Performance of the public electric power industry: evidence from Pakistan.
Ghafoor, Abdul ; Weiss, John
The study investigates the performance of electric power sector of
Pakistan at the firm level, as well as the sector as a whole. It
identifies and attempts to quantity the extent of inefficiencies. Since
either physical or financial or productivity indicators alone are not
able to explain the duality of public infrastructure purposes and the
complexity of their multi-dimensional goals, a set of relevant physical,
financial, and productivity indicators have been used in evaluating the
performance of this sector. Further, a CobbDouglas production function
has also been used to calculate the trend in the growth of total factor
productivity. Economies of scale have also been studied in the case of
electric power generation.
1. INTRODUCTION
In recent years, considerable emphasis has been placed on the
potential for private capital to play an important role in
infrastructure development, either through direct purchase of state
enterprises and mixed ownership arrangements or a form of
Build-Own-Operate-and-Transfer (BOOT) scheme. In part, this stems from
the difficulties faced by many governments in raising additional funds
for large infrastructure investments, in addition, however, a second
factor has been the widely-held perception, expressed clearly by World
Bank (1995), that state enterprises in most countries have operated with
considerable inefficiency, particularly in infrastructure, where the
large capital involved and the potential for external effects at one
time appeared to make infrastructure investments natural candidates for
public provision. There is a body of theory, based on a lack of property
rights and lack of market discipline, which attempts to rationalise the
case for inherent public sector inefficiency [Adam, et al. (1992)].
However, this does not convince everyone, and to make a firm case for
privatisation there is a strong need for further empirical studies that
demonstrate how public sector infrastructure enterprises have actually
performed.
This paper attempts to contribute to this area by evaluating the
performance of the public sector enterprises of electricity industry in
Pakistan during the period 1960-95. The following section of the paper
sets out briefly the development of this sector in Pakistan. The third
gives financial indicators for the enterprises involved. As is
frequently the case, judgments based on financial data on enterprise
performance can be misleading and, therefore, the fourth section
considers evidence based on estimated total factor productivity growth,
which gives a quite different picture on performance. Finally, the fifth
section draws some conclusions.
2. THE DEVELOPMENT OF ELECTRICITY IN PAKISTAN: AN OVERVIEW
Pakistan's two power utilities are the Water and Power
Development Authority (WAPDA) and the Karachi Electricity Supply
Corporation (KESC). The former has a national coverage, whilst the
latter serves only the Karachi division and related areas. WAPDA's
power plants are a mix of hydel and thermal supplies, whilst KESC's
are all thermal. Growth in power generation has been very substantial,
with an increase in aggregate supplies of approximately 12 percent
annually from 1960 to 1995. Over the same period, per capita power
availability increased from 28kwh to 444kwh (1). System losses in the
sector, at 24 percent in 1990, were relatively higher than in many other
industrial and developing countries [World Bank (1994)]. Both WAPDA and
KESC (2) are vertically integrated in the production, transmission, and
distribution of power, and although they are not subject to rate of
return regulation, price increases must be approved by the government.
In real terms, the average unit price for power has remained largely
constant, with some annual fluctuations, between 1960 and 1995 at around
rupees 1.0 per kwh of WAPDA and around rupees 1.20 for KESC.2 However,
comparative tariff data suggests that in dollar terms, tariffs in
Pakistan, at least in the 1980s, were well below those in comparable
economies in the Asian region [Malhotra, et al. (1994)].
Loadshedding (3) by the two companies has been seen as a major
problem over the period under consideration and several studies have
suggested that power bottlenecks have imposed serious costs on the
Pakistan's economy. For example, Pasha and Gellerson (1988) and All
(1990) calculated the loss in industrial output from factory closures
due to power cuts. The former suggested it might be 9 percent of annual
industrial output (i.e., a loss of 0.9 billion US dollars or about 2.25
percent of GDP). The latter put the annual cost in lost GDP at 1 billion
US dollars (i.e., about
2.5 percent G DP). In a production function approach, USA ID (1988)
estimated costs of loadshedding at nearly 2 percent of GDP and a fall in
manufactured exports of 4 percent.(4)
Despite a substantial increase of electric power generation during
the past decades, the performance of this sector has been criticised on
the basis of inadequate facilities relative to the growing demand. Since
the efficiency of this sector is doubted today, it faces alternative
policy reform such as build-own-operate-andtransfer (BOOT),
build-transfer-operate (BOT), lease-develop-operate (LDO), and vertical
disintegration (5) [Ziauddin (1997) and Dawn (1997)]. Therefore, the
intent of the present study is to investigate the performance of
electric power sector of Pakistan at the firm level, as well as the
sector as a whole, and identify and quantify the extent of inefficiency
in the case of poor performance.
