Debt and economic growth in South Asia.
Siddiqui, Rehana ; Malik, Afia
INTRODUCTION
After 1980s, in most developing countries, the rate of debt
accumulation and increase in debt servicing are highlighted as major
factors affecting the growth rate of output. Most of these countries
lost their competitiveness in the international market mainly as a
result of insufficient exchange rate adjustments. In addition, the
weakening of terms of trade, economic mismanagement and crisis of
governance also lowered growth rates in the developing countries. The
downward pressure was larger in the countries facing higher debt burden
as these countries faced higher interest rates, decline in the external
resource inflow, lower export earnings, lower domestic output and lower
imports.
In case of South Asian countries, the external debt scenario has
changed over time. According to World Bank (2001) Pakistan's
ranking worsened to 'severely-indebted low income country'
from 'moderately-indebted low income country' in 1997, where
as India's ranking improved to 'less indebted low income'
country from 'moderately indebted' in 1997. The rapid
accumulation of debt, rising repayment burden and the economically and
politically resource inflow or rescheduling motivated rescheduling of
debt (as in case of Pakistan) has raised concerns regarding the impact
of debt on the growth process of the South Asian countries.
Khanobis and Bari (2001) claim that foreign resource inflow
increased the resource availability and as a result it contributed to
economic growth in South Asia. However, the study does not examine the
effect of debt accumulation on economic growth. In this paper, given the
diversity of growth experience, we examine the impact of rising debt
burden on economic growth of South Asian countries.
In 1960s, the role of foreign resource inflow was to reduce the gap
between the domestic availability and the needs of the developing
countries. A higher fraction of this resource inflow was in the form of
bilateral and multilateral Aids and Grants. Over time the declining
resource availability and changing composition of resource inflow, i.e.,
a rising share of commercial loan of short term maturity at a higher
interest rate and declining share of concessional debt in total has
increased the debt burden and deteriorated the debt servicing capacity
of most of the developing countries, including Pakistan. (see Table 1).
The situation is worse for those countries where the net resource inflow
became negative. (1)
The empirical literature indicates that the critical ratios that
can be helpful in determining the debt burden of the countries include
debt-to-export ratio, debt-to-output (i.e., output can be measured
either in terms of gross domestic product or gross national product),
and the ratio of debt servicing to export or output. If for a country
these ratios are larger than the critical values, the impact of debt on
the country's growth may become negative. For example, Pattillo,
Poirson and Ricci (2001), report that average impact of debt on economic
growth becomes negative when debt-to-export ratio is around 160-170
percent and debt-to-output ratio is around 35-40 percent. (2) Comparing
these ratios for South Asian countries, we can see large variations. For
example, in Sri Lanka, in 1990s, the debt-to-GNP ratio was above these
critical levels (> 50 percent) but due to a large external sector,
the debt-to-export ratio was, on average, below 170 percent. For
Pakistan, in 1990s, both ratios are above the critical level and show a
rising trend. For India, the debt-to-output ratio is below the critical
level but the debt-to-export ratio was above the critical values but it
shows a declining trend in 1990s. (see Table 1.) Thus, the debt
situation in South Asia has changed and it is becoming critical for some
countries. As a result, it may generate negative impact on economic
growth.
Keeping this in view, we examine the impact of external debt on
economic growth in South Asian countries. The presence of these critical
ratios implies that if the ratios are below the critical level the
impact on growth may not be negative. This raises the second of
nonlinearity in debt-growth relationship. In this paper, we examine the
debt-growth relationship for South Asian countries and test if there are
nonlinearities in this relationship. If so, then, at what level the
impact of external debt on economic growth becomes negative?
The study is organised as follows: Section 2 discusses the growth
experience of selected South Asian countries briefly. (3) An over view
of recent theoretical and empirical developments is in Section 3. The
model developed for the study and data issues are discussed in Section
4. The results are discussed in Section 5. Conclusions and policy
implications are discussed in Section 6.
