The exchange rate and consumer prices in Pakistan: is rupee devaluation inflationary?
Choudhri, Ehsan U. ; Khan, Mohsin S.
This paper challenges the popular view that devaluation of the
rupee is inflationary. Recent developments in the theoretical literature
are reviewed to explain why consumer prices would be unresponsive to
exchange rate changes in the short run. Then empirical tests are
conducted for Pakistan during the period 1982 to 2001 to examine whether
inflation is systematically related to changes in the exchange rate. The
empirical analysis finds no association between rupee devaluations and
inflation in Pakistan. It appears, therefore, that concerns about the
inflationary consequences of rupee devaluation are unsupported by the
facts.
1. INTRODUCTION
Does devaluation lead to an increase in prices? This is a critical
question that policy-makers in Pakistan have faced continuously over the
past three decades or so, and particularly since 1982, following the
adoption of a flexible exchange rate policy. At the beginning of 1972,
the US dollar exchanged for about five Pakistani rupees. After a
devaluation in 1972 and a small revaluation in 1973, the exchange rate
remained fixed at about ten rupees per dollar till the end of 1981. The
exchange rate was allowed to vary since January 1982 and it rose to a
rate around sixty rupees per dollar over the next two decades. This
increase involved a number of sizable rupee devaluations. Such
devaluations receive considerable attention and often raise the concern
that they would contribute to inflation. The concern about inflation is
based on the popular view, which has sometimes been shared by officials
in policymaking circles, that consumer prices are significantly affected
by imported goods prices, which increase quickly in response to a
devaluation. (1) This view is generally thought to find support in
empirical studies of inflation in Pakistan. In the most recent study on
the subject, Ahmad and Ali (1999) assert that the "recent empirical
work in Pakistan provides consistent evidence that the domestic price
level responds significantly but gradually to exchange rate
devaluation" (p. 237).
Obviously, if the devaluation-inflation link exists, then
devaluation comes with an important cost that necessarily must be
factored into the exchange rate policy. Furthermore, it implies that the
authorities can only affect the real exchange rate temporarily, because
as domestic prices rise, the initial effects of a nominal depreciation
on the real exchange rate would be reversed. On these two counts at
least, exchange rate policy becomes fairly constrained.
This paper argues that the fear of inflation associated with
devaluations in Pakistan is largely unfounded. We draw on recent
developments in the literature on the exchange rate pass-through and the
purchasing power parity to suggest reasons why consumer prices might be
unresponsive to changes in the exchange rate. We also reexamine the
evidence for Pakistan and present new results, which demonstrate that
rupee devaluations have had little impact on inflation. (2) The theory
underlying the relationship between the exchange rate and consumer
prices is reviewed in Section 2. The empirical analysis is discussed in
Section 3. The conclusions of the paper are contained in Section 4.
2. THE EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH TO CONSUMER PRICES
This section briefly discusses the channels through which changes
in the exchange rate pass-through to consumer prices. We begin with the
conventional model that implies a significant and, under certain
conditions, a complete pass-through to consumer prices in the short run.
(3) We then discuss certain departures from the conventional model
suggested by recent literature, which could account for little or no
pass-through in the short run. Finally, we examine the long-run
relationship between the exchange rate and the price level, and discuss
conditions that would weaken this relationship.
2.1 Traded and Non-traded Goods
The basket of goods entering the consumer price index (CPI) can be
divided into traded and non-traded goods. Letting [P.sub.t] denote the
CPI in period t, we can express it as
[P.sub.t] = [([P.sup.T.sub.t]).sup.[theta]]
[([P.sup.NT.sub.t]).sup.1-[theta]], ... ... ... ... ...(1)
where [P.sup.T.sub.t] and [[P.sup.NT.sub.t] are the price indexes
for traded and non-traded goods, and 0 is the weight assigned to traded
goods. The home price of traded goods can be directly linked to the
price of foreign traded goods adjusted for the exchange rate. The
conventional model assumes that traded goods are produced under
competitive conditions. This assumption implies that, in the absence of
trade barriers, the price of a traded good expressed in a particular
currency will be the same in each country. (4) The following relation
can then be derived by aggregating over prices of individual traded
goods:
[[P.sup.T.sub.t] = [S.sub.t][[P.sup.T*.sub.t], ... ... ... ... ...