3. METHODOLOGY
Public enterprises in general and public infrastructure in
particular are expected to fulfil complex multi-dimensional goals, (6)
which makes it difficult to devise a satisfactory procedure to assess
their performance. Although many studies on public enterprises are
limited to the profitability criterion, (7) it is unfair to evaluate
this multi-objective sector on financial bases only. However, the
financial criterion cannot be neglected because of the overall budget
constraint of the government. Thus, literature suggests that financial
indicators must be used in conjunction with the factor productivity
criteria. However, these criteria could be applied to commercial
objectives only.
As regards non-commercial objectives, Millward and Parker (1983);
Jenkins and Lahouel (1983) and World Bank (1995) suggest that
performance should be evaluated on the basis of cost effectiveness or
unit cost of production while Pryke (1981) and OECD (1990) argue that
the physical yardstick is neutral regarding ownership and social and
economic costs and benefits.
By considering all these arguments, it could be concluded that the
performance of public enterprises should be evaluated through a basket
of indicators, that should contain physical, financial, and productivity
indicators relevant to the enterprises under consideration. A list of
selective indicators used in the present study is shown in Table 1.
4. PHYSICAL PERFORMANCE
Table 2 indicates that the growth in total electric power
generation decreased both in WAPDA and KESC during 1960-77. In the case
of WAPDA, it may be a combined effect of its early period of
establishment, a very slow progress on generation projects due to lack
of resources, and rapidly changing government policies on power
development. The same may be true for KESC except that it was already
established and was expected to perform better than WAPDA. Later, growth
in total generation increased, which may be due to commissioning of the
Terbela units and installation of new vintage steam and combine cycle
power plants at various places in the case of WAPDA, and the
establishing of a nuclear power plant outside Karachi in the case of
KESC. However, there may be various reasons for the later downward trend
in growth of power generation such as malfunctioning of nuclear power
plant, inadequate maintenance of old plants, negligible replacement of
old age plants, etc.
Although the growth in power generation was substantial during the
period under consideration (an average increase of 12 percent per
annum), the demand grew even faster and power shortage became a serious
problem, which forced the rationing of power supply. A simple reason for
this outcome may be inefficient use of available installed capacity.
Table 2 shows the generation capacity factor, (8) to analyse the
capacity utilisation in WAPDA, KESC, and power industry as a whole.
Although the generation capacity factor was well below that of WAPDA (34
percent) relative to KESC (49 percent) during 1960-55, it gradually
increased over time and went up to 54 percent during 1990-95. On the
other hand, in the case of KESC, it decreased during 1960-77, and then
increased again during 1978-95 and went up to 50 percent. However, the
average generation capacity factor for the power sector as a whole (46)
is as good as that for other developing countries such as Hong Kong (43), Malaysia (42), and the Philippines (46.9) [Ghafoor (2000), p.
170]. Therefore, shortage of electricity cannot be blamed on inefficient
use of available installed capacity. However, in the case of
electricity, the total production could be different from actual
delivery to the consumers, and this difference is called system losses.
These losses may be due to technical reasons such as unreliable and
aging generation plants, low-voltage transmission, and distribution
lines and inappropriate location of grid stations, as well as
non-technical factors such as inaccurate metering and billing, default
payments, un-metered supplies, and theft (through illegal connections).
Table 2* and Figure 1 show the total system losses (9) of WAPDA,
KESC, and the total power industry during 1960-95. In the case of WAPDA,
total system losses (10) increased from 26 to 38 percent during 1960-77.
However, these losses decreased to 23 percent during 1978-95, On the
other hand, during 1960-77, total system losses of KESC were very low
(from 17 to 22 percent) relative to WAPDA, but they gradually increased
over time and went up to 33 percent during 1990-95. Since WAPDA has the
largest share in total power industry, power industry has followed a
trend similar to WAPDA's. The average system losses (28 percent)
are, however, substantially higher than in other developing countries
such as India (19 percent), China (15 percent), the Philippines (19
percent), and Hong Kong (11 percent) [Ghafoor (2000), p. 169)].
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
5. FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE
Public enterprises are often heavily criticised for making
financial losses, which must be financed from central government
budgets, contributing to budget deficits and macro-economic instability.
Such criticisms can be misplaced in situations in which the prices that
such enterprises are allowed to charge are not allowed to rise in line
with costs. Apparently, this has not been a problem for these
enterprises in Pakistan, since neither sector has operated with
financial losses for any significant time when net profit margin on
sales was calculated before and after actual interest paid (11) (Table
3). However, net profit margin on sales was substantially decreased when
actual interest payments were included into total costs. It indicates
that a large part of investment is through borrowing and, therefore, net
profit is very sensitive to interest payments. Analysis of returns on
capital (12) is also telling a similar story (Table 4).