2. GROWTH EXPERIENCE OF SOUTH ASIAN COUNTRIES
Growth experience of South Asian countries varied significantly
over time. Table 2 shows that growth rate of GDP-per capita varied
between 2.4 percent and 3.5 percent per annum during 1976-1997. Table 2
shows that, for the period 1976-1997, highest growth rate of GDP per
capita was experienced by Sri Lanka (equaling 3.46 percent) and lowest
was in Pakistan (equaling 2.36 percent). This shows that despite the
rapid growth experience in 1960s and 1980s, Pakistan was not able to
keep the growth momentum. This is also reflected in higher coefficient
of variation indicating higher instability in the growth experience of
Pakistan. Capital stock and labour force growth rate are the primary
sources of growth. Population growth, a proxy for labour force growth
rate, was highest in Pakistan whereas the investment-gdp (invgdp) ratio
(a proxy for capital accumulation) was lowest for Pakistan. The
indicators of creditworthiness, i.e., debt-service-to-GDP ratio and
debt-service-to-exports ratio also show a lower ranking of Pakistan.
Thus, in case of Pakistan, higher population growth, lower rate of
capital formation, and higher rate of debt accumulation may be the main
reasons for slow down in economic growth during 1990s. (see Table 1 and
Table 2.)
The studies analysing sources of growth identify that schooling,
openness, strength of institutions and government spending, the major
contributors to economic growth in East Asia, are also important for
South Asia, but the South Asian countries are lagging in growth and
improvement of these factors.
In South Asian countries, total factor productivity growth, a
measure of improvements in competitiveness, was high in 1960s, declined
in 1970s and improves afterwards. In case of Bangladesh, as expected,
growth was slow in 1970s but improved afterwards. In India, the
contribution of capital in economic growth is quite high and growth
performance improved steadily over time. However, in the growth
experience of Pakistan shows significant fluctuations over time. In Sri
Lanka, growth was low but stable and capital was the major contributor.
According to Khanobus and Bari (2000), capital accumulation and total
factor productivity (TFP) growth are the major sources of economic
growth. The rise in TFP seems to coincide with the period of
liberalisation in most of the South Asian countries. India and
Bangladesh show higher TFP growth. In Pakistan TFP growth was
significant until 1980s but has deteriorated in 1990s. In 1980s, India
benefited from domestic policy changes as well as a large expanding
domestic market and good harvests offsetting the negative impact of
fluctuations in the global economy.
An interesting finding of the study, by Khanobus and Bari (2000),
is positive contribution of black economy to growth. The argument given
is that presence of black market partly bypass regulations and controls
and work more like a free market, thus affecting growth positively.
Thus, this effect should decline as the economies are liberalised and
deregulated. Other factors, affecting economic growth in South Asia are
open foreign investment regimes, natural resource endowment, less
controls on wages and prices and institutional strength.
Tendulkar and Sen (2000), find that exchange rate mismanagement and
market rigidities can also be blamed for slower growth in South Asia,
relative to East Asia. They argue that, "... product market
distortions emerging from restrictive trade and exchange rate policies
under centrally initiated and public sector oriented industrialisation
constituted the major causal factors behind the slow pace of growth in
South Asian countries. Recent wave of liberalisation, even though crisis
driven, can be growth promoting if adopted with commitment".
3. THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL BACKGROUND
There is no consensus in theoretical and empirical literature about
the debt-growth relationship. In neoclassical growth models perfect
capital mobility improves economic growth. Whereas, the recent
endogenous growth models argue that rising cost of foreign capital
inflow reduces external borrowing causing a decline in long run economic
growth.
Recent studies dealing with the issue of external resource inflow
and economic growth also argue that a more realistic assumption is that
countries may not be able to borrow freely because of the risk of
repudiation or moral hazard. Cohen (1993) included repudiation risk in
the analysis and found low level of debt associated with higher growth
(not under financial autarky) where as large levels of accumulated debt
stocks leads to lower economic growth. If the borrowing country can hide
its actions from the lender it may choose to consume or re-invest abroad
some of the borrowed funds.