... (2)
where [S.sub.t] is the exchange rate (expressed as the price of
foreign currency) and [[P.sup.T*.sub.t] is the foreign price index for
traded goods (which is assumed to use the same weights as the home
index). This relation implies that a change in the exchange rate will
fully pass-through to the traded goods price index. The relation can be
easily modified to introduce trade costs (e.g., transportation costs,
tariffs, and non-tariff barriers). These costs introduce a wedge between
the home and (exchange-rate adjusted) foreign prices, but as long as
these costs are determined independently of the exchange rate, the
exchange rate pass-through to traded goods prices would continue to be
complete.
The price for the non-traded goods sector will be determined by the
demand and supply functions for this sector. These functions would
depend on the ratio of non-traded goods to traded goods prices. Let
[gamma] be the price ratio that clears the nontraded goods market. Thus,
in equilibrium
[[P.sup.NT.sub.t] = [gamma][[P.sup.T.sub.t]. ... ... ... ... ...
... (3)
Relation (3) provides an indirect link between the exchange rate
and the non-traded goods price index. If the price of non-traded goods
is flexible and adjusts quickly, (3) will hold in the short run. In this
case, there will be a complete pass-through in the short run to both
traded and non-traded goods prices [via (2) and (3)] and hence to the
CPI. In fact, assuming that relations analogous to (1) and (3) hold for
the foreign economy, we can also link the domestic CPI to both the
exchange rate and the foreign CPI. Using (1), (3), their foreign
counterparts, and (2), we can obtain
[[P.sub.t] = [[P.sub.t][[P.sup.*.sub.t]
[([gamma]/[[gamma].sup.*]).sup.1-[theta]] ... ... ... ... ... ... (4)
where [[P.sup.*.sub.t] and [[gamma].sup.*] represent the CPI and
the equilibrium relative price of non-traded goods in the foreign
country. The home CPI responds fully to the foreign CPI as well as the
exchange rate in this relation.
The short-run impact of the exchange rate on CPI would be weakened
if nontraded goods prices are sticky. Exchange rate changes would now
affect only traded goods prices in the short run and the short-run
pass-through to CPI would equal the share of traded goods, [theta]. (5)
The share of traded goods can be substantial and thus the short-run
pass-through to CPI can be sizeable even if non-traded goods prices
adjust slowly.
2.2 The Short-run Pass-through
We next discuss a number of variations of the above model that
could cause the short-run pass-through to be small. Consider, first, the
variations that loosen the traded goods price relation (2) in the short
run. One important point of departure in the recent literature has been
to relax the assumption of perfect competition. Under imperfect
competition, prices include a markup over costs and producers have the
discretion to vary the markup across countries (i.e., they can price to
market). (6) The pass-through to traded goods price would be incomplete
if variations in the markup offset changes in the exchange rate. (7)
However, the equilibrium markup need not respond systematically to
exchange rate changes. In fact, it can be shown that the equilibrium
markup would be invariant with respect to the exchange rate under the
standard assumption of a constant price elasticity of demand.
Another argument is that imperfectly-competitive producers would
change prices infrequently in the presence of even small menu costs.
Infrequent price adjustment would not prevent complete pass-through in
the importing country if the producer (exporter) fixes the price in its
own currency. However, if the price is set in local (importer's)
currency and is sticky, it would be unresponsive to exchange rate
fluctuations in the short run. (8) Local currency pricing can thus play
an important role in blocking the impact of exchange rate changes on
traded goods prices in the short run. However, while local currency
pricing has been observed in some large industrial countries, such as
the United States, it is not clear whether this practice occurs in
developing countries like Pakistan.
A weak response of the traded goods component of the CPI may also
be explained by the fact that imported goods are generally not sold
directly to consumers. Many imported goods are, in fact, intermediate
inputs imported by firms producing final products. (9) If prices of the
final products are adjusted infrequently, changes in the cost of inputs
resulting from fluctuations in the exchange rate will not be quickly
passed on to consumers. Even non-intermediate imports go through
distribution channels (transportation, marketing, retailing) before they
are delivered to consumers. These channels largely use non-traded
services, which can account for a large fraction of the consumer price.
(10) The price component represented by local services would then not be
affected by the exchange rate in the short run.