Financial data can be highly misleading, however, whenever markets
are distorted by controls or function poorly due to lack of information
or structural rigidities. The key to interpreting the results in Tables
3 and 4 lies in the terms on which finance was made available to the
enterprises over this period. For example, WAPDA and KESC received
grants from federal and provincial governments for specific jobs. For
instance, the Ministry of Water and Power provided funds from its
current expenditure budget for ongoing research schemes, such as the
Khanpur and Hub Dam projects. Funds for electrification projects were
provided by the respective provincial government as a grant. WAPDA also
received a continuous special grant from the Public Sector Development
Programme (a federal government scheme to finance the public sector).
Most of the local loans were either at low interest rates or were
interest-free. For instance, KESC received an interest-free loan of
Rupees 132.57 million from the federal government in 1982 for
electrification of Balochistan province. Where interest was paid, it was
very low as compared to the interest paid by private borrowers.
Moreover, there was a hidden subsidy on foreign loans. For
instance, both WAPDA and KESC repaid their loans to the Government of
Pakistan in local currency at the rate of exchange prevailing on the
respective dates of disbursement. Any inflation and the resulting
increase in debt service were paid by the government, not the
enterprises. Further, KESC also received a subsidy from the Government
of Pakistan ranging from 3.25 percent to 6.75 percent per annum on
outstanding foreign loans. This indicates that the total financial cost
of electricity supply was well below the real economic cost incurred.
(13)
It is not possible to quantify the precise impact of each
individual component of financial assistance, due to unavailability of
actual amount of grants, local and foreign loans over 36 years, and the
complications involved in their valuation. However, an approximate
indication can be obtained by using a fairly acceptable opportunity cost
of capital employed. Therefore, the actual interest rate was replaced by
a notional real annual capital charge set at 10 percent of capital
assets in a particular year. (14) In Tables 3 and 4, revised
profitability ratios are given with profit net of this notional capital
charge rather than actual interest paid. Now it can be seen that the two
power enterprises are significantly unprofitable in all years. The
implication is that in financial terms, none of the enterprises was able
to generate a surplus equal to the estimated opportunity cost of
investment funds, and that users were not charged tariffs that reflected
the true costs of supplying electric power.
Apart from a monopoly behaviour, a higher ratio of net profit
margin and net return on capital implies a better performance of a firm.
It does not mean that the firm with a lower rate of profit is
inefficient. For instance, a firm might be minimising cost for a given
output even though profits are not maximised due to price control by the
government. On the other hand, high profits do not necessarily reflect
efficient firms since the objective of profit maximisation can be
achieved by exercising monopoly power to obtain factor inputs at unduly
low prices or through selling products at higher than competitive
prices. Therefore, profitability and ratios associated with it are
ambiguous performance indicators and can be misleading if a firm
operates in a monopolistic environment or the government controls the
price of output. Since both WAPDA and KESC are monopolistic firms and
the government controls prices, high profitability before and after
actual interest paid could be criticised on the ground of high rates of
tariff, in this situation, the efficiency of firms could be examined in
two ways: first, by looking at the trend in real price of electricity
throughout the period under consideration; and, second, by examining the
unit cost of production.
Figure 2 shows that the price of electricity in the case of WAPDA
has fallen slightly in real terms in the long run. Since WAPDA and power
industry as a whole show an upward trend in net profit margin, the high
profit is unlikely to be a function of higher price. On the other hand,
the real price of KESC has increased over time because of higher fuel
adjustment charges in 1985-86. It indicates that the declining trend in
net profit margin on sale in KESC may not be due to low prices.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Regarding unit cost of production, Table 5 indicates that there is
a general downward trend in all four concepts of unit cost during the
period under consideration. (15) It is, however, important to note that
the declining trend in unit cost was faster in the case of WAPDA
relative to KESC. It is because the power system of WAPDA consists of
hydel and thermal power plants, while KESC consists of only thermal
power plants. Since, hydel power is cheaper than thermal, any increase
in hydel power will reduce the average unit cost of generation.
Historical data indicate that WAPDA started with a high proportion of
hydel power, which substantially increased during 1968-83 due to the
commissioning of Tarbela and Mangla units. Therefore, WAPDA shows a
lower cost as compared to KESC over the period under consideration.
6. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
As financial information gives only a very partial and misleading
picture of performance, it is necessary to go further and consider the
economic efficiency of the enterprises. For this purpose, we use a
production function approach to estimate the trend in growth of total
factor productivity (TFP) over the period studied. TFP should capture
the improvements in the efficiency of factor use since it reflects
growth in output that is not attributable to growth in factor inputs. We
use the following version of the Cobb-Douglas production function where
t represents time, [V.sub.t] measures real value added, [K.sub.t]
measures capital (16) input and [L.sub.t] measures labour input. (17)
[V.sub.t] = [A.sub.0]
[e.sup.[lambda]t][K.sup.[alpha].sub.t][L.sup.[beta].sub.t] ... ... ...
... ... ... (1)
where [A.sub.0] = Scale parameter. [lambda] = Growth rate of
productivity. [alpha] = Elasticity of output with respect to capital,
holding labour constant. [beta] = Elasticity of output with respect to
labour, holding capital constant. t = Time.
Since the function is non-linear, we estimate Equation (1) as,
[v.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [lambda]t + [alpha][k.sub.t] +
[beta][l.sub.t] + [e.sub.t] ... ... ... ... ... (2)
where the lower case indicates that logarithms are used. The
intercept [a.sub.0] reflects the initial level of productivity, and
[lambda] reflects growth of TFP as discussed above.
In our analysis we use real value-added, to avoid the distortion
caused by the price control policy of the government. Nominal
value-added is deflated by the price index for electricity output using
a base year of 1990. A complication arises when a function such as this
is estimated for sectors, like power, where there are discontinuous jumps in capacity, since this will disturb the underlying relationship
between factors and output. To cope with this problem, we use a dummy
variable for each jump in capacity. (18)
Hence our final version of Equation (1) for power will be,
[v.sub.t] = [a.sub.o] + [lambda]t + [[alpha]k.sub.t] +
[beta][l.sub.t] + [[gamma].sub.1][D.sub.c1] + [[gamma].sub.2][D.sub.c2]+
[e.sub.t] ... ... .... (3)
where [D.sub.c1] and [D.sub.c2] refer to dummies for each jump in
capacity for the years 1968 and 1983, respectively. Table 6 reports our
results for the power sector.
The estimated equation has performed fairly well and all parameter
estimates are statistically significant. The DW statistics are also
acceptable.
Referring to Table 6, the intercept '[a.sub.0]' provides
information about the initial level of total factor productivity, which
is negative in the case of WAPDA, while the coefficient [lambda], giving
the growth rate of total factor productivity, is positive for WAPDA.
These results indicate that although WAPDA had negative productivity
(19) at the start of the period, total factor productivity has grown at
a rate of 1.52 percent.
On the other hand since KESC was established in 1913 and working at
full capacity in 1960, a higher level of technical efficiency, and
consequently higher level of initial productivity, was expected. A
positive sign of the intercept confirms that KESC had a relatively
higher level of initial productivity than WAPDA. However, total factor
productivity has declined at a rate of -1.65 percent which indicates
that the technical efficiency of KESC has deteriorated over time. It
could be concluded that although WAPDA was relatively less efficient
than KESC in the early period of its establishment, it has performed
better in the long run, with a modest but positive growth rate of TFP.
On the other hand, KESC shows slightly higher productivity in the
earlier period, but the situation has deteriorated over time because of
a significant decline of TFP. Total factor productivity for the electric
power sector as a whole has grown, however modestly, at a rate of 0.37
percent.
Although only two firms are involved in the power sector,
inter-firm differences in the growth of TFP are confirmed through a
panel data approach, by including another dummy variable representing
inter-firm difference ([D.sub.f]) in the Equation (3) in addition to
capacity dummies. Results of the panel data approach are shown in Table
7.
The coefficient for firm dummy is negative and statistically
significant at I percent level. Since WAPDA is represented by zero and
KESC by
one, the negative sign confirms that WAPDA is technically more
efficient than KESC and these inter-firm differences are statistically
significant.
Our results also indicate increasing returns to scale. For the
power sector, the sum of the partial elasticities is greater than unity
(0.70 + 0.52 = 1.20). So far as the individual electricity companies are
concerned, WAPDA has a greater sum of partial elasticities than KESC but
both have sums greater than unity, indicating increasing returns. The
lower figure for KESC is due to a technology mix (thermal plants only as
compared to hydel and thermal for WAPDA) as well as the productivity
differences noted above.