Similar model developed by Cohen and Sachs (1986) seems to fit well
with the experiences of most of the developing countries. (4) The model
shows that, with a possibility of debt repudiation and endogenous growth
ceiling, there would be two stages of economic growth. In the first
stage the growth rate of external capital inflow will be higher then the
output growth rate. But in the second phase, the resource inflow and
growth, both will slow down. Along this path the debt servicing will not
be complete, and permanent refinancing of debt servicing will be the
only equilibrium strategy consistent with no default by the borrowing
country. The refinancing should be linked to output growth of the
country.
The literature also emphasises that political economy
considerations leading to over-borrowing resulting in capital flight may
retard the growth prospects of the borrowing country, if the costs of
high taxes to service the debt are not internalised. The debt-overhang
theories imply that if debt is greater than the country's repayment
ability and the expected debt servicing is an increasing function of
output then returns from investment in the country face a marginal tax
by the external creditors, and new domestic and foreign investment is
discouraged. Thus, large stock of debt reduces growth by lowering
investment.
According to Cohen (1993), capital accumulation is the sole
contributor to economic growth and the impact of external resource flow
is not linear. The study emphasise that the impact of debt on economic
growth depends significantly on capital flight, since the high
distortionery tax burden on capital is required for debt-servicing,
lowering the return on capital, and lowering investment and growth. Low
levels of debt leads to opposite results and in the intermediate range
the effect on growth is indeterminate. This creates a possibility of
multiple equilibria as a result of non-linear relationship between debt
and economic growth. Thus, debt can lead to positive/negative impact on
economic growth, crowding out of investment or debt over-hang effect.
Another channel is that any activity incurring costs today for the
sake of increased output in the future will be discouraged as part of
the proceeds will be taxed away by creditors. Thus, government will have
less incentive to undertake difficult reforms such as trade
liberalisation or fiscal adjustment impling that debt-overhang effect
will not only work through lower investment but also through a weak
macroeconomic policy environment. This, in turn, affects the efficiency
of investment, i.e., if expectation is that debt-servicing will be
through distortionary taxation, such as inflation tax, or with cuts in
productive public investment then it will reduce the efficiency of
investment.
Uncertainty regarding the source of debt servicing, and probability
of rescheduling increases the risk regarding the growth prospects of a
country. In this situation, even if fundamentals are improving,
investors will continue to exercise their option of waiting. Investment
in risky environment will be in trading activities with quick returns,
rather than in long-term, high-risk, irreversible investment that will
also affect the efficiency of investment. All this implies that
reasonable levels of debt have a positive impact on economic growth and
a large stock of debt may be a constraint on economic growth.
The debt over-hang effect can also be captured by burden of future
debt services. It takes not the face value of debt but net present value
of debt (NPVD) reflecting the degree of concessionality of loans and
thus more accurately measure the expected burden of future
debt-servicing across countries. For many developing countries, the
extra earnings and rescheduling of existing debt led to an increase in
domestic output and imports since 1980s and 1990s. However, all major
credit worthiness indicators deteriorated in 1980s resulting in to
reduction in resource availability to the developing countries and
difficulty in debt servicing. This forced the affected countries to opt
for the stabilisation programme leading to domestic policy adjustment to
reduce fiscal deficit, exchange rate misalignment, rationalisation of
taxation structure and reduction in government spending. In response to
growing debt problems of the developing countries, rescheduling
agreements also increased after the debt crisis of Latin America.
These developments created an interest in the empirical analysis of
debt-growth relationship. However, according to White (1992), before
answering the question whether aid (foreign resource inflow) affects
economic growth?--there is still a need to develop theoretical
understanding of aid's impact on savings further and develop better
econometric methodology. The studies examining the debt-growth or the
external resource inflow and growth relationship for developing
countries show that slower growth in world trade, weak/declining prices
of export, declining resource inflow with large repayment obligations on
debt, particularly on external debt, have affected the economic growth
after the decade of 1980s.
