Debt Laffer curve for South Asian countries.
Chaudhary, M. Aslam ; Anwar, Sabahat
I. INTRODUCTION
The inflow of foreign capital is generally seen as an accelerating
force to economic growth, due to provision of additional resources, and
these funds are considered complementary to local savings. It could also
help to transfer technology and, therefore, increase productivity.
Besides it enhances purchasing power of the recipients [Mullick (1988)]
and as a result stimulates growth. The purpose of foreign debt is to
increase real transfer of resources from the developed countries to the
developing countries, so that these countries could pick up momentum of
economic growth and as a result improve their welfare. (1)
The rapid increase in the external debt obligations of the
developing countries, during the 1970s, had given rise to concerns about
the dangers of increasing trend in interest and amortisation payments
and, therefore, this situation posed a threat to debtor countries. The
foreign debt of the developing countries has become a threat to their
economic growth. The debt servicing of some of the LDC's exceeded
to their growth rates. (2) Initially, most analysts believed that debt
servicing problem would be temporary. It was hoped that creditworthiness and more normal growth of most of the countries would be restored with
the influx of foreign resources. However, the debt crises have
demonstrated that this assessment was optimistic and seemed never to be
realised. (3)
The South Asian countries saw the inflow of foreign resources as to
bridge the gap between their savings and investment. (4) It was thought
that these funds were needed to accelerate their desired growth. It was
also regarded as panacea for economic diseases, caused by the shortage
of domestic resources. Thus, it was considered to supplement the desired
investment. But the dream of achieving high economic growth through
foreign aid started gradually falling apart, when foreign debt turned
out to be growing encumbrance on the foreign exchange earnings of these
countries. The year 1979-80 brought the world, particularly, the South
Asian countries a set of economic problems--oil price shocks, reduction
in primary products prices, budget deficit, balance of payments deficit,
rising real interest rates and world wide recession, which made it
difficult for them to service their debts [Smith and Cuddington (1989)].
Since the 1980s, the South Asian countries were trapped in a set of
economic crisis. According to World Debt Tables (1996), during the five
years (1982-1986) the decline of economic growth rate of per capita
income from 4 percent to 1 percent between 1982 and 1986 further added
to their problems. Besides the terms of trade for South Asia also
deteriorated by a cumulative percentage of 15.4 points during the same
period.
Several researchers have analysed the debt burden issue from
different perspectives. Claessens and Diwan (1989) argue that the burden
of foreign capital inflow can depress investment below its optimal level
and thus leads to slow down economic growth of the recipient countries.
This can occur through two channels; (i) inability to get desired
foreign borrowing, a liquidity constraint, and debt overhang which is
strong enough, therefore, (ii) expected future loss of output to foreign
creditors. From the debtor country's perspective, the financing
costs of voluntary debt reductions and transformations are likely to
exceed the benefits. Thus, Pareto-improving scheme are difficult to find
in practice--unless the debtor uses funds donated for this purpose, or
that it gains in exchange some concession from creditor's group.
Therefore, conventional debt rescheduling cannot efficiently reconstruct under a situation of debt overhang.
Increasing burden of foreign debt is becoming a threat to the
developing economies of South Asia. Appropriate economic policies may
help to improve the situation. Debt-ridden countries have paid little
attention to the increasing dependency upon foreign resources. As a
result, efforts are not made to generate or mobilise domestic resources;
rather some of these economies have become consumption oriented. This
situation leads to a topology of debt crisis. It defines a debt
overhang, as a situation where outstanding debt is so large that
investment will be inefficiently low without new foreign lending or debt
and debt service reductions. A mild debt overhang can be resolved with
new money approach alone [Sachs (1989)]; which is called a liquidity
trap. Otherwise, a debt overhang requires debt or debt service
reductions unless the debtor uses a commitment mechanism. When a debtor
experiencing a debt overhang, that is more severe than a liquidity trap,
is willing to commit to an adjustment programmes against the provision
of liquidity alone, the situation is called a 'weak' debt
overhang. In such a situation, the commitment mechanism and new money
creation resolve the crisis without the need to reduce debt and debt
services. But a 'strong' debt overhang cannot be resolved
without debt and debt service reductions; the debtor will be unwilling
to commit to a large investment programmes without debt reduction, even
if large amounts of liquidity are not available. Sustainability of debt
may be evaluated by using Laffer Curve technique, developed by Sachs.
