and poverty reduction, but also
that this relationship is highly variable across countries and time
periods. The key macroeconomic determinants of the degree of pro-poor
growth appear to be the rates of employment and agricultural growth.
Inflation, at least up to a certain rate, does not impact poverty
negatively, while the role of exports is essentially indirect through
the contribution to the overall rate of economic growth. Examination of
the change in policy stance of the Asian countries during the 1990s in
relation to the 1980s demonstrates that on balance the mix of policies
has not been pro-poor. The apparent sacrifice of growth in pursuit of
macroeconomic stability has diminished the impact on poverty reduction.
Given the relatively weak trade-off between inflation and growth with
regard to the impact on poverty and the fact that inflation rates are
currently low in the region, it is argued that countries can be more
flexible in their policy stance with regard to the adoption of more
growth-oriented as opposed to stabilisation policies. In particular, a
case is made for resorting to a more expansionary counter-cyclical
fiscal policy, led by higher levels of public investment, supported by
appropriate monetary and exchange rate policies. The paper concludes
with a detailed description of the policies designed to achieve faster
agricultural development and greater employment generation.
1. INTRODUCTION
The relationship between economic growth and the change in the
incidence of poverty is both complex and multi-dimensional. An
understanding of this relationship and its underlying determinants is
the key to the formulation of successful poverty reduction strategies.
If it can be demonstrated that fast economic growth is always
accompanied by rapid poverty reduction, as a result of the
'trickledown' effect, then such strategies can focus, more or
less, exclusively on achieving faster growth. However, if this is not
necessarily the case, then the pursuit of growth will have to be
combined with an effort at achieving more pro-poor growth through a
degree of redistribution of assets and incomes in the economy. This
would have significant implications on the nature of anti-poverty
strategies.
A number of studies have attempted to analyse the relationship
between economic growth and poverty incidence across countries and time
periods [see Ravallion and Chen (1997); Bruno, Ravallion and Squire
(1998) and Adams (2003)]. It has been estimated that, on average, a one
percentage point increase in the rate of per capita income growth can
produce up to a two percent decrease in the proportion of people living
below the poverty line, subject, of course to the process of income
change being distribution-neutral in character. But inequality has
tended to change in most situations and some countries have experienced
limited poverty reduction despite impressive growth performance, while
others have managed to decrease poverty significantly despite relatively
low growth.
The experience of Asian countries with regard to poverty reduction
is mixed. Countries of East Asia have managed an exceptionally high
average growth rate of per capita income of 6.4 percent, in the 90s,
while the corresponding growth rate for the group of South Asian
countries is 3.2 percent. The incidence of poverty has declined sharply
in the former sub-region by 6.8 percent annually, whereas the rate of
decline in South Asia has been relatively modest at about 2.4 percent.
For the region as a whole, a one percentage point increase in the growth
rate of per capita income has translated into only a 0.9 percent decline
in the incidence of poverty. Clearly, inequality as a whole has worsened
in the region during the 90s, and while it has been successful in
achieving high rates of economic growth, gains with regard to poverty
reduction have been limited by the absence of pro-poor growth.
The Millennium Development Goals of the United Nations have
committed the world to reducing the incidence of poverty by half by 2015
(in relation to the base year level of 1990). This implies that poverty
will have to fall by about three percent per annum for the target to be
achieved. If progress during the 90s is any guide, East Asia has already
met this target; subject to no reversals in future years, but South Asia
is not expected to achieve the target of halving poverty by 2015 on the
basis of pat trends. It needs to be emphasised, however, that much of
the breakthrough of East Asia is due to the remarkable strides made by
China in poverty reduction. On the contrary, many countries of East Asia
have also fallen behind in terms of achieving the poverty reduction
target.
The decade of the 90s has also witnessed qualitative changes in the
growth process, which could have a vital bearing on the relationship
with poverty reduction. Some countries have just begun the transition
from a highly centrally planned to a market economy while others have
reached a fairly mature stage in this process. Many countries have
started or intensified the implementation of various structural economic
reforms, sometimes under the aegis of an IMF/World Bank structural
adjustment programme or poverty reduction and growth facility (PRGF),
which have included trade liberalisation, financial sector reform,
privatisation, deregulation and removal of restrictions on foreign
private investment. While these changes may have resulted in faster
economic growth it is not clear what the consequences have been on the
rate of poverty reduction. In some countries, like Pakistan, Philippines
and Sri Lanka, the process of poverty reduction has visibly slowed down.
In others, periods of political or economic crises (like the East Asian
financial crisis) have contributed to cases of rising poverty. (1)
The objective of this paper is to assemble on a systematic basis
the available data on Asian countries and then analyse the relationship
between growth and poverty on a long-term basis. Section 2 presents the
trends in growth, income inequality and poverty incidence for different
countries and different periods. These trends reveal the substantial
variation in the relationship between growth and poverty, which is then
explained on the basis of changes in the level of inequality. Section 3
studies the role of different potential macroeconomic determinants of
poverty in the Asian context on the basis of simple statistical
techniques. (2) Section 4 analyses the impact of different types of
policies on the proximate determinants of poverty and highlights how
different Asian countries have operated within the policy trade-offs
with respect to poverty. Finally, Section 5 provides some concluding
observations.
Figure 1 highlights in schematic fashion the methodological
approach adopted in the paper. According to this framework, various
policies impact on macroeconomic determinants of poverty, with inflation
likely to cause an increase in poverty, while income and employment
growth expected to mitigate against poverty. A successful policy is one
that operates on the right side of this trade off.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
2. GROWTH, INEQUALITY, AND POVERTY REDUCTION
Before we quantify the relationship between growth and poverty in
different settings, we proceed to describe the data. The sample consists
of nine countries from East Asia (Cambodia, China, Indonesia, Lao PDR,
Malaysia, Mongolia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam) and five from
South Asia (Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka). These
countries account for 97 percent of the population and 77 percent of the
gross national income of the whole of Asia. For all these countries data
is available for the 90s, in most cases for the 80s and in some cases
for the 70s. Changes are measured over the decades to remove the impact
of random factors and to identify the underlying long-term
relationships. Altogether, we are able to observe 32 'cases',
where a case relates to a particular country over a particular decade.
14 cases are for the 90s, 10 for the 80s and 8 for the 70s.
Poverty estimates, based on national poverty lines, are used in the
analysis. (For the justification behind using national poverty estimates
rather than those based on the international poverty line of US $ 1 PPP per capita per day, see Appendix I). These estimates are given in Table
A-1 in the Statistical Appendix. Annual rates of change in the incidence
of poverty are computed by decade and presented along with the rate of
per capita income growth in Table 1. It is interesting to note that out
of the 32 cases on which data is available, there are only nine cases in
which poverty increased. This testifies to the success of Asian
countries in reducing poverty, on average, during the last three
decades. It is significant to note, however, that most cases of
increasing poverty are concentrated in the 90s. This indicates greater
variability in performance of countries with regard to poverty reduction
during the last decade.
The strong relationship between growth and change in poverty is
demonstrated by the fact that the fastest growing country, China (in the
80's and 90s), has shown the highest rate of decline in poverty
while the slowest growing country, Mongolia (in the 90s), has
experienced the largest rate of increase in poverty. In between,
however, there appears to be much heterogeneity in the relationship, as
revealed by the scatter diagram in Figure 2. There are countries, on the
one hand, which despite showing only modest growth or even decline in
per capita income were able to bring down poverty in particular periods.
Examples of this are India (in the 70s) and Philippines (in the 80s and
90s). On the other hand, we observe cases where countries were unable to
reduce poverty despite achieving fairly high rates of growth in per
capita income. Thailand (in the 80s), Malaysia (in the 90s) and Sri
Lanka (in the 90s) are examples of such a failure. However, in the
latter two cases the rise in poverty could be attributed to prevailing
economic or political crises.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In order to focus on the underlying relationship between growth and
poverty and to remove the effect of individual country variations, we
categorise the cases into two types, on the basis of growth rate of per
capita income (above or below 3.5 percent). (3) 29 cases have been
included in the analysis. Three cases have been excluded because of
economic or political crisis during these periods. (4) The objective is
to focus on the long-term relationship between growth and poverty in a
'normal' development situation.
Results of this simple analysis are presented in Table 2. It
appears that in 13 cases of fast growth, the average rate of poverty
reduction per annum was 4.9 percent, whereas in cases of relatively slow
growth there was only a marginal decline in poverty of 0.4 percent.
Clearly, on the average, there is a well-defined relationship between
growth and poverty reduction. It appears on the basis of this
relationship that, on average, countries will have to achieve a growth
rate in per capita income of about 3.5 percent if the MDG target of
halving poverty in 25 years is to be attained.
Perhaps, the best way to capture the intensity of the relationship
between economic growth and poverty is to compute the growth elasticity
of poverty. This indicates the percentage change in the incidence of
poverty associated with a one percent increase in per capita income.
Estimates of this elasticity for the sample countries in different
decades are given in Table 3. This Table demonstrates a wide variation
in the elasticity estimates.