Using the data for 93 developing countries for the period 1968-98,
Pottillo, et al., (2001) find that the nonlinear impact of debt on
economic growth is through the impact on total factor productivity not
through the impact on efficiency of capital. The result of the study
suggest that average impact of debt on economic growth becomes negative
when debt is at about 160-170 percent of export-earnings or 35-40
percent of gross domestic product. The marginal impact of debt starts
becoming negative at about half of these values. High debt reduces
economic growth mainly by lowering the efficiency of investment rather
than its volume. This implies that negative effect works through decline
in total factor productivity not through reduction in contribution of
capital. Similarly Chawdhury (2001) finds that debt servicing as a
percentage of either export earnings or GDP affect growth rate of GDP
per capita adversely. This effect is equally important and statistically
significant for HIPCs and other developing countries facing heavy debt
burden.
Thus, whereas the theoretical literature develops the argument for
an adverse impact of foreign resource inflow on economic growth, the
empirical literature estimates these relationships showing that the
relationship may be negative and nonlinear in all the developing
countries, including HIPCs and others.
4. MODEL AND DATA ISSUES
In this paper we examine the impact of various indicators of debt
burden on the economic growth of South Asian countries. We also examine,
whether this relationship is linear or not. For estimation, the model is
specified as:
[G.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.I] + [[gamma].sub.t] + [SIGMA]
[[beta].sub.j] [X.sub.itj] + [SIGMA] [[delta].sub.k] [X.sub.itk] + [mu]
Where:
G = growth rate of gross domestic product per capita.
[X.sub.j] = set of j conditioning variables. It includes:
[X.sub.l] - investment-GDP ratio.
[X.sub.2] = Deficit-GDP ratio.
[X.sub.3] = indicator of external competitiveness, measured as
Trade-to-GDP ratio or the growth rate of exports or the growth rate of
import or terms of trade.
[X.sub.4] = population growth rate.
[X.sub.5] = log of lagged GDP.
[X.sub.k] = set of k variables measuring debt burden. It includes:
[X.sub.6] = Foreign Debt-to-GDP ratio.
[X.sub.7] = Foreign Debt-to-GDP squared.
[X.sub.8] = Debt servicing-to-Export ratio.
[X.sub.9] = Debt servicing-to-Export ratio squared.
[X.sub.10] = Foreign Debt-to-Exports.
[X.sub.11] = Foreign Debt-to-Exports squared.
[[alpha].sub.I] controls for the country-specific fixed effects,
[[gamma].sub.t] controls for time-specific fixed effects, [[beta].sub.j]
are the coefficients of the first five conditioning variables,
[[delta].sub.k] are the coefficients of six variables measuring debt
burden and finally [mu] is the random error term. The impact of
debt-burden is captured by including various indicators, [X.sub.6] ....
[X.sub.11]. The coefficients may be positive or negative. However, if
the relationship is nonlinear then we expect the coefficient of the
squared-term to be negative. This will support the view that the
positive impact of the resource inflow becomes negative after a
threshold level of debt burden is reached.
The set of conditioning variables includes investment-GDP ratio,
deficit-GDP ratio, openness, population growth rate, and log of lagged
GDP-per capita. The effect of investment-GDP ratio is expected to be
positive and statistically significant. The impact of deficit-GDP ratio
is expected to be negative if deficit crowds-out public saving and
resource inflow encourages corruption and resource outflow. The impact
of openness is expected to be positive as the rise in trade flows
relative to GDP represents improved competitiveness and productivity of
the economy. The effect of population growth will be negative if the
population is bottleneck to the growth process and it lowers the
productivity in the economy. The coefficient of log of lagged output per
capita is expected to be negative to support the convergence hypothesis.