The concept of a Laffer curve for the value of claims on a
developing country can be used as an argument for debt forgivingness.
The logic implies that if a country is on the wrong (declining) side of
the Debt Laffer curve, a reduction in nominal claims outstanding will
lead to an increase in the value of outstanding claims and will thus
benefit the both creditors and debtors. If the country is on the correct
side of the Debt Laffer curve (right side), then, debt forgiveness will
not increase the market value of debt, and creditors plus debtors as a
whole, will lose. Thus, across-the-board debt forgiveness is only in the
interest of the creditors and debtors when the debtor is on the wrong
side of the Debt Laffer curve
Another aspect of Debt Laffer curve analysis is related to the
price elasticity of the market value of the debt. Greater the price
elasticity of the debt, greater will be the benefits to the debtor from
a debt reduction. There is limited number of research that analysed the
situation of debt overhang and the possibilities of debt reduction for
indebted developing countries. Most of the studies are cross sectional.
Claessens (1990) estimated the market value of the debt for 29 highly
indebted countries and identified only five countries that were on the
wrong side of the Debt Laffer curve. (5) Cohen (1989) estimated price
elasticity of the debt for thirty developing countries that severe debt
problem was only for four highly indebted countries. Thus the approaches
help to identify the nature of debt problem.
Following Claessens (1990) and Cohen (1989) in this study, we have
carried out a time-series analysis for seven countries of South Asia.
(6) It will be interestingly important to find out whether these
countries stand on the right or wrong side of Debt Laffer curve. The
estimates of the price elasticities of debt will reflect the relative
effectiveness of debt written off for south Asian countries. The policy
description will be derived for meaningful evaluation of debt position
in South Asia. So far hardly any study has analysed this aspect of
foreign debt for the South Asian countries. After this, the study is
organised as under. Part II provides discussion on methodology and
empirical estimation, by using Debt Laffer curve. The discussion of the
results is provided in this Section III. Conclusion and policy
implications are given in Section IV.
II. DEBT LAFFER CURVE: METHODOLOGY
Figure 1 depicts the relationship, as postulated by Sachs (1989)
and Krugman (1988), between the face value of debt and the market value
of expected repayments. On the horizontal axis, the nominal face value
of the external claims is measured while on the vertical axis; the
nominal face Value of foreign debt by creditors is measured. Creditors
expect that the nominal claims will be paid in full at low levels of
external debt. The secondary market price will be one, and the value of
the debt will lie along the 45-degree line. At higher levels of debt,
however, the possibilities of partial repayments grow as the country has
fewer incentives to invest and market value of debt falls increasingly
below the 45-degree line. The secondary market price for debt, which is
the slope of the line from the origin to point like A, will have a
negative relationship with the amount of debt outstanding and it will
fall increasingly below one as debt increases (Fig. 1). At point B, the
debt outstanding becomes so large and the nominal debt acts as such a
large disincentive on the debtor's effort to adjust, reform and
invest, that the market value of debt starts to fall when the face value
of debt increases further. (7)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The relationship between the nominal face value of the debt
outstanding and the market value of the debt is related in the form of
Debt Laffer curve. The market value of the debt of a country is
determined by the secondary market price of the debt as postulated by
Claessens (1990) and Cohen (1989). As market value of debt is dependent
upon nominal amount of claims outstanding and other variables such as
exports and with growth rate of exports which explains the
country's ability to repay the debt, ("creditworthiness"
indicators). To simplify assuming the real export growth rate as
exogenous (8) and debt servicing is assumed to be payable in equal
annual instalments. Further, assuming that the interest rate remains
same during and after the grace period and this interest is payable
after the end of the grace period. The secondary market price of debt
involves three steps. Firstly, equal annual instalments payable on the
external debt outstanding for South Asia, which are calculated by using
the following formula.