Three conclusions can be drawn from Table 3. First, the elasticity
is both positive and negative. Positive elasticities are generally
observed in cases where the growth of per capita income is low and
poverty has increased. Second, the elasticity tends to be more negative
in the case of countries, which experience faster growth. For example,
when China's growth rate soared in the 80s and 90s, the elasticity
became substantially more negative as compared to the 70s. Third, the
elasticity appears to be highly unstable in the case of individual
countries over time. In the case of Sri Lanka it has varied from -0.3 in
the 70s to -2.23 in the 80s.
It is generally recognised that the extent to which the growth
elasticity of poverty is negative is a good measure of the degree to
which the growth process has been pro-poor. The basic question that
arises then is: what determines the magnitude of this elasticity? Before
we proceed to analyse what characteristics of growth determine the
degree to which it is pro-poor, we explore the implications of changes
in the level of inequality; trends in which are shown in Table A-2.
Clearly, for a given growth rate, the implications for the level of
poverty are likely to be more favourable if there is simultaneously a
reduction in inequality such that the income of poor rises
disproportionately in relation to the increase in average income in the
economy. Alternatively, if the trickle down effect is weak and much of
the gains in income are pre-empted by relatively well-off households,
then the impact on poverty is likely to be limited.
Table 4 focuses on four types of cases. The first category consists
of cases in which a country experienced rapid growth, but simultaneously
witnessed a rise in income inequality. There are nine such cases, mostly
in East Asia, with the notable exception of India in the 90s. It appears
that in these cases the process of growth was robust enough to offset
any negative consequence on poverty of worsening inequality since the
average rate of decline in poverty was as high as 5.6 percent. This
exceeds, on average, the rate of poverty reduction achieved by countries
that experienced both fast growth and falling inequality primarily
because the growth rate was much higher. Of particular interest is what
happened at the other extreme--when not only was growth slow but there
was also a rise in inequality. Countries in this situation experienced
on average an increase in poverty of close to one percent per annum.
It is of significance to note that some countries have managed to
reduce poverty fairly rapidly even in periods of relatively slow growth
by ensuring that whatever gains ensue from this growth accrue relatively
more to the poorer segments of the population. This is observed in five
cases. For example, despite growth in per capita income of about three
percent, Malaysia and Sri-Lanka in the 80s were able to reduce poverty
annually by as much as four to seven percent due to falling inequality.
It is not surprising that high growth elasticities of poverty are
observed in these cases.
A striking example of success in poverty reduction, despite slow
growth (of less than two percent), is that of Pakistan during the decade
of 70s. The largest negative value of 2.77 is observed in this case
among the sample growth elasticities of poverty. This decade witnessed a
rapid increase in labour migration of workers to the Middle East leading
to a large and growing inflow of home remittances. At home, there was a
vigorous expansion of the public sector, workers were given more rights
and living standards of the poor were raised through enhanced budgetary
outlays for subsidies on basic consumer items. However, it has been
argued that the poverty reduction strategy adopted was fiscally
unsustainable.
3. MACROECONOMIC DETERMINANTS OF PRO-POOR GROWTH
In the Asian context, the previous section has demonstrated that,
although there exists a strong relationship between growth and poverty,
this relationship is highly variable in character. We proceed now to
examine the impact of different macroeconomic variables like the rate of
inflation, employment growth, sectoral pattern of growth, etc., on the
intensity of the relationship between growth and poverty. The approach
adopted is to control for the rate of growth, and then to see the impact
of variation in magnitude of a particular macroeconomic variable on the
level of poverty.
Inflation
It has been argued that inflation affects the poor directly through
a decline in their real wages owing to the short-run rigidity of nominal
wages. Also, if there are any savings, the poor mostly hold it in liquid
form. Inflation generally reduces the real value of such holdings. If
inflation is unanticipated, the poor will be harmed disproportionately
as they have weaker bargaining power and are generally unable to hedge
against inflation. On the contrary, since the poor are frequently
indebted, the real cost of their debt falls with inflation. If the
source of inflation is higher food prices, then this could have an
ambiguous impact on the level of poverty. On the one hand, farmers who
market their surplus food production, benefit, but on the other hand,
the landless in rural areas and the urban poor are impacted adversely.
Empirical findings on the effect of inflation on poverty, after
controlling for the rate of economic growth, are, in fact, mixed. Agenor
(2002) finds a statistically insignificant relationship between
inflation rate and change in poverty. Datt and Ravallion (2002), using
panel data on poverty from Indian states, show that inflation matters to
India's poor and attribute this effect primarily to adverse shocks
on the real wage of unskilled labour.
Table A-3 gives the rates of inflation in sample countries, while
Table 5 quantifies the average rate of change of poverty in different
types of cases. The first two types of cases relate to periods of fast
economic growth, with the first type also witnessing double-digit rates
of inflation and the second type having low rates (single digit) of
inflation. There are six cases of the first type and seven of the second
type. It is important to note that given this, more or less, equal
distribution, fast growth appears to be as likely during periods of high
inflation as low inflation. For example, China achieved a per capita
income growth of as high as eight percent in the 80s when the inflation
rate approached 12 percent. Similarly, during the 70s, the Indonesian
economy averaged a growth rate in per capita income of almost 5.5
percent in the presence of high inflation of almost 18 percent per
annum. Comparison of the average rates of decrease in the incidence of
poverty in the two types of cases reveals hardly any difference.
We turn next to the other two types of cases, both corresponding to
situations of slow economic growth. In seven cases, slow growth was
accompanied by low inflation while in nine cases there was high
inflation. Here again, we find that once the growth effect on poverty is
controlled for, inflation has only a minor effect on poverty. Overall,
the direct effect on the incidence of poverty of inflation does not
appear to be significant in the Asian context, within the range of rates
of inflation experienced.
The lack of sensitivity of poverty to inflation is one of the
potentially more important findings of the paper. It highlights that the
trade-off faced by policies, fiscal or monetary, between growth and
inflation from the viewpoint of impact of poverty is not as severe as
has traditionally been thought to be the case. It appears that to the
extent expansionary policies are resorted to with the objective of
stimulating the process of growth, then any resulting inflation is
likely to be less damaging on poverty. This clearly strengthens the case
for pursuing expansionary fiscal and monetary policies at a time when
space already exists, as inflation rates are currently low throughout
the region.
Employment Growth
Employment is one of the main channels through which the link
between economic growth and poverty reduction is established. As the
level of income is the key determinant of poverty and as productive
employment is the principal source of income, expanding gainful employment opportunities has to be a major element in the strategy of
poverty reduction. This might be called the 'employment nexus'
between growth and poverty. Unfortunately, the
growth--employment--poverty linkage has not been adequately recognised
in the pro-poor debate.
Clearly, employment growth depends upon the growth of the economy.
However, empirically a wide variation is observed in this relationship.
The rate of employment growth is also influenced by the sectoral
composition of economic growth, the choice of technology and the degree
of effective functioning of the labour market. If economic growth is
concentrated in sectors in which most of the poor work, then this is
likely to have a positive impact on poverty reduction. Also, if the
process of trade liberalisation leads to greater openness of the
economy, the net impact on employment opportunities depends on how far
employment is gained or lost in shifting resources from the non-tradable
to the tradable sectors.
Based on the data available, we test whether employment growth has
any impact on the change in poverty, independently of the effect of
economic growth on poverty. Table A-4 gives the rate of employment
growth in sample countries. As before, we distinguish four types of
cases depending upon the rate of growth of per capita income (fast or
slow) and the rate of employment growth (fast or slow). There is
substantial variation in the rate of employment growth. For example, the
growth rate of the Chinese economy was higher in the 90s in relation to
the 80s, but while employment grew at almost 5 percent in the latter
period, it increased by only 1 percent during the 90s, despite faster
growth. As opposed to this, in the presence of relatively slow growth,
Sri Lanka was able to achieve almost a 4 percent growth in employment
during the 80s.
Results of the analysis presented in Table 6 clearly demonstrate
the importance of employment growth in influencing the rate of change in
the incidence of poverty, after controlling for the effects of economic
growth on poverty. In the seven cases where both rapid economic and
employment growth was observed, the average rate of decline was close to
5.5 percent, whereas in the six cases where fast growth was accompanied
by relatively slow employment growth, the rate of fall in poverty was
4.2 percent. The importance of employment growth in contributing to
poverty reduction appears to be even more pronounced in situations where
the overall pace of economic growth is slow. We observe seven cases
where employment growth in excess of 2.5 percent per annum was achieved
despite a growth in per capita income of less than 3.5 percent. Poverty
declined on the average in these cases by 2 percent. As opposed to this,
in the nine cases of both slow economic and employment growth, poverty
increased on an average by almost 1 percent per annum. These results
confirm the view that employment growth is a key element in pro-poor
growth.