Our economic indicator, TFP growth, gives a very different picture
of performance to the financial indicators. The results imply that only
a very low proportion of growth is due to improvements in the efficiency
of factor use. However, there is no absolute benchmark with which these
TFP results can be compared. Some sector studies have revealed
significant TFP growth in publicly owned infrastructure enterprises. For
example, Pryke (1981) estimated TFP growth of 8 percent annually for the
UK electricity sector in the period 1968-73, which is well above the
WAPDA growth of 1.4 percent. However, later work on the UK for the
period 1978-83 found a much lower TFP growth, of broadly the same rate
as that of WAPDA [Molyneux and Thompson (1987)]. (20) It may not be fair
to compare the performance of Pakistan's public enterprises with
those in developed economies, but it is reasonable to expect modest, and
positive, TFP growth from important state-run enterprises.
7. CONCLUSIONS
Our results show that although WAPDA has performed slightly better
than KESC, neither of the enterprises has done well in the long run. For
instance, in terms of financial performance, the average annual net
profit after interest, as a proportion of sale for both WAPDA (12
percent) and KESC (9 percent), is substantially lower than net profit
for the public corporation for electricity in Turkey, i.e., in the range
of 20-36 percent. (21) In terms of economic performance, TFP growth has
been negative in the case of KESC and relatively low in the case of
WAPDA, as compared to the TFP growth calculated by Pryke (1981) for the
electric power industry in the United Kingdom, i.e., 8.7 percent. This
does not confirm the case for privatisation per se, but it does indicate
the need for improvement on past performance. Therefore, the case for
reforming these enterprises is strong, and alternative modes of
organisation, finance, and ownership need to be considered.
In Pakistan, as elsewhere, there has been some discussion of ways
of involving private capital in infrastructure development activities.
(22) In the context of the power sector, most attention is given to ways
of unbundling integrated public enterprises; thus for example in power,
separating generation, transmission, and distribution, and introducing
competition between suppliers. Therefore, the issue should not be the
ownership, but rather an appropriate reform package that could suit the
specific environment for economic development of Pakistan.
REFERENCES
Adam, C., W. Cavendish, and P. Mistry (1992) Adjusting
Privatisation: Case Studies from Developing Countries. London: James
Curry.
Ali, S. (1990) Energy: Plugging in Pakistan. Far Eastern Economic
Review 148:18, 44-44.
Bhattacharyya, S. C. (1995) Power Sector Privatisation in
Developing Countries: Will it Solve All Problems? Energy Sources 17:3,
373-389.
Dawn (1997) Load Shedding, Heat Ally to Oppress Karachi. Pakistan,
The Internet Edition (May 28). (Staff Report.)
Galal, A., L. Jones, P. Yandon, and I. Vogelsang (1994) Welfare
Consequences of Selling Public Enterprises: An Empirical Analysis. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Ghafoor, A. (2000) Public Infrastructure Performance in Developing
Countries: The Case of Electric Power and Telecommunications Industries
in Pakistan. England: Ashgate Publishing Limited.
Humplick, F. (1993) Does Multiplicity Matter More than Ownership in
the Efficiency of Infrastructure Services? Paper prepared for conference
on: Infrastructure Economic Growth and Regional Development: The Case of
Industrialised High Income Countries. Jonkoping, Sweden (June 10-12).
Jenkins, G. P., and M. H. Lahouel (1983) Evaluation of Performance
of Industrial Public Enterprises: Criteria and Policies. Industry and
Development 7, 13-23.
Karata, C. (1995) Has Privatisation Improved Profitability and
Performance of Public Enterprises in Turkey? In P. Cook, and C.
Kirkpatrik (eds) Privatisation Policy and Performance: International
Perspectives. London: Prentice Hall.
Malhotra, A. K., O. Koenig, and P. Sinsukprasert (1994) A Survey of
Asia's Energy Prices. The World Bank, Washington, D. C. (Technical
Paper No. 248.)
Mann, P. C. (1970) Publicly Owned Electric Utility Profit and
Resource Allocation. Land Economies 46, 478-483.
Meyer, R. A. (1975) Publicly Owned Versus Privately Owned
Utilities: A Policy Choice. Review of Economics and Statistics 24, 1-14.
Millward, R., and D. M. Parker (1983) Public and Private
Enterprises: Comparative Behaviour and Relative Efficiency. In R.
Millward, et al. Public Sector Economics. London: Longman.
Molyneux, R., and D. Thompson (1987) National Industry Performance:
Still Third-rate. Fiscal Studies 8:1, 48-82.
Naqvi, S. N. H., and A. R. Kemal (1991) The Privatisation of the
Public Industrial Enterprises in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development
Review 30:2, 105-144.
OECD (1990) Performance Indicators for Public Telecommunications
Operators. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development.
Parsons, J. (1980) Profitability Analysis in Inters Firm
Comparison: A New Approach. In D. Bailey and Y. Hubert (eds)
Productivity Measurement. An International Review of Concepts,
Techniques, Programmes and Current Issues. Hants: Gower Publishing
Company Limited.