EAI = [(/) (AO [(1+//100).sup.T][([sub.1]+P/100).sup.G]]/100[(1+//100).sup.T] ... ... (1)
Where:
EAI = Equal annual instalments of debt servicing on a given amount
of external debt outstanding.
i= Average rate of interest on foreign loans.
M = The amount of the external debt outstanding.
T = The repayment period.
P = The rate of interest in the grace period.
G = The grace period.
After estimating the equal annual instalments present value of
external debt outstanding is estimated by using equal annual
instalments.
PV = {(EAI)[1-1/(1+D/100)]}/{D/100[1+D/100]C} ... ... (2)
Where:
PV = present value of external debt outstanding. (9) D = discount
rate.
Equation (2) can also be expressed as a price equation of external
debt outstanding by dividing both sides by the amount of nominal claims
outstanding. Since the market value of debt is defined in terms of the
secondary market prices. Therefore, prices of debt can be determined by
the following equation.
SMP = [[??].sub.0] + [[??].sub.1] EXTD + [[??].sub.2]GREXP ... ...
... ... (3)
Where:
SMP = Secondary market price of the external debt outstanding.
EXTD = Ratio of the external debt outstanding to exports.
GREXP = Growth rate of exports.
To see whether a country is on the right side of the Debt Laffer
Curve or not, the maximised value of external debt is estimated. The
maximised value of external debt can be estimated by multiplying the
nominal external debt outstanding with its secondary market price for
each country, as follows:
MVD = (SMP)(M) ... ... ... ... ... ... (4)
The second approach pertains to price elasticity is estimated for
which the following procedure is followed. Estimate the following
equation.
LSMP = [[??].sub.0] + [[??].sub.1] LEXTD + [[??].sub.2]GREXP ...
... ... (5)
Where:
LSMP= Log of secondary market price of the external debt
outstanding.
LEXTD = Log of external debt outstanding to exports ratio.
GREXP = Growth rate of exports.
The impact of debt write off on the market value of the debt will
depend on the marginal price of the debt. Thus, marginal price of the
debt can be estimated by the following formula.
DMV = (SMP) (1 - [??]) (DM) ... ... ... ... ... (6)
Where:
[??] = Price elasticity of the debt.
DMV = Change in the market value of debt.
DM = The change in total external debt outstanding.
Now a country will stand to gain from a debt write off if and only
if the following condition is fulfilled [Cohen (1988)].
[??] > (1-[t.sub.x]) (S.E) ... ... ... ... ... ... (7)
Where:
[t.sub.x] = t-statistic corresponding to the x-degree of
confidence.
S.E = Standard error of the elasticity in Equation (5).
The price elasticity of external debt outstanding measures the
responsiveness of demand of foreign debt to changes in its own price. If
the price elasticity of external debt of a country is greater than the
product of standard error and /-statistics corresponding to the x-degree
of freedom, then a country gets benefit from debt reduction.
Table 1, presents the estimates of the market value and the
secondary market price of external debt outstanding of seven countries
of South Asia. As already mentioned in the methodology that market value
of external debt is the present value of debt obtained from multiplying
the nominal debt outstanding with its secondary market price for each
year10 [Claessens (1990) and Sachs and Hizinga (1987)].
The results of OLS estimate are obtained by applying a time series
analysis for South Asian countries in this paper, which support the
theoretical intuitions developed at the background of this model.
Claessens (1990) and Sachs and Huizinga (1987) estimate the Debt Laffer
curve with OLS technique, while Cohen (1988) attempts to find out the
Debt Laffer curve problem with price elasticity approach, while we
estimate the Debt Laffer curve problem for South Asian countries with
applying both approaches. The sample size is taken from 1970-71 to
1994-95 and data for all the countries are in real terms (1990-91
prices). First of all, equal annual instalment are calculated for all
the seven countries of South Asia, then through equal annual instalments
we estimate the present value of debt outstanding by using Equation (2).