Agricultural Growth
There is a substantial body of literature that argues that it is
not only the overall growth that matters for poverty reduction, but that
the pattern of growth also matters [see Ravallion (2001); Datt and
Ravallion (2002)]. In particular, since bulk of the poverty is rural in
character, agricultural growth has a crucial role to play in the process
of poverty reduction, through both its direct effect within the rural
economy and through the spill over effects on the urban economy. Very
few countries in the world have experienced rapid and sustained growth
without agricultural growth either preceding or accompanying it. As
highlighted by the UNDP Global Human Development Report (1997), strong
agricultural growth has been a feature of countries that have
successfully reduced poverty at different times. We test, therefore, for
the direct effect of agricultural growth after controlling for the
overall rate of growth. The hypothesis is that for the same rate of
economic growth, the impact on poverty is likely to be more pronounced
the faster the rate of agricultural growth.
Table A-5 gives the rate of agricultural growth in sample
countries. It is interesting to note that in ten cases where rapid
agricultural growth occurred along with overall rapid economic growth,
poverty fell sharply in all these cases, by almost 6 percent per annum,
as shown in Table 7. As opposed to this, in the three cases where
agriculture lagged behind other sectors in achieving rapid growth, the
performance with respect to poverty reduction was more modest, at about
2 percent per annum. The evidence points to the fact that progress in
bringing down poverty was retarded (China in the 70s, India during the
80s and 90s and Thailand in the 90s) due to slow progress of agriculture
during these periods.
We also observe seven cases where although the overall growth
performance was relatively poor, agriculture performed strongly, showing
a growth rate in excess of 3 percent. On average, in these cases, the
rate of decline in poverty was 0.7 percent per annum. Of particular
significance is the fact that although the agricultural sector of
Pakistan has done exceptionally well during the last two decades, it has
not made a significant dent on rural poverty in the country, and thereby
on poverty overall. In a recent paper, Malik (2003) has argued that this
is due to a number of reasons, such as the high level of inequality, the
lack of non-farm employment opportunities and a decline in the real
wages of the rural poor as mechanisation has reduced labour demand. In
the nine cases of both slow economic and agricultural growth, poverty
incidence remained stagnant.
Export Growth
The relationship between trade liberalisation, as reflected by a
greater emphasis on seeking export markets, and poverty reduction and
inequality both within countries and at the global level, has been one
of the most prominent elements of the current debate on pro-poor growth.
This debate is reflected in a study published by the WTO Secretariat in
2000 on Trade, Income Disparity and Poverty. While there is generally a
consensus that expansion of exports can make to faster economic growth,
there is less clarity on the direct impact of exports on poverty, once
we control for the overall rate of growth.
In a comprehensive paper, Winters (2000) identifies several key
linkages between trade liberalisation and poverty. He highlights the
fact that trade tends to alter relative product and factor prices, so
its net effect on poverty reduction depends also on the signs of these
relative product and factor price changes. For example, if exports are
primarily of labour-intensive manufactures, then they could bid up the
relative wages of unskilled and semi-skilled labour, thereby
contributing to poverty alleviation. This appears to be the experience
of East Asia in earlier decades. However, during the 90s, trade
liberalisation seems to have led to the emergence of urban
'enclaves', with beneficiaries consisting primarily of those
directly involved in export activities and the limited auxiliary service
functions that developed around these activities. For example,
information technology exports from India and exports of garments from
countries such as Bangladesh and Cambodia have remained restricted to a
few urban centres. In the case of latter, exports have not contributed
much to value added because of high import content. The absence of
backward and forward linkages has meant that the employment generation
due to export expansion has not been significant.
Table A-6 gives the rate of export growth in sample countries. Here
again, we distinguish among four types of cases depending upon the rate
of economic growth (fast or slow) and rate of expansion of exports (fast
or slow). For fast growing countries, the rate of poverty reduction
appears to be mildly sensitive to export performance, as shown in Table
8. However, a counter-intuitive result is that among cases of slow
growth, greater buoyancy of exports can actually contribute to a lower
rate of reduction of poverty.
Nonetheless, our findings on the impact of export performance on
poverty are in line with some recent empirical studies. For example,
studies such as Agenor (2002); Ghura, et al. (2002); Epaulard (2003)
find that, once the effect of overall income has been taken into
account, trade openness has no significant direct influence on poverty
incidence or on the income of the poor or on the elasticity of the
poverty with respect to growth. Overall, it appears that export growth
does not have a significant direct impact on poverty. Its effect has to
be seen primarily via its bearing on the overall rate of economic
growth. Therefore, exports cannot be said to playa significant role in
influencing the extent to which the process of growth is pro-poor or
not.
Based on the above analysis, it appears that the key macroeconomic
determinants of the degree of pro-poor growth are employment growth and
agricultural growth. Inflation, at least up to a certain rate, does not
seem to matter in negatively impacting on poverty while the role of
exports is essentially indirect through its contribution to the overall
rate of economic growth. Altogether, a successful poverty reduction
strategy will need to focus on achieving a high and sustainable rate of
economic growth, with such growth possessing two key characteristics:
high rate of employment generation and rapid agricultural growth. (5)
These appear to be the key conclusions drawn from the Asian experience
vis-a-vis poverty reduction during the last three decades. (6)
4. PRO-POOR POLICIES
We turn now to the role of policies in influencing the magnitude of
macroeconomic determinants of growth and the extent to which it is
pro-poor. The empirical analysis in the previous section has
demonstrated that from the viewpoint of poverty reduction in Asia the
stance of policies can be oriented more towards faster economic growth
rather than lowering of inflation within the overall inflation-growth
trade-off. Apparently, poverty in the region is more sensitive to the
rise in real income than prices. This is an important finding and
indicates that in the stabilisation versus growth debate, the
'Washington Consensus' view is at one extreme and, by and
large, countries can be more flexible in their policy posture with
regard to the adoption of more growth oriented policies.
Examination of the change in policy stance of the Asian countries
during the 90s in relation to the 80s yields some important conclusions:
(i) The size of the fiscal deficit (as a percentage of the GDP) has
fallen in most of the sample countries, with the exceptions of Cambodia
and Lao PDR, as shown in Table A-7. However, the path to fiscal
adjustment has been achieved in different ways. Some countries such as
Bangladesh and Philippines have opted to use part of their revenue gains
to bring down their fiscal deficit and the remaining part to raise the
level of public expenditure. Nepal and Vietnam have managed significant
increases in the revenue to GDP ratio, but have combined this with a
containment of public expenditure to achieve significant lowering of the
fiscal deficit. There has been a visible slackening of resource
mobilisation effort in a number of countries including Indonesia,
Malaysia, Pakistan and Sri Lanka. These countries have been compelled to
make major cutbacks in public expenditure in order to contain the fiscal
deficit. In the case of Pakistan and Sri Lanka, capital expenditure as a
percentage of the GDP has fallen by almost half. It is likely that in
such cases fiscal policy has exerted a strong negative influence on the
process of growth.
(ii) Monetary policy has tended to be less expansionary in the
majority of the sample countries. In relation to the 80s, the rate of
expansion in money supply has been lower or, more or less, the same
during the 90s, with the exception of Malaysia, Pakistan and Sri Lanka,
as shown in Table A-8. Consequently, real interest rates have been high,
and have shown a tendency only in recent years to fall sharply. The
tightening of monetary policy throughout the region appears to have been
largely motivated by the objective of containing inflation and the need
to avoid any balance of payment difficulties. It is, therefore not
surprising that inflation rates have been lower in the majority of
sample countries in the 90s (see Table A-3). Two countries, Indonesia
and Pakistan, have experienced higher inflation, arising in the latter
case from the pressure exerted on the money supply by runaway government
borrowing in the first half of the decade. In the case of Indonesia,
inflation spiralled in the aftermath of the East Asian financial crisis,
as the GDP plummeted and the exchange rate depreciated significantly.
(iii) There has been much more action during the 90s in the area of
trade liberalisation and exchange rate policies. Import tariffs, on
average, at the end of the decade are one-sixth the level prevailing at
the beginning of the decade in Bangladesh, about one-half in India, and
one-third in Pakistan and Thailand, one-fifth in Philippines, and so on.
Simultaneously, most countries have operated a managed floating exchange
rate regime and allowed their currency to depreciate in real terms at a
faster rate than in the 80s with the exception of Bangladesh, China,
Philippines and Lao PDR, as shown in Table A-9. The objective clearly
was to stimulate exports and limit the size of any trade deficit. Most
countries did, in fact, experience an upsurge in exports. For example,
the growth rate of exports in countries such as India, Philippines and
Vietnam more than doubled. A relative stagnation of exports was observed
only in the case of Pakistan.
What are likely to have been the implications of these policy
choices on the level of poverty in the region? South Asia, as a whole,
grew somewhat less rapidly that it dial in the 80s. East Asia did show
faster growth, but due primarily to the exceptional growth performance
of China, while other countries like Indonesia and Thailand, which were
impacted by the East Asian financial crisis, experienced a significant
decline in growth. Part of the fall in growth rates is clearly due to a
resort to contractionary fiscal and monetary policies in pursuit of
stabilisation. Another key development was the change in sources of
growth, arising from the shift in emphasis from raising domestic demand
through fiscal and monetary stimuli towards tapping into foreign demand,
through exports, by adopting aggressive trade and exchange rate
policies.