The short-run pass-through could also be weakened by certain
factors that introduce biases in measured prices and are of special
relevance to developing economies. For example, a home-currency
devaluation could induce a substitution of cheaper lower-quality local
goods for imported goods. Burstein, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2001) refer
to this phenomenon as "flight from quality" and argue that it
helps explain why a number of large devaluations had a small impact on
the measured inflation rate. Price regulation of "essential"
commodities and foreign exchange controls could represent another
important source of bias in the observed price and exchange rate data.
Because measured values would not fully reflect true market values under
these policies, the pass-through relation would be distorted.
2.3 The Long-run Relation
The reasons discussed above can insulate traded goods prices from
changes in the exchange rate in the short run. However, they do not
explain why traded and non-traded goods prices would not fully respond
to exchange rate changes in the long run. To understand the long-term
association between these variables, it is important to note that both
the exchange rate and consumer prices are determined endogenously and
respond differently to various shocks. Estimates of the effect of the
exchange rate on consumer prices essentially capture the average
response of the two variables to a variety of shocks. To explain the
long-run relation between the exchange rate and consumer prices, it is
useful to discuss how these variables would respond to different shocks.
We can distinguish three types of shocks.
First, there are temporary shocks to the foreign exchange and
financial markets. These arise largely from policy interventions and
private speculation triggered by changing expectations of future values.
These shocks account for much of the short-term variability of the
exchange rate, but may have little effect on consumer prices for reasons
discussed above.
Second, there are permanent shocks to the money stock. These shocks
would be fully passed on to both the exchange rate and consumer prices
in the long run. Suppose, for example, that home money supply increases
permanently by 10 percent. Assuming that the long-run money demand is
unchanged, monetary equilibrium would require that the CPI rise by 10
percent in the long run. As this change would not affect the equilibrium
relative price of non-traded goods ([gamma]), relation (4) implies that
the exchange rate would also rise by 10 percent. Thus a permanent
monetary shock would bring about a change in the price level that would
match the exchange rate change in the long run.
Finally, there are real shocks (to technology and preferences) that
lead to permanent changes in relative prices. These shocks would
influence only the exchange rate in the long run. As an example, assume
that labour productivity in traded goods increases permanently. This
change would increase the wage rate in both the traded and non-traded
goods sectors and increase the equilibrium price for the non-traded
goods sector (where labour productivity has not risen). Since the money
market is not affected, the CPI would be unchanged. However, relation
(4) would require that the exchange rate fall to compensate for the
increase in the relative price of non-traded goods. The long-run
response to a permanent real shock, therefore, involves a change in the
exchange rate but not the price level.
As the above discussion indicates, the long-run association between
the exchange rate and CPI would depend on the relative importance of
monetary and real shocks. Monetary shocks would tend to be less
important in economies where long-run inflation rates are low. The
long-run relation between the exchange rate and CPI is likely to be weak
in such economies. (11) Identification of this relation would be made
difficult, moreover, by the presence of noise introduced by temporary
shocks to the exchange rate.
The long-run link between the exchange rate and prices can be
related to Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) theory. According to this
theory, the exchange rate and the ratio of home and foreign price levels
would exhibit the same proportional change in the long run. This
implication can be restated in terms of the behaviour of the real
exchange rate, defined as the nominal exchange rate divided by the ratio
of the price levels (i.e., the real exchange rate equals
[S.sub.t][P.sup.*.sub.t/[P.sub.t]). PPP implies that the real exchange
rate will revert to a constant level in the long run. In terms of the
model with traded and non-traded goods discussed above, it can be seen
from (4) that PPP will hold only if the ratio, [gamma]/[[gamma].sup.*],
is constant in the long run. As discussed above, however, this condition
would not be satisfied if the home and foreign economies are subject to
different permanent real shocks.
3. EVIDENCE FOR PAKISTAN
For our empirical analysis we focus on the period since 1982,
during which the dollar-rupee exchange rate was no longer fixed. The
behaviour of the exchange rate (ER), the domestic consumer price index
(CPI), and an index of foreign consumer prices (FCPI) are shown in
Figure 1 from the first quarter of 1982 to the second quarter of 2001.
(12) FCPI represents a weighted average of the consumer prices for
Pakistan's trading partners expressed in US dollars with weights
based on Pakistan's foreign trade. Note that this index is
influenced by each country's US dollar exchange rate, and thus
tends to be more variable than the consumer price series for individual
countries expressed in national currencies.