Pasha, H. A., and M. Gellerson (1988) Study of Financial Aid and
Economic Impact of Power Interruption and Load-shedding. Karachi:
University of Karachi.
Peltzman, S. (1971) Probing in Public and Private Enterprises and
Electric Utilities in the United States. Journal of Law and Economics 4,
109-147.
Pryke, R. (1981) The Nationalised Industries : Policies and
Performance since 1968. Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Sarma, A. (1995) Performance of Public Enterprises in India. In D.
Mookherjee (ed.) Indian Industry: Policies and Performance. Bombay:
Oxford University Press.
Tenenbaum, B., R. Lock, and J. Barker (1992) Electricity
Privatisation--Structural, Competitive and Regulatory Options. Energy
Policy 20:12, 1134-1160.
USAID (1988) Power Shortage in Developing Countries: Magnitude,
Impacts, Solutions and the Role of Private Sector. USAID Report to
Congress.
Weiss, J. (1980) Practical Appraisal of Industrial Project:
Application of Social Cost Benefit Analysis in Pakistan. New York:
United Nations.
World Bank (1994) World Development Report: Infrastructure for
Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
World Bank (1995) Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and
Policies of Government Ownership. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ziauddin, M. (1997) Excessive WAPDA Staffing Cause of Tariff Hikes.
Dawn, The Internet Edition (12 May).
(1) Data cited here come primarily from the published reports of
the companies. For lull intbrmation on the sources, see [Ghatbor (2000),
p 223.]
(2)The real prices are calculated on the basis of year 1990.
(3) Loadshedding means rationing of electricity at the time of
shortage.
(4) The variation among these results might be due to various units
and different methodologies. It is, however, clear that in the past
loadshedding had caused a serious damage to the economy. 5Literature
also uses the word "unbundling".
(5)Literature also uses the word "unbundling".
(6)Such as income distribution, industrial development, employment,
etc
(7) For a detailed discussion on the subject, see Mann (1970):
Peltzman (1971); Meyer (1975): Parsons (1980); Galal, et al (1994);
World Bank (1995) and Sarma (1995).
(8) Generation capacity factor is expressed as tbllows [Humplick
(1993)]. Generation Capacity Factor = [Annual Gross Output (MWh) /
Annual Installed Capacity (MW) x 8760] x 100. Where. 8760 are total
number of hours in a year of 365 days.
(9) Total systern losses include auxiliary (the amount of
electricity used with the generation process), transmission and
distribution losses. "Tables tbllow the main text and References.
(10) Total production could be different from actual delivery to
the consumers and the difference between two two is called system
losses. These are expressed in percentage terms and defined as the
difference between total production and actual delivery as a proportion
of total production [Humplick (1993)].
(11) The most familiar concept of financial profit measures, the
ratio of net profit (difference between total revenue and total cost) on
sale, has been used in this study. Total revenue includes the revenue on
sale of electricity and other operating revenue such as meter rent, late
payment, other surcharges, etc., and total cost includes cost of
generation (fuel cost, depreciation), transmission cost, distribution
costs (selling, administration, research and development) and interest
payments. Furthermore, net profit margin on sale has been calculated
both before and alter interest to demonstrate the significance of
interest payments.
(12) A detailed discussion on how the capital was calculated in
this study has been made in the next section, under productivity
analysis.
(13) It, however, can be said with assurance that in either case,
whether it is grant for a specific project or subsidies on foreign or
local loan. the sum entered the capital stock figure.
(14) In an earlier study, Weiss (1980) also estimated a similar
opportunity cost of capital of 10 percent for Pakistan in the late
1970s.
(15) Since public managers do not have any control over interest
and fuel price, evaluation of their performance would be misleading by
including these costs. Therefore, a concept of controllable cost has
been included in this study which measures the performance of sate-owned
enterprises by looking at cost without interest and fuel cost
(16) The series for capital are generated with the help of the
formula, i.e., [K.sub.t] = [K.sub.t-1] + ([delta][K.sub.t]), where
[K.sub.t-1] is initial level of capital (which was total assets alter
depreciation) and [delta][K.sub.t] represent the change in capital in
current year {(Net Fixed Assets +Work in Progress)--Depreciation] +
Working Capital {(Current Assets--Current Liabilities)}. All figures
have been calculated on the basis of constant price of 1990 by using
consumer price index.
(17) Labour is the total number of employees in a firm as given by
the Annual Reports of these firms. Some economists believe that the
number of employees at a given time-period is not a good variable since
it does not take into account the quality of individual worker.