On balance, the mix of policies does not appear to have been
pro-poor. The sacrifice of growth in pursuit of macroeconomic stability,
implied by a lower rate of inflation, has diminished the impact on
poverty. Export buoyancy has certainly contributed to faster growth,
thereby indirectly resulting in lowering poverty. However, as
demonstrated earlier, exports have not done much directly to alleviate
poverty. This is primarily due to the failure of exports to stimulate
faster growth of employment. Exports of manufactures from the region
grew rapidly in the 90s and this contributed to the fast growth of the
industrial sector; employment, however in this sector, failed to
respond. A classic example of such a failure is observed in the case of
Bangladesh. Exports from this country, mostly of manufactured goods like
garments, grew by almost 12 percent per annum in the 90s and the
industrial sector expanded at the rate of 7 percent, but industrial
employment fell by close to 4 percent.
Given that fiscal deficits have fallen in most countries and
interest rates have shown a strong tendency to decline recently, while
foreign exchange reserves have generally tended to go up in the region,
there is a strong case for providing a fiscal stimulus to achieve faster
growth. Such a stimulus is unlikely to ignite inflationary pressures at
a time when inflation rates are generally down to low single digit
levels, as shown in Table A-3. A modest enhancement in the inflation
rate is unlikely to have adverse consequences on poverty as demonstrated
in the previous section.
The fiscal stimulus should come in the form of a boast to public
investment, which has been curtailed in many countries during the 90s.
Such public investment should be used for human development and physical
infrastructure of direct benefit to the poor. The allegation that higher
public investment could 'crowd out' private investment is not
borne out by the facts. In many countries of the region buoyant private
investment has gone hand in hand with major increases in public
investment. The best examples of this complementary relationship are
seen in China and Vietnam. If anything, the evidence points to a
'crowding in' through the familiar multiplier effect and the
impact of higher profit expectations and cost reductions associated with
improved infrastructure. Countries that have limited the investment role
of the public sector such as, Cambodia, Indonesia, Nepal, and Pakistan
have experienced an inferior investment performance by the private
sector.
Therefore, the function of fiscal policy must be one of helping the
economy achieve its potential and sustain a higher growth rate via a
redistribution of income at the margin in order to increase the
elasticity of poverty reduction with respect to growth. Public
investment is the key to these goals since it increases capacity, and
can be designed to do so in a way that biases income gains to the poor.
It needs to be emphasised, however, that there are limits in
special circumstances to the use of expansionary fiscal policy,
involving deficit financing of higher public investment outlays. If the
government has a burden of large internal or external debt, then such a
policy may lead to an unsustainable fiscal position. It is sometimes
argued that this is the situation in Indonesia. However, when GDP growth
is significantly lower than the potential long-run growth rate, there is
definitely a case for using fiscal policy, at least temporarily as a
counter-cyclical measure. Another argument that has been put forward is
that the use of fiscal policy should be limited in the presence of
'governance' failure arising from corruption and problems in
implementation of public sector projects. In such situations,
improvements in governance have to go hand in hand with the conduct of a
more active fiscal policy. Thailand has discovered an ingenious way of
increasing aggregate demand in the 90s by adopting an ambitious
programme of fiscal decentralisation.
As far as monetary policy is concerned, it is necessary to maintain
a stance of this policy that sustains the recent fall in interest rates
in the region. As highlighted earlier, with inflation rates generally
down, there exists considerable space for resorting to an expansionary
monetary policy. Exchange rate policy should aim at preventing an
overvaluation of the currency, to avoid loss of competitiveness.
Currently, many countries in the region are showing symptoms of the
'Dutch disease', involving appreciation of the currency
resulting from a rapid build up of foreign exchange reserves.
We now discuss below how fiscal, monetary and other policies can
jointly be used to further the goals of faster agricultural development
and employment absorption, which have demonstrated to be key elements of
a pro-poor growth strategy.
Policies for Agricultural Development
Over the past few decades, Asian agriculture has demonstrated
remarkable resilience. The spectre of population growth outstripping
agriculture's ability to meet human needs has not materialised.
Food prices have secularly declined on a long-term basis in the region.
However, growth of agricultural output has slowed down both in East Asia
and South Asia during the 90s as compared to the 80s. East Asian
agriculture grew at close to five percent in the 80s, which has fallen
to about three percent in the 90s, whereas agriculture in South Asia
rose by 3.5 percent in the 80s and has come down to three percent in the
90s. This has fundamental implications for the rural poor, whose share
in the total number of poor ranges from 66 percent in Indonesia to 94
percent in Nepal.
China's remarkable success in poverty reduction during the
initial years after the systemic land reforms in 1979 was largely
because of a sharp improvement in agriculture's terms of trade and
an increase in public expenditure for the rural economy. Rural communes
were dismantled, land was parcelled to households on an essentially
egalitarian basis, farmers were encouraged to abandon the previous
'grain first' policy and to diversify production, and farm
prices rose substantially along with a large increase in chemical
fertiliser supplies. When China shifted gears in the late 80s to a
development strategy oriented towards exports with concentration of
economic activity in the coastal region, the process of growth became
noticeably less pro-poor. Similarly, when India experienced relatively
fast agricultural growth (mainly due to the green revolution) in the 70s
and in the first half of the 80s, poverty declined despite a relatively
low rate of economic growth. However, the slowdown in agricultural
growth in the 90s, despite high economic growth, has had an adverse
impact on poverty reduction. Further, the astonishing egalitarian and
poverty alleviating growth in Indonesia during the 70s and the 80s was
principally due to a diversion of a high proportion of public investment
towards the rural areas, and to reforms of the domestic trade and
marketing regime, which led to an improvement of the agricultural terms
of trade.
These examples reveal that if economic growth is to be favourable
to the poor, then it should have a pattern that directs resources to the
sectors in which the poor work (agriculture), areas in which they live
(relatively backward regions), factors of production which they possess
(unskilled labour) and outputs which they consume (such as food).
Policies for promoting faster agricultural development will have to
focus on the following:
(i) Diversification of agriculture into labour-intensive high-value
agricultural commodities such as horticulture and livestock for
increased profit incentives and employment opportunities. This may
require intervention by the state initially in the process of marketing
and in providing minimum support prices to help farmers manage the risks
of moving into new economic activities.
(ii) Strengthening of the backward and forward linkages between the
agricultural sector and the off-farm sector in the rural areas in order
to create a virtuous cycle of growth of incomes and employment. This is
what happened in the countryside of China during the 80s and largely
explains the phenomenal employment growth during this period.
Development of small and medium-scale rural enterprises for agri
processing and provision of agricultural inputs will require greater
outreach for extension of rural credit, both farm and off-farm, by
financial institutions, specialised or otherwise.
(iii) Higher priority in public sector allocations to rural
development. In fact, during the 90s, the share of government spending on agriculture has declined sharply throughout the region. For example,
it has fallen in Indonesia from over 16 percent in the mid-80s to only
four percent in recent years, from 11 percent to four percent in Sri
Lanka, from 19 percent to 11 percent in Nepal, and so on. This trend
will have to be reversed. Numerous studies have been undertaken to find
out what kind of public expenditure caters most to needs of the rural
poor. It appears that the greatest impact on agricultural productivity and poverty comes from investment in roads, irrigation, village
electrification, and from outlays on agricultural research and
development and extension.
(iv) Focus on redistribution of assets to the poor. This will also
include the possibility of progressive land reform in countries, like
Nepal, Philippines and Pakistan, where agricultural land is unevenly
distributed. In addition, rural micro-credit schemes, of the type in
Bangladesh, can endow the poor, especially women, with some basic
assets.
Policies for Employment Generation
The share of employment in agriculture is currently high in most
countries of the region. For example, at one extreme, in less developed
countries like Cambodia and Bangladesh, the share of employment in
agriculture is close to three-quarters. As opposed to this, the share of
employed in industry is relatively small (in the range of six to 20
percent) in most countries. The data on employment reveals that,
contrary to expectations, in some countries such as Bangladesh, India,
Mongolia and Pakistan, the industrial sector's share in employment
has declined during the 90s. A substantial increase in employment share
is observed only in the services sector of most countries.
However, as a consequence of slow growth of formal (organised)
sector jobs in the modern industrial sector and increasing labour supply
pressure in agriculture, there has been enormous pressure put on
informal sector activities. This has translated into falling labour
productivity and income levels in the services sector. Therefore, it is
not surprising that one- half of the poor consist of employed workers
due to part-time work, low wages and frequently hazardous working
conditions. Mega cities of Asia have witnessed an explosion of the
informal sector and 'urbanisation' of poverty is an ongoing
phenomena.
Policy-makers have generally had an ambivalent attitude towards the
informal sector, recognising, on the one hand, the problems that it
poses in terms of tax evasion, illicit activities, adverse impact on the
environment, etc., and, on the other hand, accepting that it acts as a
cushion for the poor in terms of at least providing some minimum
livelihood. While regulation will need to be improved to avoid some of
the evils, it is clear that the informal sector will also have to be
supported through provision of better physical infrastructure and other
government facilities. Simultaneously, the progressive and dynamic end
of the informal sector consisting of small and medium enterprises
(SMEs), frequently engaged in export, will need to be encouraged by
improved access to management and technical extension services and to
credit from the banking system.