To examine the exchange rate pass-through to consumer prices, we
estimate the effect of ER on CPI, using FCPI as the control variable. As
Figure 1 indicates, these series exhibit a marked upward trend and
appear to be non-stationary. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test
indicates that all three series contain a unit root. (13) Estimation of
the pass-through relation in levels could thus lead to finding a
spurious relation between these variables. The relation in first
differences, on the other hand, would ignore relevant information if
these variables were co-integrated.
These variables would be co-integrated if the PPP holds and thus
the real exchange rate for Pakistan (RER) is stationary. (14) The path
of RER is also shown in Figure 1.
There has been a significant increase in RER (or a decrease in the
real value of the rupee) during the 1980s and 1990s, and RER does not
appear to converge to a constant value (or a deterministic path). (15)
The ADF test does not reject the hypothesis that RER (in logs) has a
unit root. (16) We assume that the exchange rate and prices are not
co-integrated and thus estimate the relation between these variables in
first differences.
Estimates of the exchange rate pass-through are based on a
regression equation of the following form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
where lags are introduced to allow for gradual adjustment in prices
and et is the error term. (17) This equation can be used to derive
estimates of the degree of the exchange rate pass-through over different
periods. The pass-through coefficient after in periods is defined as the
effect of a one unit increase in log ER in period t on log CPI in period
t + m, and can be readily calculated from estimates of coefficients,
namely the [b.sub.i']s and [c.sub.i]'s, in (5).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Equation (5) is estimated using quarterly data from 1982:1 to
2001:2. Two estimates of this equation are shown in Table 1: one based
on 4 lags for each variable, and the other using the Schwartz criterion
to determine the optimal lag length for each variable. In both cases,
the effect of ER on CPI is insignificant. Estimates of the short-run
pass-through, in fact, are negative. For example, the regression
equation using the Schwartz criterion implies that the pass-through
coefficient is -0.02 in the current quarter, and -0.01 after 4 quarters.
Equation (5) focuses on the effect of the US dollar exchange rate. For a
given US dollar-rupee rate, the rupee value in another currency could
vary because of changes in the currency's exchange rate with
respect to the US dollar. The effect of such a change on consumer prices
would operate via FCPI. As Table 1 shows, however, even this variable
does not have a significant impact on CPI. (18)
The unresponsiveness of consumer prices to the exchange rate can be
seen clearly by looking at the behaviour of the inflation rate after
large rupee devaluations. During the sample period, the rupee registered
quarterly depreciations of more than 10 percent only three times, once
at the beginning and twice at the end of the period. Figure 2 shows the
behaviour of the inflation rate for several quarters after these
devaluations. As the figure shows, the devaluations do not have any
appreciable effect on the path of the inflation rate.
Consumer prices include retail margins that depend on local
services and are likely to be insensitive to the exchange rate. It may
be thought that the exchange rate may exert a stronger influence on the
wholesale price index (WPI) that excludes retail margins and gives more
weight to traded goods. Equation (5) was thus reestimated replacing
[DELTA]logCPI by [DELTA]logWPI. The effect of ER remained insignificant
even in this equation. (19) These results are consistent with the recent
view discussed in the previous section that even the traded goods prices
respond weakly to the exchange rate.
One limitation of the pass-through relation estimated above is that
exchange rate changes are not exogenous, but reflect the effect of a
variety of shocks. Each shock may have a different pattern of effect on
prices. A structural model is needed to identify individual shocks and
to trace the effect of each shock on the exchange rate and prices.
Although a thorough analysis along these lines is beyond the scope of
this paper, we briefly explore this issue by estimating a simple Vector
Auto-regression (VAR).
We consider a VAR with two endogenous variables, [DELTA]logER and
[DELTA]logCP1, and one exogenous variable, [DELTA]logFCPI. In this
simple framework, we can distinguish between two types of shocks: (1)
shocks to asset markets and (2) shocks to goods markets. Asset market
shocks are thought to account for much of the observed exchange rate
volatility. It is thus interesting to examine how these shocks
pass-through to consumer prices. To identify these shocks we exploit the
assumption that information about goods markets becomes available with a
lag, so that asset market shocks are independent of the contemporaneous value of [DELTA]logCPI. Under this assumption, the reduced-form shock to
[DELTA]logER can be viewed as an asset market shock, and Cholesky
decomposition can be used to estimate the response of consumer prices to
this shock.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 3 shows the response of [DELTA]logCPI to a one
standard-deviation shock to [DELTA]logER over 10 quarters. (20) Two
standard deviation bands for this impulse response function are also
shown in the figure. The response of the rate of inflation to the shock
is close to zero not only in the first year but even after two years.