The growth model is estimated using the data for three South Asian
countries, viz., Sri Lanka, Pakistan, and India. In order to capture the
effect of country-specific factors, most studies using panel data apply
Fixed Effects/Random Effects models. In this study, we estimate the
equations by applying OLS and Fixed Effects Models. The implication is
to control the country specific effects in the data. Country dummies are
used for the three countries included in the analysis. These dummies are
not correlated with other independent variables, but have constant or
fixed effect on the dependent variable that is on the per capita growth.
The advantage of using the technique is that by employing the
conventional tests we can see whether the same regression applies to all
data points or not.
The data sources for the study are "International Financial
Statistics Yearbook-2000" published by International Monetary Fund,
"Global Development Finance-2001" and "World Debt
Tables" (various issues), published by the World Bank. The time
period covered is 1975-98. Furthermore, in order to reduce the impact of
cyclical fluctuations, we have computed three years moving of all the
variables.
5. RESULTS
A number of equations are estimated with same control variables and
alternative variables representing debt burden. However, we report only
those equations which include the variables found consistently
significant. Furthermore, the comparison of estimated coefficients of
the growth equations with and without adjustment for the
country-specific fixed effects, show that the results improve
significantly, if we control for the presence of country-specific
effects. Therefore, we are reporting the results of Fixed Effect model
only.
The results of estimated equations are reported in Table 3. The
coefficients of all the conditioning variables have expected signs. The
impact of conditioning variables, like investment-GDP ratio, defi-GDP
ratio, openness, population growth and lagged GDP per capita (in log)
have expected signs and they are statistically significant, except for
defi-GDP ratio. The sign of the coefficient of defi-GDP is negative in
most equations and it is not statically significant. The impact of
investment-GDP ratio is positive and statistically significant,
supporting the findings of the earlier studies that capital formation is
the main source of economic growth. Furthermore, the coefficient is
quite robust in different estimated equation.
As expected, openness has a positive and statistically significant
impact on economic growth. The impact of population growth is negative,
as expected, and statistically significant. The result shows that rise
in population affect the productivity adversely. This calls for
improving the effectiveness of the population programmes in the South
Asian countries. The coefficient of lagged GDP is negative, as expected,
and statistically significant, supporting the convergence hypothesis.
However, surprisingly, the impact of foreign debt on economic
growth is positive and statistically significant. The coefficient of the
squared term is not statistically significant, except in the second and
the last equation, but in all the equations its presence improves the
significance of the variables indicating the debt burden. Interestingly
the results of the other indicators of debt burden, i.e.,
debt-servicing-to-exports ratio and debt-to-export ratio support the
results of the second equation. We also find that rise in debt servicing
affects the contribution of investment, but the impact of other
variables, indicating debt burden, does not seem to affect the
contribution of investment rate in economic growth. The results also
support the findings of earlier studies, like the study by Pottillo, et
al. (2001), partially.
The results show that the coefficient of squared terms for debt
indicators are statistically significant in two equations. The exclusion
of these terms affects the coefficient of debt indicators adversely, in
the other equations also. Thus, we conclude that our result support the
presence of a nonlinear relationship between economic growth and all the
indicators of debt burden. The comparison of computed critical values of
debt-to-GDP, debt servicing-to-exports and debt-to-exports, based on the
results reported in Table 3, with the ratios reported in Table 1, shows
that in most cases, the impact on economic growth in Pakistan is
expected to be negative whereas for the other two countries these ratios
are below the critical levels. (see Table 4.) This has important
implications for the countries in South Asian region, particularly for
Pakistan. (5)
6. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The results of this study support, partially, the findings of
Pottillo, et al. (2001) and other earlier studies that ignoring the
nonlinearities in the growth-debt relationship and the presence of
country-specific fixed effects can lead to biased coefficient estimates
and consequently wrong policies for a region or a specific country. All
the indicators of debt burden, included in the study, highlight the
importance of improving the economic management. This could be in the
form of improving the efficiency of the resource use so that the debt
burden can be effectively reduced. In case of Pakistan, all the debt
indicators increased sharply in the 1990s, whereas for Sri Lanka the
debt-export ratio has not crossed the critical levels and for India the
ratio is declining.