The results of the price equation indicated that the secondary
market price of debt for Pakistan has negative association with the
nominal debt outstanding (debt to export ratio). Then, this price
equation is used to calculate the market value of external debt
outstanding of Pakistan and other South Asian countries. The equation
for the market value of external debt outstanding can now be used to
derive the face value of debt (debt to export ratio) for which the
market value of debt reaches its maximum, the top of the Debt Laffer
curve.
As indicated in Table 1, there is a negative relationship of debt
to export ratio with secondary market price of debt outstanding for
Pakistan and India, and have an insignificant effect on secondary market
price of debt outstanding. Pakistan and India are agricultural based
countries and its products contribute a small amount to GNP and on the
other hand, they also face balance of payment problem. In 1994-95,
exports as a percentage of GNP was 15.9 percent for Pakistan and imports
as a percentage of GNP was 24.5 percent, these figures for India was
11.6 percent and 15.7 percent, respectively. The above figures indicate
trade gaps for Pakistan and India respectively. Therefore, any increase
in exports insignificantly decreases the market value of external debt
outstanding, whereas Bangladesh has also negative relationship but it
has a significant effect. The results show the same trend for Sri Lanka.
Debt-toexport ratio of Nepal is also negative and shows insignificant
effect on secondary market price of debt outstanding. An increase in
exports insignificantly decreases the market value of debt.
Maldives and Bhutan are positive, but with insignificant
relationship of debtto-export ratio and with secondary market price of
debt outstanding. Growth rate of exports is positive but it has
insignificant effect on secondary market price of debt outstanding for
Pakistan and Maldives. This means that one percent increase in growth
rate of exports increases the SMP value by 0.002 in case of Pakistan and
0.02 in case of Maldives. Other five countries, India, Bangladesh, Sri
Lanka, Nepal and Bhutan are negative and insignificant relationship of
growth rate of exports with secondary market price of debt outstanding.
This means that one percent increase in growth rate of exports decreases
the SMP value by 0.012 for India, 0.009, in the case of Bangladesh,
0.024, in the case of Sri Lanka, 0.0002, in case of Nepal and in the
case of Bhutan it is 0.002.
Except for Maldives and Bhutan the secondary market price of debt
for Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, and Nepal has a negative
association with the nominal debt outstanding (debt to export ratio) but
Maldives and Bhutan have a positive relationship of face value of debt
with secondary market price of debt. Pakistan and Maldives have a
positive relationship between growth rate of exports and secondary
market price of debt but other group of countries has the positive
relationship.
In addition to the price equation, the maximised value of external
debt is also estimated, which indicates whether the country is on the
right side of the Debt Laffer curve or on the wrong side of the Debt
Laffer curve. Estimates of the maximum market value of debt outstanding
indicates that Pakistan is on the right side of the Debt Laffer curve
because its current debt-to-export ratio in 1995 is 2.72 which is below
the debt-to-export ratio for which its external debt reaches its maximum
which is 3.44. India is also on the correct side of Debt Laffer curve
and its current debt-toexport ratio is 3.63 and debt-to-export ratio for
which its external debt reaches its
maximum is 5.12. Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal have debt to
export ratios (in 1995) are 5.38, 2.18, 5.59, respectively and their
debt-to-export ratio for which their external debts reach their maximum
are 6.96, 2.55, 6.42, respectively. While in case of Maldives and Bhutan
debt-to export ratios (in 1995) are 3.43 and 1.34, respectively which
are above the debt-to-export ratio for which the external debt reaches
their maximum which are 1.37 and 0.82, respectively, so they falls on
the wrong side of the Debt Laffer curve. So Pakistan, India, Bangladesh,
Sri Lanka, and Nepal stand on the right side of the Debt Laffer curve
because their current debt to export ratio (in 1995) is below the debt
to export ratio for which their external debt reaches their maximum (see
Appendix) . The total debt stock of Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri
Lanka and Nepal has an increasing trend [World Debt Tables (1996)]. The
external debt outstanding of Pakistan and India is bifurcated into
private and public loans, in which private loans are hard loans and
public loans are soft loans, while Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal have
taken only public loans so foreign debt has a favourable impact on their
economies. As for the case of Maldives and Bhutan, the both countries
stand on the wrong side of the Debt Laffer curve because their current
debt to export ratio, (in 1995) is far above to their debt to export
ratio for which their external debt reaches their maximum level (see
Appendix Table 1).