China provides an excellent example of how a development strategy
focusing on SMEs can play an important role in growth and employment.
The experience of Bangladesh is also illustrative in this regard. In the
90s, Bangladesh was able to accelerate the rate of poverty reduction
mainly by employment generation in nontradable sectors (i.e.
construction small-scale industry, services etc.).
Within rural areas, much of the focus on employment generation will
have to be on the off-farm sector, as discussed above. Several
countries--notably Bangladesh and India--have used rural public works programmes as an effective method of providing employment to poor
workers, especially on a seasonal basis.
Beyond this, the overall policy environment will have to be one
that promotes a higher labour intensity of growth. This will include the
development of a system of incentives and institutions that avoids
undesirably high capital intensity of investment (e.g. maintenance of an
overvalued exchange rate that permits the import of cheap machinery, the
promotion of large mechanised corporate farms instead of small holders,
making intensive use of family labour).
Reducing vulnerability due to labour market conditions could also
be useful in the context of reducing poverty among the working poor.
Legal and institutional reforms will be needed to address the various
factors contributing to vulnerability. A recent ILO study provides
strong support to the idea that minimum wage would bring positive
results in poverty alleviation. The study shows that the minimum wage
has a small disemployment effect, while providing unskilled workers with
decent living conditions [Saget (2001)]. Similarly, social protection
can help workers adapt to both cyclical and structural change. In many
developing countries, social protection systems tend to cover only
workers in formal full-time employment, leaving most of the workers with
no protection. Hence, new mechanisms to extend coverage of social
security need to be explored.
5. CONCLUSIONS
The Asian experience reveals a strong, though variable,
relationship between growth and poverty. For the region as a whole, the
growth elasticity of poverty is estimated at -0.9 during the 90s as
compared to a distribution-neutral elasticity of -2. The divergence is
attributed to worsening inequality. It appears that while the region has
been successful in achieving high rates of economic growth, gains with
regard to poverty reduction have been limited by the absence of pro-poor
growth.
Analysis of the macroeconomic determinants of pro-poor growth like
the rate of inflation, employment growth and sectoral pattern of growth
leads to some important, perhaps unexpected, findings. Once the effect
of growth on poverty is controlled for, the level of poverty does not
appear to be sensitive to the rate of inflation, at least up to the
level experienced by most Asian countries. Similarly, while greater
exports indirectly impact upon poverty via faster growth, the direct
relationship with poverty seems to be limited. The empirical evidence
indicates that the key macroeconomic determinants of the degree of
pro-poor growth are the rates of agricultural growth and employment
generation.
Based on these findings, the paper recommends a set of pro-poor
policies. Given the relatively weak trade-off between inflation and
growth with regard to the impact on poverty and the fact that inflation
rates are currently low, it is argued that countries can be more
flexible in their policy stance with regard to the adoption of more
growth-oriented as opposed to stabilisation policies. In particular, a
case is made for resort to a more expansionary counter-cyclical fiscal
policy, led by higher levels of public investment, supported by
appropriate monetary and exchange rate policies. The paper concludes
with a detailed description of the policies designed to achieve faster
agricultural development and greater employment generation.
Comments
1.
I am excited to be a discussant on this important paper. I am
excited because the subject is close to my heart.
In the absence of a written paper to review, however, it is very
difficult to offer meaningful comments, especially when a super-smart
speaker like Dr Hafiz Pasha makes the presentation. Under the
circumstances I shall be very brief in my remarks.
The core message coming out of the presentation is that inflation
does not matter in the menu of pro-poor policies followed by the Asian
countries. This is what a multi-equation econometric models tell the
authors of the paper entitled, "Pro-poor Policies: The Asian
Experience". If the conclusions emerging from sophisticated
econometric models do not jibe with economic common sense then they
should be taken with a pinch of salt. To say that there is no
relationship between inflation and growth is perhaps far fetched.
General experience and economic common sense tell us that inflation
has both direct and indirect effects on the poor in more than one ways.
Let me explain my position on this point.
First of all, most of the poor are unemployed of severely
under-employed. They do not have enough to eat in the first place. If on
the top of it prices are rising, especially that of the foodstuff and
other essential commodities, then the burden on the poor rises
disproportionately. Also we know both from economic theory and actual
experience, that a high level of inflation distorts savers as well as
investor's behaviour pattern. If inflation is high and rates on
saving instruments are low, the negative interest rates will discourage
savings. At the same time investors would go for speculative profits or
investments in real estate rather than long term investments in
production process in manufacturing activities. If the revenue
elasticity is not high enough to match with nominal rate of GDP growth,
the deficit financing ensues which may further accentuate inflationary
pressures depending on the sources of deficit financing. More
importantly, expectations of a rising trend in prices may itself worsen inflationary pressure. Therefore, in light of all theses common sense
observation my feeling is that inflation does matter even though in
econometric may tell us otherwise. It quite possible that in some
countries inflation in a certain range may not show an impact on growth,
but hyperinflation, as in Indonesia in 1960, and/or zero inflation
signalling recessionary conditions, does matter both for growth
prospects and job opportunity for the poor.
In my judgment not only inflation matters but also certain
non-economic factors matter even more for the poor in order to beat the
poverty trap. Most critical in this category are; (i) the sustainability
of the right kind of macro-economic, and sectoral policies, (ii)
political stability for a duration of time, (iii) human resource
development on a wide scale, (iv) security of life and property, and (v)
the rule of law in general. If these factors are focused upon and the
pattern of growth throw up ample opportunities for the employment of the
poor who already have been endowed with skill and some assets, then the
poor may benefit from the growth process, otherwise they will be by
passed and the poverty will deepen.
Fateh M. Chaudhry
Islamabad.
2.
It is indeed a great honour to be a discussant on the paper
presented by Dr Hafiz Pasha. The paper deals with a topic of great
importance to the developing countries, particularly in Asia and Africa.
The analysis is sound and robust. The authors have made an
ambitious effort to capture the diverse experience of 14 countries in
Asia over the past three decades. Findings are interesting and highly
valuable. Most of the conclusions are plausible and in harmony with the
findings of other researchers. The recommendations, based on the
analysis, are equally solid and appealing.
The paper has re-validated the findings of earlier researches that
showed a strong association between economic growth and poverty. It has
rightly underlined the importance of achieving and sustaining a high
rate of economic growth in lowering the incidence of poverty.
The paper has revealed that, despite a great divergence in the
systems of governance and resource ownership, there are many
similarities in the policies and programmes adopted for promotion of
growth in various countries. The degree of reduction in poverty in
response to economic growth was, however, different depending on the
composition of growth. A rapid drop in poverty was experienced when high
growth rates were achieved and sustained over time in agriculture and
off-farm rural sectors. The gain in poverty reduction was even higher,
where the growth in these two sectors was accompanied by measures that
reduced income inequalities, improved access to assets/landownership by
the poor. Continuity of policies, national capacity to implement and
adequacy of infrastructure, both institutional and physical, have had a
significant influence on growth and its impact on poverty.
The analysis rightly shows that the reduction in poverty comes
through employment generation which, in turn, is influenced by the
choice of technology and degree of effective functioning of the labour
market. It also shows that economic growth is pro-poor, when achieved by
encouraging investment in sectors and areas where the poor work and live
and that greatest impact on agricultural productivity and poverty comes
from investment in agricultural research and extension, roads,
irrigation, village electrification and agro-based industries.
The findings about the lack of sensitivity of poverty to inflation
and exports are apparently less plausible. Further work should be done,
using data from countries and regions that experienced very high rates
of inflation and where exports largely comprise primary commodities and
the products of labour-intensive industries.
Recommendations on the use of fiscal, monetary and trade policies
in support of accelerated economic growth are sound. However, their
impact on inflation should be closely monitored since it affects the
real wages of the poor. The recommendation on enhanced public sector
investment in the expansion of physical and institutional infrastructure
is equally sound. Redistribution of assets through measures such as land
reforms is highly desirable and rightly emphasised in the paper.
However, halfhearted and poorly implemented reforms, without adequate
improvements in the related areas, could easily be counter-productive.
Pakistan's experience in this area is quite revealing. Our country
failed to achieve either the intended impact on redistribution of assets
and/or an improvement in productivity.
The reliability and comparability of data across countries and over
time poses serious limitations on the study, since most of the countries
have been under different systems. Some countries are still in a
transition phase. Totalitarian and autocratic regimes generally have the
tendency of manipulating data to claim better results in terms of
economic growth and poverty reduction. These and other similar reasons,
depreciate the value of some of the conclusions drawn by the authors.
Pakistan's experience of achieving a rapid decline in poverty
despite low economic growth in the 70s quoted in the paper lacks
credibility. Moreover, the long term impact of some of the irresponsible
socialist policies adopted in the 70s was disastrous for the national
economy. Such policies can hardly be recommended for replication at home
or elsewhere.