The effect of population growth is productivity reducing. This
effect can be controlled by reducing population growth rate and by
improving human capital. We have not included the variable of human
capital in the analysis due to non availability of comparable time
series data across countries. Furthermore, earlier studies like
Guhu-Khanobus and Bari (2000) find insignificant impact of education
(measured by enrolment) claiming that the quality, not quantity, is
important to capture the effect of human capital on economic growth.
In case of Pakistan, mismanagement of resources, macro imbalances,
loss of competitiveness in the international market and the role of
political interest groups has aggravated the debt burden. There is a
need to improve the competitiveness of the economy and to improve the
macro imbalances.
Given the rising debt burden, particularly for Pakistan, it is
critical to reduce dependence on foreign aid. This requires efforts to
mobilise domestic resources. For example, Kemal (1975) suggests that,
"The elimination of aid flows within a reasonable time period
implies increasing the marginal rate of saving and lowering capital
intensity either through the adoption of less capital-intensive
techniques or by changing the sectoral compositions of investment
towards sectors with lower capital-output ratios". Furthermore,
there is need to provide conducive macroeconomic environment by reducing
mismanagement and by improving governance to promote economic growth.
REFERENCES
Chawdhury, A. R. (2001) Foreign Debt and Growth in Developing
Countries: A Sensitivity and Causality Analysis Using Panel Data.
Milwaukee, Department of Economics, Marquette University, USA.
Cohen, D. (1993) Low Investment and Large LDC Debt in the 1980s.
American Economic Review 83:3, 437-449.
Cohen, D., and J. Sachs (1986) Growth, and External Debt Under Risk
of Debt Repudiation. European Economic Review 30:3, 529-560.
Guhu-Khanobus, B., and F. Bari (2000) Sources of Growth in South
Asian Countries. Unpublished Study Prepared for Global Research Project
of World Bank.
IMF (2000) International Financial Statistics. Washington, D. C.:
International Monetary Fund.
Kemal, A. R. (1975) Eliminating Dependence on Foreign Aid--Some
Policy Implications. The Pakistan Development Review 14:4, 381-396.
Pottillo, Poirson, and Ricci (2001) External Debt and Growth.
Unpublished Paper prepared for International Monetary Fund. (August).
Tendulkar, S., and B. Sen (2000) Markets and Economic Growth in
South Asia, 1950-97: An Interpretation. Unpublished Study Prepared for
Global Research Project of World Bank.
White, H. (1992) What Do We Know About Aid's Macroeconomic
Impact? An Overview of the Aid Effectiveness Debate. Journal of
International Development 4:2, 121-137.
World Bank (Various Issues) Global Development Finance. Washington,
D.C.
World Bank (Various Issues) Worm Debt Tables. Washington, D.C.
The comments on the paper were not received in lime for press. Ed.
(1) In Pakistan, the net inflow of resources was negative in 1997
and 1999-2000.
(2) According to World Bank the critical value of debt-to-GDP is 80
percent and critical value of debt-to-export earnings is 220 percent.
According to both sets of estimates of critical values, Pakistan is
categorised as heavily indebted low income country.
(3) We include, Sri Lanka, Pakistan and India in the analysis.
Other South Asian countries are excluded due to incomplete information.
(4) The model seems to explain the debt situation of Pakistan.
(5) The study reports mixed evidence regarding the impact of debt
burden on economic growth.