In addition to the above, another approach is used to see whether a
country uses a debt reduction scheme for or not for improving its
economic position. To analyse the effect of a debt write-off on the
market value of external debt outstanding, the price elasticity of the
debt is estimated. The price elasticity of the debt is estimated through
Equation 5 (mentioned above). The results of the equation are given in
the Appendix.
As mentioned in Equation (7), a country can gain from debt write
off if the following condition is fulfilled.
[??] > (1-[t.sub.x](S.E)
Where '[??]' is price elasticity of external debt
outstanding and [t.sub.x] is t-statistic of corresponding x degree of
freedom and S.E is standard error of the estimate. Table 2 provides
price elasticities of external debt for South Asian countries. The price
elasticity of external debt for Pakistan is 0.39, which is less than (1
- [t.sub.x]) (S.E) so Pakistan does not gain from debt reduction. India
has a price elasticity of (-1.22) which is also less than desired value.
Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal have the values -0.66, -2.68 and -0.07
against the comparative values (1 - [t.sub.x]) (S.E), which are 1.51,
0.68 and 0.68, respectively. The values for Maldives and Bhutan are 0.14
and 0.07, where product of S.E are greater which are -0.15 and 0.05,
which means that they gain from debt reduction. So it is concluded that
Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal do not fulfil that
above condition so we can say that debt reduction scheme for these
countries will not benefit to them at this point. But Maldives and
Bhutan's results show that this condition is fulfilled so they gain
from debt write off. As these results are rechecked again because from
following the Claessens (1990) model, results show that debt reduction
scheme is favourable for the both countries.
Figure 2 provides a picture of the estimates of the debt-to-export
ratios at which the market value of debt reaches its maximum, EXT*,
again the actual debt-to-export ratio (of 1995), EXT, using the Equation
(3), for South Asian countries. (11) The 45-degree line in Figure 2
divides the countries into two portions. The right side of the Debt
Laffer curve (above the 45-degree line) indicates that those are on the
wrong side. Sri Lanka and Nepal are on the correct side of Debt Laffer
Curve.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Laffer curve, the side where the face value of debt is bellows the
level for which the market value of external debt starts to decline. The
only country that is perceived by the market to be on the wrong side of
the Debt Laffer curve are Maldives and Bhutan where the market value of
debt is maximised at roughly the current debt level. This result implies
that across-the-board debt forgiveness, through the general reduction of
the nominal claims outstanding, is not in the interest of the creditors
for most highly indebted countries.
On the basis of above cited empirical evidences, it may be stated
that Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal have faced debt
condition that may create serious problem for them. However Maldives and
Bhutan face the debt problem more severe than other South Asian
countries. The external debt of Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka
and Nepal have been increasing one time but at relatively slower rate
than the total debt of Maldives and Bhutan. The debt situation of
Maldives and Bhutan has deteriorated during the second half of the 1980s
[World Debt Tables (1996)], increases in interest rates and reduction in
the maturity and grace periods in respect of new loan commitments added
to their debt-servicing problem, while for Pakistan, India, Bangladesh,
Sri Lanka and Nepal, terms and conditions of their new loan commitments
maintained at favourable levels.
In addition to the price equation, the maximised value of external
debt is also estimated, which indicates whether the country is on the
right side of the Debt Laffer curve or on the wrong side of the Debt
Laffer curve. Estimates of the maximum market value of debt outstanding
indicates that Pakistan is on the right side of the Debt Laffer curve
because its current debt-to-export ratio in 1995 is 2.72 which is below
the debt-to-export ratio for which its external debt reaches its maximum
which is 3.44. India is also on the correct side of Debt Laffer curve
and its current debt-to-export ratio is 3.63 and debt-to-export ratio
for which its external debt reaches its maximum is 5.12. Bangladesh, Sri
Lanka and Nepal have debt to export ratios (in 1995) are 5.38, 2.18,
5.59, respectively and their debt-to-export ratio for which their
external debts reach their maximum are 6.96, 2.55, 6.42, respectively.