The paper has focused only at the income dimension of poverty.
Equally important aspects like education, health and access to other
basic social services have been ignored South Asia's record, with
the exception of Sri Lanka, in addressing these aspects of poverty, has
been quite dismal.
The paper has also failed to analyse the impact of fertility
reduction on poverty. In East Asia and Sri Lanka, a rapid drop in
fertility concurrently with sustained economic growth, made an important
contribution to poverty reduction and an overall improvement in the
quality of life. The countries experiencing either a slow decline or
even a rise in poverty, have failed to achieve the desired level of drop
in fertility. Rapid population growth in these countries is continuing
to exacerbate the problems of unemployment, poor quality of life and
environmental degradation.
Since only aggregated data were used in the analysis, the paper
could not capture the wide regional and gender disparities that still
exist even in countries that have been experiencing rapid economic
growth.
On the whole, the authors have made a valuable contribution to the
literature on economic growth and poverty, clearly identifying the
conditions that make the macro policies more pro-poor. I hope my
comments will be considered by the authors while pursuing further
research on this or related themes.
Dilawar Ali Khan
Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
APPENDIX I
There is need for a discussion of the particular measure used to
quantify the incidence of poverty. Most studies have used data on
poverty incidence based on the poverty line of income of US $ 1 (in
purchasing power parity terms) per capita per day. Alternatively, some
studies have looked at changes in income share in the bottom quantile of
the income distribution as a proxy for changes in poverty [for example,
Roemer and Gragerty (1997); Dollar and Kraay (2001) and Ghura, Leite and
Tsangarides (2002)]. Both approaches have been subjected to various
forms of criticism. The former approach has been criticised by a number
of authors [Bhalla (2002) and Reddy and Pogge (2002)] on the grounds
that the relative purchasing power per dollar of the people of poor
nations is not measured accurately. The estimate of the purchasing power
of the poor is based on the measure of their ability to buy any of the
goods and services an economy has to offer. However, the poor do not
generally use services (and services in low income countries are much
cheaper in relative terms to other goods in the basket in terms of a
dollar's purchasing power across countries). Nonetheless, services
do get included in their basket of goods, thus reflecting an inflated
purchasing power of the poor.
As opposed to this, the latter approach has been found to have the
problem that the income of the bottom 20 percent of the income
distribution cannot be assumed to fully represent the income of the
poor. In many developing countries, 30 to 50 percent of the population
lives below the poverty line.
We have relied on estimates of the incidence of poverty based on
national poverty lines. These estimates are being used perhaps for the
first time to analyse the relationship between growth and poverty. Given
that these estimates are indigenous in character and are mostly produced
by national statistical organisations, they are likely to be more
acceptable to national governments. But the basic problem with these
estimates is their comparability across countries. Since the national
poverty lines are generally derived as the consumption expenditure
required to finance a minimum nutritional intake (in calories) by an
individual, there is a lack of standardisation as reflected by the
choice of different minimum nutritional level in different countries.
However, if the analysis is not with respect to the levels of poverty
but with regard to changes in the incidence of poverty then the problem
is likely to be less serious.
Our primary motivation for choosing poverty estimates based on
national rather that international poverty line (of US$ 1 PPP per capita
per day) is that the direction of change highlighted by the two
approaches tends to be different for a number of countries, especially
during the decade of the 90s. As can be seen from Table B-l, out of 14
countries in the sample for the 90s there is divergence in trends
revealed by the two approaches for five countries, namely, Bangladesh,
Cambodia, Indonesia, Malaysia and Pakistan. Differences are particularly
pronounced in the case of the last three countries. Indonesia and
Malaysia went through an economic crisis after 1997 and the former, in
particular, experienced a severe contraction in its GDP. Poverty
estimates in the immediate aftermath of the Asian financial crisis
revealed that the incidence had increased sharply. While there has been
some economic recovery since then, it is hardly likely that poverty
could have fallen as sharply as indicated by estimates based on the
international poverty line. Similarly, Pakistan has experienced low
growth during the decade of the 90s and the common perception is that
poverty has increased significantly during this period. Today, the
government of Pakistan is placing a high emphasis on reducing poverty
and unemployment. According to estimates based on the poverty line of US
$ 1 PPP per capita per day, the incidence of poverty in Pakistan has
fallen from as much as 48 percent in 1990 to 31 percent in 1996. This
seems very unlikely.
Table A-1
Incidence of Poverty in Different Countries in Different Years,
according to National Poverty Line (% of Population)
Country 1970 1980 1990 2000
Bangladesh 71.0 (73) 52.3 (83) 49.7 (91) 39.8
Cambodia -- -- 39.0 (94) 51.1 (99)
China 33.0 31.0 (78) 9.0 3.2
India 55.6 48.4 (78) 38.9 (88) 28.6 (99)
Indonesia 60.0 26.5 (81) 15.1 18.2 (99)
Lao PDR -- -- 53.0 31.5
Malaysia 18.0 9.0 6.1 (89) 8.1 (99)
Mongolia -- -- 17.0 (92) 35.6 (98)
Nepal -- 36.2 (77) 40.0 (89) 42.0 (96)
Pakistan 46.5 30.7 (79) 26.1 (91) 32.6 (99)
Philippines 61.6 (71) 59.7 (85) 45.2 (91) 40.0
Sri Lanka 37.0 (63) 30.9 (85) 19.9 (91) 25.2 (96)
Thailand 26.0 17.0 18.0 14.2
Vietnam -- -- 75.0 (88) 32.0 (02)
Source: UNDP (2003b); ESCAP (2002); ESCAP and UNDP (2003)
and World Bank (2004).
Note: Figure in the parenthesis corresponds to the year
of poverty level.
Table A-2
Level of Inequality in Sample Countries in Different Years
(Gini Coefficient %)
Countries 1970 1980 1990 2000
Bangladesh 36.8 (73) 39.0 (81) 28.9 (89) 31.8
Cambodia -- -- 37.4 40.4 (97)
China 27.9 32.0 34.6 40.3 (98)
India 30.4 31.5 (83) 29.7 37.8 (97)
Indonesia 30.7 31.8 33.1 30.3
Lao PDR -- -- 30.4 (92) 37.0 (97)
Malaysia 51.8 51.0 (79) 48.3 (89) 49.2 (97)
Mongolia -- -- 37.4 44.0 (98)
Nepal -- 30.1 (84) 33.4 (89) 36.7 (96)
Pakistan 33.0 37.3 (79) 40.7 33.0 (98)
Philippines 48.3 (71) 46.1 (85) 47.7 46.1
Sri Lanka 31.2 42.0 30.1 34.4 (96)
Thailand 49.9 (71) 47.3 (81) 42.9 43.2
Vietnam -- -- 35.7 (92) 36.1 (98)
Source: UNDP (2003a); UNDP (2003b) and World Bank (2003).
Note: Figure in the parenthesis corresponds to the year
of inequality level.
Table A-3
Rate of Inflation in Sample Countries in Different Decades (%)
Country 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000-2002
Bangladesh -- 7.4 5.2 2.5
Cambodia -- -- 5.4 -0.7
China 10.0 11.8 7.5 0.3
India 8.2 8.9 9.1 3.8
Indonesia 17.5 8.6 14.1 7.6
Lao PDR -- -- 34.1 16.4
Malaysia 6.0 3.2 3.6 1.5
Mongolia -- -- 65.6 9.8
Nepal -- 10.2 8.9 2.1
Pakistan 12.4 7.0 9.2 3.8
Philippines 14.9 13.7 8.6 5.2
Sri Lanka 8.9 12.4 9.7 10.2
Thailand 10.0 4.4 4.5 1.6
Vietnam -- -- 3.7 -1.1
Sources: World Bank (2003) and Asian Development Bank (2003).
Table A-4
Rate of Employment Growth in Sample Countries in Different Decades (%)
Country 1970s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh -- 2.3 1.4
Cambodia -- -- 2.8
China 2.2 4.7 1.1
India 2.1 2.2 2.4
Indonesia 2.5 3.0 1.8
Lao PDR -- -- 2.9
Malaysia 3.2 3.4 3.2
Mongolia -- -- 0.6
Nepal -- 1.8 3.1
Pakistan 3.1 2.0 2.1
Philippines 2.9 2.9 2.1
Sri Lanka 2.1 3.6 2.2
Thailand 3.1 3.1 0.4
Vietnam -- -- 2.9
Sources: ILO (2003) and various ILO employment reports.
Table A-5
Rate of Agricultural Growth in Sample Countries in Different Decades
Country 1970s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh -- 2.3 1.4
Cambodia -- -- 2.8
China 2.2 4.7 1.1
India 2.1 2.2 2.4
Indonesia 2.5 3.0 1.8
Lao PDR -- -- 2.9
Malaysia 3.2 3.4 3.2
Mongolia -- -- 0.6
Nepal -- 1.8 3.1
Pakistan 3.1 2.0 2.1
Philippines 2.9 2.9 2.1
Sri Lanka 2.1 3.6 2.2
Thailand 3.1 3.1 0.4
Vietnam -- -- 2.9
Sources: World Bank (2003).