Therefore, a better measure such as the weighted cost of labour
according to their wages should be used. It can be argued that the main
objective of such study is not to estimate the productivity of
individual worker but an average productivity of the whole labour force
working in a firm. Furthermore, the wage system in Pakistan is very
complex and it is hardly mentioned in the published material on
individual basis. Moreover, pay scales are revised by the Government of
Pakistan from time to time and it is very hard to find such detailed
information for 35 years. It is also believed that the salary does not
reflect the true picture of labour quality. Therefore, we decided to use
the number of workers, which seems to be a better measure in this
situation. However, since the quality of labour did improve during the
study period, our productivity growth would be slightly upward-biased.
(18) In the case of WAPDA, the first jump was caused by the
commissioning of 6 units of Mangla Dam during 1968. It added 600 MW to
the total generating capacity which increased growth in power generation
from 4 percent to 19 percent. A second jurnp was due to the
commissioning of 4 units of Terbela Dam and two more units of Mangla
Dam, which added 960 MW to the total installed capacity and increased
the growth in power generation to 33 percent in 1983. In the case of
KESC, there was only one large jump during 1985 due to the commissioning
of Bin Qasirn thermal power plant of 420 MW capacity, which increased
the growth in electric power from 17 percent to 24 percent. Since these
additions caused a large increased in installed capacity, it would
certainly lower the measured productivity in the short run. These
dummies have been used to neutralise this disturbing effect which is
assumed to last for just one year.
(19) In constant growth models, as used in this study, the
intercept estimates the real value of the value-added in the initial
year. It means that in our case the value-added was negative in 1960,
with inputs and outputs valued at 1990 prices. There could be several
reasons for this outcome. The main reason may be that WAPDA was in its
development stage, where the cost of production was always higher than
the revenue because most of generation plants were not working at lull
capacity. Therefore, output was relatively well below input costs.
(20) The variations among these studies may be due to various
time-periods and methodologies used. It is, however, important to note
that the performance of public enterprises has deteriorated in the long
run.
(21) Karata (1995).
(22) Tenenbaum, et al. (1992) and Bhattacharyya (1995) discuss
alternative models for power sector reform.
ABDUL GHAFOOR and JOHN WEISS
Abdul Ghafoor is Associate Professor/Director, Institute of Social
Sciences, and Acting Dean, Faculty of Communications, Cyprus
International University, Lefkosa, Mersin 10, Turkey. John Weiss is
Professor of Development Economics at the Bradford Centre for
International Development, University of Bradford, UK.
Table 1
Selective /indicators to Evaluate the Performance of Public Electric
Power Industry in Pakistan
Group Indicators
Physical Growth in Physical Output
System Losses
Generation Capacity Factor
Financial Net Profit Margin on Sale
Return on Capital
Unit Cost of Production
Productivity Labour Productivity
Capital Productivity
Growth in Total Factor Productivity
Source: Data and other information were obtained from published
material of relevant enterprises and from The Planning Commission of
Pakistan. These included Annual Reports, Power System Statistics,
Five-Year Development Plans, etc. For dull information on sources,
see [Ghafoor (2000), p. 223.]
Table 2
Selected Physical Indicators for Eral:rating the Performance of
State-omned Electric Power Indarstry in Pakistan (/961-95)
Growth in Power Generation System Losses