Rehana Siddiqui and Afia Malik are Senior Research Economist and
Research Economist, respectively, at the Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Major Debt Indicators in South Asia (1970-1999) in Percentage
1970 1980 1990 1995
1. Debt-to-Export of Goods and
Services (DEXGS)
Sri Lanka -- 123.4 210.4 145.9
Pakistan 382.4 208.7 250.0 256.7
India 379.1 136.7 334.0 195.7
S. Asia -- 162.0 327.4 216.3
LDCs 88.4 160.7 141.1
2. Debt-to-Gross National Product
(DEGDNP)
Sri Lanka 19.2 46.1 74.3 64.8
Pakistan 33.9 38.8 49.4 48.6
India 13.9 11.3 26.8 27.1
S. Asia -- 16.1 32.3 33.2
LDCs -- 18.2 30.9 38.4
3. Total Debt Servicing-to-Export
of Goods and Services (DEXGS)
Sri Lanka -- 12.0 13.7 7.5
Pakistan 29.2 18.3 23.0 27.3
India 33.6 9.4 32.7 28.1
S. Asia -- 11.8 28.9 25.0
LDCs -- 6.4 9.5 5.8
4. Interest Payments-to-Export
of Goods and Services (INTXGS)
Sri Lanka -- 5.7 6.1 2.9
Pakistan 9.1 7.9 10.1 10.2
India 8.9 4.3 19.2 10.2
S. Asia -- 5.2 15.6 9.1
LDCs -- 6.8 7.8 6.6
5. Reserves-to-Debt Ratio (RESDE)
Sri Lanka 9.9 15.4 7.6 25.7
Pakistan 5.7 15.8 5.1 8.4
India 12.1 58.0 6.7 24.2
S. Asia -- 40.4 6.9 19.5
LDCs -- 36.4 15.4 25.1
6. Short-term-to-Total Debt (EDT-1)
Sri Lanka 8.8 11.9 6.9 6.5
Pakistan 3.1 7.4 15.4 10.7
India 3.4 6.1 10.2 5.3
S. Asia -- 12.8 18.1 15.7
LDCs -- 23.7 16.8 19.8
7. Concessional Debt-to-Total
Debt (EDT-2)
Sri Lanka 43.2 56.0 71.9 77.5
Pakistan 68.9 71.6 58.5 53.9
India 79.7 74.2 46.2 45.7
S. Asia -- 74.3 56.3 36.6
LDCs -- 18.7 21.5 19.1
8. Multilateral Debt-to-Total
Debt (EDT-3)
Sri Lanka 6.7 11.7 27.7 34.8
Pakistan 18.0 15.4 33.4 40.3
India 18.5 29.3 26.0 31.8
S. Asia -- 24.5 29.5 36.2
LDCs -- 8.3 14.2 13.5
1997 1998 1999
1. Debt-to-Export of Goods and
Services (DEXGS)
Sri Lanka 115.3 123.2 139.5
Pakistan 265.0 277.9 342.9
India 161.6 166.0 139.9
S. Asia 182.6 188.3 174.5
LDCs 128.1 148.5 141.0
2. Debt-to-Gross National Product
(DEGDNP)
Sri Lanka 52.1 56.0 60.3
Pakistan 47.4 51.0 58.3
India 23.3 23.5 21.3
S. Asia 28.8 29.5 28.4
LDCs 36.1 42.8 40.5
3. Total Debt Servicing-to-Export
of Goods and Services (DEXGS)
Sri Lanka 6.4 6.4 7.9
Pakistan 36.0 19.8 28.3
India 21.3 20.6 15.0
S. Asia 21.0 18.4 15.3
LDCs 5.3 4.4 4.3
4. Interest Payments-to-Export
of Goods and Services (INTXGS)
Sri Lanka 2.2 2.2 2.6
Pakistan 10.9 7.4 9.6
India 8.3 8.7 5.6
S. Asia 7.7 7.7 5.7
LDCs 6.2 6.9 6.7
5. Reserves-to-Debt Ratio (RESDE)
Sri Lanka 26.6 23.4 17.3
Pakistan 6.0 5.0 4.4
India 30.1 31.4 34.6
S. Asia 22.4 22.9 23.5
LDCs 28.2 27.6 28.7
6. Short-term-to-Total Debt (EDT-1)
Sri Lanka 6.2 5.1 10.0
Pakistan 8.3 6.7 5.3
India 5.4 4.4 4.3
S. Asia 17.1 18.2 21.4
LDCs 20.1 16.0 15.9
7. Concessional Debt-to-Total
Debt (EDT-2)
Sri Lanka 78.6 80.1 78.6
Pakistan 50.0 52.3 54.3
India 41.2 41.1 47.3
S. Asia 49.6 50.4 55.1
LDCs 15.9 14.7 15.4
8. Multilateral Debt-to-Total
Debt (EDT-3)
Sri Lanka 37.4 37.8 38.1
Pakistan 39.4 40.6 41.3
India 31.2 31.3 33.2
S. Asia 36.0 36.7 38.6
LDCs 12.4 12.8 13.5
Source: World Bank (2001) "Global Development Finance-2001".