Table A-6
Rate of Export Growth in Sample Countries in Different Decades (%)
Country 1970s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh -- 10.4 11.7
Cambodia -- -- 22.7
China 6.9 12.1 17.5
India 6.4 6.0 13.6
Indonesia 9.5 1.4 7.7
Lao PDR -- -- 15.7
Malaysia 8.1 10.7 12.5
Mongolia -- -- 8.8
Nepal -- 11.5 12.7
Pakistan 2.6 8.8 5.2
Philippines 10.3 4.0 8.1
Sri Lanka 1.8 6.7 --
Thailand 9.9 14.1 10.8
Vietnam -- -- 27.4
Sources: World Bank (2003).
Table A-7
Revenues, Expenditure and Fiscal Deficit in Sample Countries
in Different Decades (%)
Revenue Expenditure Fiscal Deficit
Country 1980s 1990s 1980s 1990s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh 6.4 9.1 11.4 13.1 -4.9 -4.0
Cambodia 4.9 7.5 7.2 12.6 -2.3 -5.1
China 19.3 12.7 21.9 14.6 -2.7 -1.8
India 12.7 10.2 19.0 16.5 -6.3 -6.3
Indonesia 17.1 16.7 19.5 17.4 -2.5 -0.7
Lao PDR 5.3 40.4 12.0 70.3 -6.7 -29.9
Malaysia 24.9 22.8 30.5 23.5 -5.6 -0.8
Mongolia -- 27.5 -- 32.4 -- -5.0
Nepal 9.4 11.0 19.6 19.2 -10.2 -8.2
Pakistan 20.4 19.0 29.1 26.6 -8.7 -7.6
Philippines 14.2 17.4 16.8 19.1 -2.6 -1.7
Sri Lanka 21.5 18.3 32.0 28.3 -10.5 -10.0
Thailand 16.5 17.0 16.0 16.9 0.5 0.0
Vietnam 13.7 18.2 21.9 21.6 -8.1 -3.4
Sources: Asian Development Bank (2003).
Table A-8
Growth in Money Supply and Real Interest Rates in Sample
Countries in Different Decades (%)
Country Money Supply Growth Real Interest Rate
1980s 1990s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh 20 13 4.7 10.2
Cambodia -- 28 -- 9.7
China 24 25 2.5 2.5
India 17 17 7.4 6.6
Indonesia 27 25 11.9 7.3
Lao PDR 115 51 -- 1.2
Malaysia 11 17 7.1 4.5
Mongolia -- 53 -- 45.9
Nepal 20 19 4.3 5.6
Pakistan 13 16 4.8 5.4
Philippines 21 19 5.4 6.4
Sri Lanka 16 18 1.3 7.8
Thailand 20 13 9.6 8.0
Vietnam -- 31 -- 8.2
Sources: World Bank (2003).
Table A-9
Rate of Real Depreciation in Exchange Rate and Average
Import Tariffs in Sample Countries (%)
Rate of Exchange
Rate Depreciation * Average Import Tariff
Country 1980s 1990s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh 1.2 -1.0 88.2 21.0
Cambodia -- 13.6 -- --
China 0.8 -1.0 32.5 14.3
India -0.5 1.1 56.2 28.2
Indonesia 3.3 13.7 13.2 5.4
Lao PDR 10.1 1.2 -- 14.2
Malaysia -1.0 0.6 9.9 5.8
Mongolia -- -47.5 -- --
Nepal -0.7 0.6 17.5 16.8
Pakistan 1.3 0.3 46.3 14.7
Philippines -0.4 -1.7 22.4 4.0
Sri Lanka -3.0 -2.9 26.9 7.2
Thailand -2.1 0.7 33.0 9.7
Vietnam -- 5.4 18.4 15.1
Sources: World Bank (2003).
* A positive rate indicates depreciation in the value of the currency.
Table B-1
Direction of Change in Incidence of Poverty according
to Different Measures
1980s
According to According to
International the National
Country Poverty Line Poverty Line
Bangladesh Increase Decrease
Cambodia -- --
China Decrease Decrease
India Decrease Decrease
Indonesia Decrease Decrease
Lao PDR -- --
Malaysia Decrease Decrease
Mongolia -- --
Nepal Decrease Increase
Pakistan Decrease Decrease
Philippines Decrease Decrease
Sri Lanka Decrease Decrease
Thailand Decrease Increase
Vietnam -- --
1990s
According to According to the
International National Poverty
Country Poverty Line Line
Bangladesh Increase Decrease
Cambodia Decrease Increase
China Decrease Decrease
India Decrease Decrease
Indonesia Decrease Increase
Lao PDR Decrease Decrease
Malaysia Decrease Increase
Mongolia -- Increase
Nepal -- Increase
Pakistan Decrease Increase
Philippines Decrease Decrease
Sri Lanka Increase Increase
Thailand Decrease Decrease
Vietnam Decrease Decrease
Source: World Bank, 2003, various tables from Pasha
and Palanivel, 2003.
REFERENCES
Adams, R. H. (2003) Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty:
Findings from a New Data Set. World Bank, Washington, D.C. (World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper No. 972.)
Agenor, P. R. (2002) Macroeconomic Adjustment and the Poor:
Analytical Issues and Cross-Country Evidence. World Bank, Washington,
D.C. (World Bank Policy Research Paper, No. 2788.)
Asian Development Bank (ADB) (2003) Key Indicators of Developing
Asian and Pacific Countries 2003. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Bhalla, S. (2002) Imagine There's No Country--Poverty,
Inequality and Growth in the Era of Globalisation. Washington, D. C.:
Institute for International Economics.
Bruno, M., M. Ravallion, and L. Squire (1998) Equity and Growth in
Developing Countries: Old and New Perspectives on the Policy Issues. In
Vito Tanzi and Keyoung Chu (eds.) Income Distribution and High-Quality
Growth. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT.
Datt, G., and M. Ravallion (2002) Why Has Economic Growth Been More
Pro-poor in Some States of India Than Others? Journal of Development
Economics 68, 381-400.
Dollar, D., and A. Kraay (2001) Growth is Good for the Poor.
Washington, D.C. (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2587.)
Easterly, W., and S. Fischer (2001) Inflation and the Poor. Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking 33, 160-79.
Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP)
(2002) Economic and Social Survey of Asia and the Pacific 2002. New
York: United Nations.
Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP),
and UNDP (2003) Promoting Millennium Development Goals in Asia and the
Pacific-Meeting the Challenges of Poverty Reduction. New York: United
Nations.
Epaulard, A. (2003) Macroeconomic Performance and Poverty
Reduction. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C. (IMF Working
Paper, WP/03/72.)
Ghura, D., C. Leite, and C. Tsangarides (2002) Is Growth Enough?
Macroeconomic Policy and Poverty Reduction. International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D.C. (Working Paper 02/118.)
International Labour Office (ILO) (2003) Global Employment Trends.
Geneva.
International Labour Office (Various Reports) Employment Report or
Annual Labour Statistics. Geneva.
Malik, J. Sohail (2003) Agricultural Growth and Rural Poverty in
Pakistan: A Review of the Evidence. Asian Development Bank.
Pasha, H. A., and T. Palanivel (2003) Macroeconomics of Poverty
Reduction: An Analysis of the Experience in 11 Asian Countries. UNDP
Asia-Pacific Regional Programme on Macroeconomics of Poverty Reduction.
(Discussion Paper No. 3.
Ravallion, M. (2001) Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond
Averages. World Development 29:11, 1803-15.
Ravallion, M., and S. Chen (1997) What Can New Survey Data Tell Us
about Recent Changes in Distribution and Poverty? World Bank Economic
Review 11:2, 357-82.
Reddy, S. G., and T. W. Pogge (2002) How Not to Count the Poor.
(Version 3.0). Barnard College, New York. (Mimeographed.)
Roemer, M., and M. Gugerty (1997) Does Economic Growth Reduces
Poverty? Cambridge, Massachusetts. (CAER Discussion Paper No. 4.)
Saget, C. (2001) Is Minimum Wage an Effective Tool to Promote
Decent Work and Reduce Poverty? The Experience of Selected Developing
Countries. ILO, Geneva. (Employment Paper, 2001/3.)
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (1997) Human
Development Report 1997. New York: Oxford University Press.
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (2003) Macroeconomics
of Poverty Reduction: Country Case studies in Bangladesh, Cambodia,
China, Indonesia, Mongolia, Nepal, Sri Lanka, and Vietnam. UNDP Regional
Programme on the Macroeconomics of Poverty Reduction. (Mimeographed.)
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (2003a) Human
Development Report 2003. New York: Oxford University Press.
Winters, A. L. (2000) Trade and Poverty: Is There a Connection? In
World Trade Organisation (WTO), Trade, Income Disparity and Poverty.
Geneva (WTO Special Study No. 5.) pp. 43-69.