While in case of Maldives and Bhutan debt-to-export ratios (in 1995) are
3.43 and 1.34, respectively which are above the debt-to-export ratio for
which the external debt reaches their maximum which are 1.37 and 0.82,
respectively, so they falls on the wrong side of the Debt Laffer curve.
So Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, and Nepal stand on the right
side of the Debt Laffer curve because their current debt to export ratio
(in 1995) is below the debt to export ratio for which their external
debt reaches their maximum. The total debt stock of Pakistan, India,
Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal has a increasing trend. The external
debt outstanding of Pakistan and India is bifurcated into private and
public loans, in which private loans are hard loans and public loans
are, relatively, soft loans. Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal have taken
only public loans so foreign debt has a favourable impact on their
economies. As far as the case of Maldives and Bhutan is concerned, the
both countries stand on the wrong side of the Debt Laffer curve because
their current debt to export ratio, is far above to their debt to export
ratio for which their external debt reaches at the maximum limit (see
Appendix, Table 1).
III. CONCLUSION
The main focus of this paper was to highlight and analyse the
problem of rising debt burden of South Asia. The increasing dependency
of South Asian economies on foreign resources is evident by their debt
and debt servicing ratios of the South Asian countries, which is very
high. The figures are alarming which indicated that the countries were
on the verge of liquidity or solvency. The ratios of debt to GNP and
foreign exchange earnings both showed rising trends.
To see whether debt reduction is favourable to the economies of
South Asia, Debt Laffer curve is estimated. The estimates of the Debt
Laffer curve reveal that Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and
Nepal lie on the right side of the Debt Laffer curve because their
current level of debt outstanding is below that level of debt at which
the market value of debt would be maximised. But the difference between
the current level of debt outstanding and that level of debt at which
market value of debt would be maximised is not significant. Projection
of these economies shows that if the same trend of borrowing continues,
they may face a rising burden of debt and debt servicing. On the other
hand, Maldives and Bhutan lie on the wrong side of the Debt Laffer
curve. They can gain from debt write off. The rapid increase in the
foreign debt of other South Asian countries also indicates that they
will also reach at the maximum level of debt. Thus, there is a need for
them also to better manage their debt.
REFERENCES
Chaudhry, M. Aslam, and Sabahat Anwar (2001) Foreign Debt,
Dependency, and Economic Growth in South Asia. The Pakistan Development
Review 39:4, 551-570.
Claessens, S. (1990) The Debt Laffer Curve: Some Estimates. World
Development. 18:12.
Claessens, Stijn, and Ishac Diwan (1989) Market-Based Debt
Reduction. Dealing with the Debt Crisis. Washington, D. C. (World Bank
Discussion Papers.)
Claessens, Stijn, and Ishac Diwan (1989a) Liquidity, Debt, and
Conditionality. Dealing with the Debt Crisis. Washington, D. C. (World
Bank Discussion Papers.)
Cohen, Daniel (1989) How to Cope with a Debt Overhang: Cut Flows
Rather Than Stocks. Dealing with the Debt Crisis. Washington, D.C.
(World Bank Discussion Papers.)
Cuddington, John T. (1989) The Extent and Causes of the Debt Crisis
of the 1980s. Dealing with the Debt Crisis. Washington, D. C. (World
Bank Discussion Papers.)
Froot, K. (1989) Buybacks, Exit Bonds, and the Optimality of Debt
and Liquidity Relief. International Economic Review 30: February, 49-70.
Krueger, Anne O. (1987) The International Debt Crisis Debt, Capital
Flows, and LDC Growth. The American Economic Review 77:2.
Krugman, Paul (1988) Financing vs. Forgiving a Debt Overhang.
Journal of Development Economics 29:3.
Mullick, Hussein M. A. (1988) Is Foreign Aid an Obstruction to
Democracy and Development in the Third World? The Pakistan Development
Review 27: 4, 529-534.