Note: DEXGS=debt-to-export ratio: DEGNP=debt-to-GNP ratio:
TDSXGS=total debt servicing-to-exports: INTXGS=interest
payment-to-Exports: RESDE=reserves-to-debt ratio: EDT-1= short-term
debt-to-total debt: EDT-2=Concessional debt-to-total debt: and
EDT-3=multilateral debt-to-total debt. (all the ratios are reported
as percentages). S. Asia=South Asia: LDCs=All Developing Countries.
Table 2
Major Economic Indicators for South Asia (1976-1997)
Sri Lanka Pakistan India All
Growth Rate of 3.49 2.36 2.79 2.87
GDP-Per Capita (0.60) (0.77) (0.08) (0.83)
Inv.-GDP Ratio 24.35 21.39 22.53 22.76
(0.15) (0.07) (0.04) (0.12)
Population Growth 1.33 2.90 2.11 2.11
(0.46) (0.21) (0.09) (0.40)
Terms of Trade 80.87 102.36 83.39 88.87
(0.17) (0.12) (0.17) (0.18)
Openness 84.87 45.31 14.21 48.13
(0.10) (0.05) (0.19) (0.55)
Note: Numbers in parentheses represent coefficients of variation.
Table 3
Results of Estimated Growth Equations-Fixed Effect Model
Equation 1 Equation 2
Inv-GDP 2.865 2.954
(2.739) (3.185)
Deficit-GDP 0.768 0.671
(0.822) -(0.755)
Openness 0.805 1.473
(2.995) (5.244)
Population Growth -- -10.55
(2.888)
Ln (GDP (t-1)) -- 46.53
(5.436)
Fdebt-GDP 4.260 3.707
(2.087) (2.027)
Fdebt-GDP:sq. -0.035 -0.031
(0.146) (2.014)
Debt-servicing-to-Export -- --
Debt-servicing-to-Export-sq. -- --
Debt-Export -- --
Debt-Export Sq. -- --
Adjusted R-Sq. 0.434 0.433
N (Number of Observations) 63 63
Equation 3 Equation 4
Inv-GDP 1.966 2.796
(1.640) (3.550)
Deficit-GDP -1.34 -0.561
(1.153) (0.576)
Openness 0.854 1.655
(2.405) (4.768)
Population Growth -9.501 -13.411
(2.039) (3.310)
Ln (GDP (t-1)) -32.112 -35.613
(3.111) (4.086)
Fdebt-GDP --
Fdebt-GDP:sq. -- --
Debt-servicing-to-Export 0.304 --
(2.963)
Debt-servicing-to-Export-sq. -0.008 --
(0.295)
Debt-Export -- 0.394
(4.374)
Debt-Export Sq. -- -0.001
(4.015)
Adjusted R-Sq. 0.243 0.339
N (Number of Observations) 63 63
Table 4
Critical Values of Debt Burden and Impact on Growth
Impact on Economic Growth
Critical
Values * Sri Lanka Pakistan India
Debt-to-GDP-1 61 +/- +/- +
Debt-to-GDP-2 88 + +/- +
DS-to-Exports 12.75 + - +/-
Debt-to-Export 197.0 + - +
Note: * The critical values are computed on the basis of
estimated equations in Table 3.