The variance-decomposition analysis shows that shocks to [DELTA]logER
explain 97 percent of the variance of this variable after 10 quarters
and 96 percent of the variance after 20 quarters. These results suggest
that asset market shocks dominate exchange rate changes, and a weak
response of CPI to these shocks accounts for the absence of a
significant exchange rate pass-through.
Our empirical analysis does not support the results of Ahmad and
Ali (1999) that a devaluation has a significant impact on inflation. We
believe that their results differ from ours because they estimate a
model that is based on some fairly restrictive assumptions. For example,
they assume that there is a complete exchange rate pass-through to
import prices. This assumption is important for their results, but is
not supported by recent theoretical models or empirical evidence. They
also estimate relations linking the price level and the exchange rate in
(log) levels. As noted above, estimation of relations between
non-stationary variables in the level form can produce spurious results.
(21)
4. CONCLUSIONS
This paper challenges the popular view that devaluations tend to
cause inflation in Pakistan. The empirical analysis in the paper finds
no evidence of a significant pass-through of rupee depreciations to
consumer prices in the short run. This finding is consistent with recent
theoretical analysis that suggests a weak short-run association between
exchange rate changes and inflation. It would appear, therefore, that
concerns about the inflationary consequences of devaluation in Pakistan
are somewhat misplaced. Stability of the nominal exchange rate may be
desirable for many reasons, but not because of fears that exchange rate
fluctuations will impose an inflationary cost on the economy.
In the last two decades, the rupee has depreciated significantly
not only in nominal but also in real terms. This long-period loss of
rupee's real value implies that even in the long run,
Pakistan's inflation rate has not fully reflected the rate of rupee
depreciation. One interesting issue that remains to be explored is: What
factors have caused the long-term change in the real exchange rate, and
what effects has this had on the Pakistan economy.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Authors' Note: The paper was prepared while Ehsan Choudhri was
Visiting Professor at the IMF Institute. The views expressed are those
of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the
International Monetary Fund.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Eatzaz, and Saima Ahmed Ali (1999) Exchange Rate and
Inflation Dynamics. The Pakistan Development Review 38:3,235-251.
Burstein, Ariel, Joao Neves, and Sergio Rebelo (2001) Distribution
Costs and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics During Exchange-rate-based
Stabilisations. Journal of Monetary Economics (forthcoming.)
Burstein, Ariel, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo (2001) Why
Are Inflation Rates So Low after Large Contractionary Devaluations?
(Mimeographed.)
Choudhri, Ehsan U., and Dalia S. Hakura (2001) Exchange Rate
Pass-through to Domestic Prices: Does the Inflationary Environment
Matter? (IMF Working Paper 01/194.)
Devereux, Michael B., and Charles Engel (2001) Monetary Policy in
the Open Economy Revisited: Exchange Rate Flexibility and Price Setting
Behaviour. (Mimeographed.)
Krugman, Paul R. (1987) Pricing to Market When the Exchange Rate
Changes. In Sven W. Arndt and J. David Richardson (eds.) Real-Financial
Linkages among Open Economies. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
McCallum, Bennett T., and Edward Nelson (1999) Nominal Income Targeting in an Open-Economy Optimising Model. Journal of Monetary
Economics 43, 553578.
Siddiqui, Rehana, and Naeem Akhtar (1999) The Impact of Changes in
Exchange Rate on Prices: A Case Study of Pakistan. The Pakistan
Development Review 38: 4, 1059-1066.
(1) A related view emphasises the role of "input
inflation" via devaluation-induced increases in electricity tariffs
and prices of petroleum products (ABN AMRO Economic Bulletin, July
2002).
(2) Our results complement those of Siddiqui and Akhtar (1999),
which show no causal relation between changes in the exchange rate and
consumer-price inflation in Pakistan.
(3) The degree of pass-through to a particular price index is
defined as ,me elasticity of the price index with respect to the
exchange rate. The pass-through is complete when this elasticity equals
one.
(4) Arbitrage would eliminate inter-country price differences under
these conditions. This result is referred to as the "Law of One
Price".
(5) A 1 percent change in the exchange rate will cause a I percent
change in the traded goods price index according to (2) and thus a
[theta] percent change in CPI by (l).