Years WAPDA KESC Power WAPDA KESC Power
19605 26 17 24 26 17 24
1966-71 15 14 15 31 19 28
1972-77 7 4 7 34 22 32
1978-83 12 9 12 32 23 31
1984-89 10 12 10 26 26 26
1990-95 8 5 8 23 33 26
Average 13 10 12 29 33 28
Generation Capacity Factor
Years WAPDA KESC Power
19605 34 47 36
1966-71 45 42 44
1972-77 46 42 45
1978-83 50 48 48
1984-89 52 50 50
1990-95 54 50 52
Average 47 47 46
Table 3
Various Concepts of Net Profrt Margin on Sale of State-owned Electric
Poiver Industry in Pakistan (1960-95)
Net Profit Margin on Net Profit Margin
Sale before on Sale after
Interest Interest (Actual)
(%) (%)
Years WAPDA KESC Power WAPDA KESC Power
1960-65 31.49 29.94 34.33 5.680 20.37 13.96
1966-71 34.98 26.40 35.17 4.510 19.24 10.71
1972-77 26.15 8.20 25.28 -1.32 -0.38 1.50
1978-83 48.72 18.09 42.85 29.86 9.31 25.93
1984-89 33.46 17.01 31.77 15.54 5.27 14.82
1990-95 39.40 13.74 36.29 19.93 0.07 17.53
Net Profit Margin on Sale after 10
Percent Opportunity Cost on Capital
(%)
Years WAPDA KESC Power
1960-65 65.26 -29.28 -51.85
1966-71 -63.61 -36.25 -52.75
1972-77 -98.94 -88.58 -90.66
1978-83 -2.34 -5.65 64.21
1984-89 -37.38 -50.65 -35.90
1990-95 -26.43 -34.95 -28.88
Table 4 Y
Various Concepts of Return on Capital of State-oinned Electric Power
Industry in Pakistan (1960-95)
Return on Capital
Return on Capital before after Interest
interest (Actual)
Years WAPDA KESC Power WAPDA KESC Power
1960-65 3.34 4.89 4.06 0.65 1.84 1.69
1966-71 3.57 4.51 4.02 0.47 0.96 1.23
1972-77 2.16 1.49 2.28 -0.05 -0.23 0.21
1978-83 5.52 3.76 5.06 3.45 1.51 3.11
1984-89 4.80 3.29 4.73 2.26 0.19 2.33
1990-95 6.02 2.83 5.60 3.05 0.05 2.71
Return on Capital after 10 Percent
Opportunity Cost on Capital
Years WAPDA KESC Power
1960-65 6.66 -2.93 -5.94
1966-71 6.43 -6.21 -5.98
1972-77 -7.84 -8.11 -7.72
1978-83 6.48 -1.28 -4-94
1984-89 -5.20 -5.91 -5.27
1990-95 -3.98 -5.17 4.40
Table 5
Various Concepts of Unit Cost of Production (Rupees) of State-otrned
Electric Poorer lradusny in Pakistan (1960-95)
Unit Cost before Fuel Cost Unit Cost before
and Interest Interest
Years WAPDA KESC Power WAPDA KESC Power
19605 0.42 0.52 0.45 0.53 2.15 0.56
1966-71 0.26 0.38 0.27 0.38 1.63 0.40
1972-77 0.24 0.45 0.26 0.33 1.46 0.36
1978-83 0.24 0.36 0.26 0.33 0.78 0.39
1984-89 0.27 0.42 0.29 0.48 0.75 0.52
1990-95 0.24 0.37 0.25 0.47 0.59 0.51
Average 0.28 0.42 0.29 0.42 1.23 0.45
Unit Cost after Actual Unit Cost after 10 Percent
Interest Paid Opportunity Cost of
Years WAPDA KESC Power WAPDA KESC Power
19605 0.73 2.21 0.77 1.29 2.67 1.31
1966-71 0.56 1.68 0.57 0.95 1.99 0.96
1972-77 0.46 1.53 0.48 0.90 1.95 0.92
1978-83 0.45 0.85 0.50 0.91 1.25 0.96
1984-89 0.61 0.87 0.65 0.99 1.24 1.04
1990-95 0.63 0.72 0.66 1.00 1.07 1.03
Average 0.57 1.31 0.60 1.01 1.70 1.04
Table 6
Parameter Estimates of Electric Power /ndtrstries in Pakistan Using
Cobb-Dotrglas Prodtrctiort Ftutction
Parameters WAPDA KESC Power Sector
[a.sub.o] -2.0418 3.1228 -2.1124
(-3.49) ** (3.67) ** (-2.39) *
[lambda] 0.0152 -0.0165 0.0037
(3.21) ** (-3.33) ** (3.18) **
[alpha] 0.6829 0.8119 0.6948
(3.97) ** (3.92) ** (3.58) **
[beta] 0.5421 0.2107 0.5224
(4.10) ** (3.21) ** (3.61) *
[gamma].sub.1] 0.1443 0.3061 0.1481
(4.04) ** (3.01) ** (2.27) *
[gamma].sub.1] 0.1719 -- 0.1248
(2.47) * (3.19) **
Adj. [R.sup.2] 0.57 0.59 0.62
DW 1.87 1.82 1.69
Figures in the parenthesis are t values.
* The coeficients are signifcant at 5 percent level.
** The coefficients are significant at 1 percent level.
Table 7
Parameter Estimates, Using Cobb-Douglas Production Frnrction
with Parcel Data
Parameters Coefficients
[a.sub.o] -3.2457
0.0039
(3.41) **
[lambda] 0.7981
(4.30) **
[alpha] 0.5526
(3.94) *
[beta] 0.1928
(3.99) **
[gamma].sub.1] 0.1134
(3.91) **
[gamma].sub.3] 0.0349
(3.01) **
[D.sub.f] -0.0941
[R.sup.2] 0.65
DW 1.80
Figures in the parenthesis are t values.
* The coefficients are significant at 5 percent level.
** The coefficients are significant at 1 percent level.