World Bank (2003) World Development Indicators C-D ROM. Washington,
D. C.: The World Bank.
World Bank (2004) Vietnam Development Report, 2004. Washington,
D.C. (forthcoming)
Authors' Note: Views expressed here are solely those of the
authors.
(1) Out of the ten countries of Asia on which data is available on
the incidence of poverty during the last two decades, the rate of
poverty reduction has declined in the 90s in relation to the 80s in
Philippines, while there has been a reversal in the poverty trend during
the 90s, from a reduction in the 80s, in Indonesia, Malaysia, Pakistan
and Sri Lanka. Poverty incidence has increased over both decades in
Nepal.
(2) Econometric analysis involving the use of the OLS technique has
also been tried. However, due to the limited number of observations, the
results appear to be very sensitive to one or two observations and
cannot, therefore, be judged as being robust in character. For example,
the inclusion of Mongolia into the data dramatically alters the nature
of the results because this country experienced a sharp increase in
poverty in the 90s, arising from a fall in per capita income and a very
high rate of inflation. Hence, regression results have not been
presented here, though they indicate a negative and significant
relationship between growth and poverty.
(3) The cut-off point used in deciding whether faster or slower
growth (higher or lower inflation, higher or lower employment growth,
etc.) is generally based on the average figure of our sample as well as
on the international experience.
(4) The three excluded cases are Indonesia, Malaysia, and Sri
Lanka, all in the 90s--the first two because of the Asian financial
crisis, and the last because of the serious conflict situation in the
North and East of the country.
(5) Looking at the two extremes we observe that in the six cases of
fast growth per capita income combined with fast employment and
agricultural growth, the average rate of decline annually in the
incidence of poverty was as high as seven percent. These cases are:
China (80s); Indonesia (70s); Malaysia (70s); Thailand (70s); Vietnam
(90s) and Lao PDR (90s). As opposed to this, in the eight cases where
slow growth of per capita income was accompanied by both slow
agricultural and employment growth, poverty increased on the average at
the rate of one percent per annum.
(6) In order to test whether these findings are driven mainly by
China or/and India, we carried out these exercises without China as well
as without both China and India. The results are, more or less, the same
in these exercises too.
Hafiz A. Pasha is Assistant Secretary-General and Assistant
Administrator and Director of the Regional Bureau for Asia and the
Pacific of the UNDP. T. Palanivel is Programme Coordinator of the
UNDP's Asia-Pacific Regional Programme on Macroeconomics of Poverty
Reduction.
Table 1
Rates of Per Capita Income Growth and Change in Incidence
of Poverty in Sample Countries in Different Decades (%)
1970s 1980s
Rate of Rate of Rate of Rate of
Per Change in Per Change in
Capita Incidence Capita Incidence
Income of Income of
Country Growth Poverty Growth Poverty
Bangladesh -- -- 2.2 -0.6
Cambodia -- -- -- --
China 4.4 -0.8 7.8 -9.8
India 0.8 -1.7 3.6 -2.2
Indonesia 5.4 -7.2 4.5 -6.1
Lao PDR -- -- -- --
Malaysia 5.3 -6.7 3.1 -4.2
Mongolia -- -- -- --
Nepal -- -- 2.5 0.8
Pakistan 1.5 -4.1 3.5 -1.3
Philippines 3.1 -0.2 -0.6 -4.5
Sri Lanka 2.7 -0.8 3.1 -7.1
Thailand 4.1 -4.2 6.0 0.6
Vietnam -- -- -- --
1990s
Rate of Rate of
Per Change in
Capita Incidence
Income of
Country Growth Poverty
Bangladesh 3.0 -2.4
Cambodia 2.4 5.5
China 9.0 -9.8
India 3.6 -2.8
Indonesia 2.9 2.1
Lao PDR 3.7 -5.1
Malaysia 4.6 2.9
Mongolia -1.2 13.1
Nepal 2.6 0.7
Pakistan 1.4 2.8
Philippines 0.6 -1.3
Sri Lanka 3.9 4.8
Thailand 3.7 -2.3
Vietnam 5.8 -6.9
Sources: (i) Rate of Per Capita Income Growth: World Bank (2003),
World Development Indicators. (ii) Rate of Poverty Incidence:
from Table A-1 (Statistical Appendix).
Table 2
Relationship between Economic Growth and Poverty (%)
Average Kate
of Growth in
Number Per Capita
of Cases Income
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
(> 3.5% per annum) 13 5.1
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
([less than or equal 16 1.9
to] 5 3.5% per annum)
Average rate Average
of Change in growth
Incidence of Elasticity
Poverty of Poverty
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
(> 3.5% per annum) -4.9 -0.96
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
([less than or equal -0.4 -0.21
to] 5 3.5% per annum)
Sources: v. Calculated from Table 1.
Table 3
Growth Elasticity of Poverty in Different Countries
in Different Decades
Country 1970s 1980s 1990s
Bangladesh -- -0.29 -0.81
Cambodia -- -- 2.31
China -0.18 -1.26 -1.09
India -2.15 -0.6 -0.77
Indonesia -1.33 -1.35 0.72
Lao PDR -- -- -1.37
Malaysia -1.26 -1.36 0.63
Mongolia -- -- n.a
Nepal -- 0.33 0.27
Pakistan -2.73 -0.38 2.01
Philippines -0.07 n.a -2.25
Sri Lanka -0.3 -2.28 1.24
Thailand -1.02 0.10 -0.63
Vietnam -- -- -1.18
Sources: Computed from Table 1.
Table 4
Relationship between Economic Growth, Inequality, and Poverty (%)
Average Rate
of Change in Average Growth
Number Incidence of Elasticity of
of Cases Poverty Poverty
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Rising Inequality 9 -5.6 -1.06
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Falling Inequality 4 -3.1 -0.65
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Rising Inequality 11 0.7 0.41
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Falling Inequality 5 -2.7 -1.13
Sources: Data taken from Table 1 and Table A-2 (Statistical Appendix).
Table 5
Economic Growth, Inflation, and Poverty (%)
Number of Average Rate
Cases of Inflation
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
High Rate of Inflation
([greater than or equal 6 15.4
to] 10%)
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Low Rate of Inflation
(< 10%) 7 6.2
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
High Rate of Inflation 7 19.8
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Low Rate of Inflation 9 7.0
Average Rate Average
of Change in Growth
Incidence of Elasticity
Poverty of Poverty
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
High Rate of Inflation
([greater than or equal -5.0 -1.04
to] 10%)
Fast Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Low Rate of Inflation
(< 10%) -11.8 -0.89
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
High Rate of Inflation 0.1 0.07
Slow Growth in Per
Capita Income;
Low Rate of Inflation -0.7 -0.3
Sources: Calculated from Table I and Table A-3 (Statistical Appendix).
Table 6
Economic Growth, Employment, and Poverty (%)
Average Rate
Number of of Employment
Cases Growth
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Employment Expansion
([greater than or equal 7 3.3
to] 2.5 % per annum)
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Employment Expansion
(< 2.5% per annum) 6 1.8
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Employment Expansion 7 3.1
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Employment Expansion 9 1.8
Average Rate Average
of Change in Growth
Incidence of Elasticity
Poverty of Poverty
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Employment Expansion
([greater than or equal -5.4 -1.02
to] 2.5 % per annum)
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Employment Expansion
(< 2.5% per annum) -4.2 -0.84
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Employment Expansion -2.0 -0.91
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Employment Expansion 0.9 0.53
Sources: Calculated from Table 1 and Table A-4 (Statistical Appendix).
Table 7
Economic Growth, Agricultural Development, and Poverty (%)
Average
Rate of
Number Agricultural
of Cases Growth
Fast Growth of Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Agricultural Development
([greater than or equal 10 4.4
to] 3 % per annum)
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Agricultural Development
(< 3 % per annum) 3 2.5
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Agricultural Development 7 3.9
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Agricultural Development 9 2.1
Average Rate Average
of Change in Growth
Incidence of Elasticity
Poverty of Poverty
Fast Growth of Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Agricultural Development
([greater than or equal -5.7 -1.04
to] 3 % per annum)
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Agricultural Development
(< 3 % per annum) -2.0 -0.51
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Agricultural Development -0.7 -0.26
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Agricultural Development -0.1 -0.08
Sources: Calculated from Table 1 and Table A-5 (Statistical Appendix).
Table 8 Economic Growth, Exports, and Poverty
Average
Rate of
Number Export
of Cases Growth
Fast Growth of Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Export Expansion
([greater than or equal 7 15.9
to] 10% per annum)
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Export Expansion
(< 10% per annum) 6 7.0
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Export Expansion 7 12.9
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Export Expansion 9 5.8
Average
Rate of Average
Change in Growth
Incidence Elasticity
of Poverty of Poverty
Fast Growth of Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Export Expansion
([greater than or equal -5.2 -0.91
to] 10% per annum)
Fast Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Export Expansion
(< 10% per annum) -4.5 -0.98
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Rapid Export Expansion -0.1 -0.04
Slow Growth in Per Capita
Income;
Slow Export Expansion -0.6 -0.33
Sources: Calculated from Table 1 and Table A-6 (Statistical Appendix).