Pakistan, Government of (1996) Economic Survey: 1995-96. Islamabad:
Finance Division, Economic Advisory Wing.
Sachs, Jeffrey (1989) Efficient Debt Reduction. Dealing with the
Debt Crisis. Washington, D.C. (World Bank Discussion Papers.)
Sachs. J., and H. Hizinga (1987) U. S. Commercial Banks and the
Developing Country Debt Crisis. Brookings Papers on Economic Activit 2:
November, 55-606.
Thirlwall, A. P. (1999) Growth and Development with Special
Reference to Developing Countries. London: Macmillan Press Limited.
World Bank (Various Issues) World Tables. Washington, D. C.
Comments
The paper entitled, "Debt Laffer Curve for South Asian
Countries", by M. Aslam Chaudhary and Sabahat Anwar deals with an
important issue affecting the economy of South Asian countries.
Utilising the data for the period 1976-77-1994-95, the study concludes
the following:
(1) The debt servicing ratios are alarmingly high in the South
Asian Countries.
(2) The estimates of laffer curve show that Pakistan, India,
Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Nepal lie on the right side of the debt laffer
curve whereas Bhutan and Maldives are on the wrong side of the laffer
curve. Thus, Bhutan and Maldives can benefit from the debt reduction.
(3) The rapid rise in debt indicates the need for better management
of debt in South Asian countries.
The first and the third points are not surprising conclusions. The
second point is expected to be sensitive to the selection of period of
study. Extending the time period to the year 2000 may change the
conclusions significantly as the data shows deterioration in the debt
situation of Pakistan. Extending the analysis to the year 2002 will also
change the analysis significantly. The analysis will be more meaningful
if critical debt ratios are analysed by sub periods.
The results of the price equation, reported in Table 1, indicate
that the effect of debt-export ratio and growth rate of exports on
secondary market price of external debt in South Asia are not
statistically significant, except for Bangladesh and Sri Lanka. This
raises the questions about the usefulness of reported results and
specification of the model. Dummy variables, for the different time
periods, and other variables like debt-GDP ratio, growth rate of gross
domestic product can also be incorporated in price equation. This will
give us more meaningful results. For example, the coefficient estimates
of dummy variables will be useful in analysing the structural changes in
price behaviour.
The study seems to suggest that only the countries lying on the
wrong side of the debt laffer curve will benefit from debt reduction.
This is a surprising conclusion because reduction in debt will be
beneficial to all the countries, irrespective of their position on the
debt laffer curve.
The main contribution of the authors is computation of EAI, i.e.,
equal annual installments of debt servicing on a given external debt
outstanding. It will be useful to those working on this important topic
if the authors add this series in the data appendix along with the
critical ratios of debt to export, debt to GDP and export growth.
Rehana Siddiqui
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
(1) Thirlwall (1999) pointed out that developed countries agreed,
under UNO, to transfer 1 percent of their GDD as international aid to
the developing world but it was never fulfilled.
(2) The debt servicing is double than the economic growth of
developing countries. For details see Chaudhary and Anwar (2001).
(3) For details of present nature of foreign debt and recycling of
debt [see Thirlwall (1999)].
(4) The saving-investment gag was filled by borrowing from abroad,
rather mobilising additional domestic resources.
(5) Five countries are Bolivia, Sudan, Peru, Zambia and Nicaragua.
See Claessens (1990). There is no such study pertaining to S. Asian
countries, as per knowledge.
(6) These countries are Pakistan, India, Sri Lanka, Bangladesh,
Maldives, Nepal and Bhutan. These countries are also member of South
Asian Associations for Regional Cooperation (SAARC).
(7) Claessens and Diwan (1989); Krugman (1988) and Froot (1989)
derive Debt Laffer curve through formal models of a country's
investment and adjustment incentives.
(8) The growth of real exports is likely to be dependent on the
level of the external debt outstanding. [See Claessens (1990).]
(9) Present value of debt is the market value of the debt which
depends on the secondary market prices of the debt.
(10) The maximum value of debt can be estimated through the
maximisation of Eq. MVD = (SMP) (EXTD).