(6) See, for example, Krugman 0987) for a discussion of pricing to
market. It is assumed that trade costs and other factors segment
international markets and make it difficult to arbitrage inter-country
price differences.
(7) The price of a traded good i supplied by a foreign producer
would equal [[P.sup.T.sub.it] =
[[mu].sub.it][S.sub.t][([C.sup.*.subi.t], where [[mu].sub.it] represent
the markup and [C.sup.*.sub.it] is the foreign marginal cost. The
pass-through would be incomplete if [[mu].sub.it] is inversely related
to [S.sub.t]
(8) See Devereux and Engel (2001) for a discussion of local
currency pricing and its implications for monetary policy.
(9) A number of recent open economy macro-economic models [e.g.,
McCallum and Nelson (1999)], in fact, treat all imports as intermediate
inputs.
(10) See Burstein, Neves, and Rebelo (2001) for a discussion of the
importance of the distribution costs.
(11) Choudhri and Hakura (2001) present evidence that the
pass-through (in the short as well as the long run) is positively
related to the average inflation rate across countries.
(12) The source of all data is IMF, International Financial
Statistics. The series on the real effective exchange rate for Pakistan
was used to construct the FCPI measure.
(13) Applying the ADF test to each series expressed in logs,
including an intercept, a deterministic trend, and using up to 4 lags,
the test statistic does not reject the unit-root null at the 10 percent
level for all three series.
(14) 1n this case, there is a co-integrating relation between logs
of ER, FCPI and CPI with a cointegrating vector (1, 1, -1).
(15) One possible explanation of the sharp increase in RER is that
the traded-goods productivity gap between foreign countries and Pakistan
has widened over the past two decades.
(16) The ADF statistic with an intercept, trend, and 4 lags is
-2.038 while the 10 percent critical value is -3.160.
(17) For a discussion of a theoretical model that would suggest a
pass-through relation of this form, see Choudhri and Hakura (2001).
(18) We also estimated (5) after redefining ER as the effective
exchange rate (i.e., the price of a basket of currencies using
Pakistan's trade weights), and FCPI as the corresponding foreign
consumer price index. The influence of the effective exchange rate was
statistically insignificant in this equation as well.
(19) The results are available on request from the authors.
(20) The VAR includes 4 lags of each endogenous variable. A
constant term, and the current and 4 lagged values of [DELTA]logFCPI are
also included in each VAR equation. The impulse response function is
based on a Cholesky decomposition with [DELTA]logER as the first
variable.
(21) They claim that their relations are co-integrated. Their
co-integration test (an ADF test on the residuals), however, is applied
after imposing a number of ad. hoc restrictions on each relation. We
eschew estimating our pass-through relation in the level form in view of
the indication of a unit root in the real exchange rate.
Ehsan U. Choudhri is Professor of Economics, Carleton University,
Canada. Mohsin S. Khan is Director, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D. C.
Table 1
Estimates of the Pass-through Relation
Coefficient (t-value in Brackets)
Variable (1) (2)
Constant 0.007 (1.29) 0.007 (2.01)
[DELTA]logCP[I.sub.t-1] 0.450 (3.56) 0.444 (3.71)
[DELTA]logCP[I.sub.t-2] -0.300 (-2.23) -0.311 (-2.42)
[DELTA]logCP[I.sub.t-3] 0.275 (2.03) 0.283 (2.21)
[DELTA]logCP[I.sub.t-4] 0.239 (1.89) 0.244 (2.05)
[DELTA]logE[R.sub.t-1] 0.004 (0.06)
[DELTA]logE[R.sub.t-2] -0.027 (-0.45)
[DELTA]logE[R.sub.t-3] -0.033 (-0.59)
[DELTA]logE[R.sub.t-4] 0.065 (1.18)
[DELTA]logFCP[I.sub.t] -0.022 (-0.55) 0.005 (0.16)
[DELTA]logFCP[I.sub.t-1] 0.009 (0.24)
[DELTA]logFCP[I.sub.t-2] -0.012 (-0.31)
[DELTA]logFCP[I.sub.t-3] 0.007 (0.20)
[DELTA]logFCP[I.sub.t-4] 0.043 (1.10)
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.260 0.307
S.E. of Regression 0.010 0.010
Note: The dependent variable is [DELTA]log[CPI.sub.t].
The lags in regression (2) are determined by the
Schwartz criterion.