(11) The scales are in logs.
M. Aslam Chaudhary is Associate Professor in the Department of
Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad. Sabahat Anwar is a
Visiting Faculty Member at the Fatima Jinnah Women's University,
Rawalpindi.
Appendix Table 1
The Secondary Market Prices of External Debt Outstanding
of South Asian Countries
(Millions, Real) *
Pakistan
Year SMP MV EXT
1970-71 0.180 28765 7.99
1971-72 0.628 10433 4.92
1972-73 0.629 14712 2.73
1973-74 0.448 20851 4.57
1974-75 0.343 16325 4.62
1975-76 0.573 32543 5.04
1976-77 0.845 53109 5.56
1977-78 0.454 32350 5.48
1978-79 0.126 9792. 4.56
1979-80 0.301 25811 3.66
1980-81 0.421 36546 2.96
1981-82 0.454 42190 3.53
1982-83 3.866 457494 3.44
1983-84 0.791 101068 3.42
1984-85 0.752 111018 3.88
1985-86 1.056 189389 3.62
1986-87 1.140 235585 3.26
1987-88 0.444 101102 2.90
1988-89 0.542 147784 3.02
1989-90 0.357 115868 3.40
1990-91 0.399 138469 2.51
1991-92 0.398 171835 2.51
1992-93 0.121 60066 2.79
1993-94 0.067 41406 2.98
1994-95 0.126 86451 2.72
India
Year SMP MV EXT
1970-71 0.218 12966.04 3.92
1971-72 0.437 28880.35 4.34
1972-73 0.189 14259.89 4.07
1973-74 0.250 20561.47 3.65
1974-75 0.191 18601.13 3.07
1975-76 0.222 25468.54 3.14
1976-77 0.569 71053.30 2.51
1977-78 0.215 28561.46 2.38
1978-79 0.122 16512.50 2.48
1979-80 0.491 70932.39 2.28
1980-81 1.563 253514.6 2.40
1981-82 1.450 292032.9 2.81
1982-83 1.933 509702.0 2.98
1983-84 1.093 359664.9 3.56
1984-85 1.091 439096.9 3.75
1985-86 1.251 625723.7 4.42
1986-87 0.722 446271.3 5.22
1987-88 0.420 303240.3 4.94
1988-89 0.676 571965.0 4.60
1989-90 0.333 408171.2 4.75
1990-91 0.202 297420.0 4.68
1991-92 0.392 807755.5 5.13
1992-93 0.181 431805.7 4.68
1993-94 0.151 433581.8 4.38
1994-95 0.124 352769.5 3.63
Bangladesh
Year SNIP MV EXT
1970-71 0.125 1258.2 2.58
1971-72 0.142 258.2 1.54
1972-73 0.177 156.1 0.44
1973-74 0.493 1887.3 1.38
1974-75 0.427 4245.9 3.53
1975-76 0.103 1651.9 4.35
1976-77 0.138 4207.5 5.19
1977-78 0.107 4034.9 5.17
1978-79 0.082 3667.2 5.45
1979-80 0.048 2300.2 4.66
1980-81 0.055 3432.3 5.33
1981-82 0.094 6842.1 5.15
1982-83 0.036 3642.0 5.94
1983-84 0.039 5013.2 7.29
1984-85 0.027 3753.8 5.92
1985-86 0.023 3859.0 6.07
1986-87 0.018 4213.5 8.79
1987-88 0.012 3500.9 9.01
1988-89 0.200 6349.2 7.80
1989-90 0.009 3109.1 8.17
1990-91 0.042 1704.1 6.96
1991-92 0.007 3651.9 7.44
1992-93 0.010 5074.4 6.17
1993-94 0.001 5343.8 6.08
1994-95 0.013 7572.6 5.38
Sri Lanka
Year SNIP MV EXT
1970-71 0.677 1833.49 1.33
1971-72 1.436 4769.42 1.63
1972-73 1.114 4278.64 1.91
1973-74 1.524 7377.62 1.84
1974-75 2.359 14314.47 1.73
1975-76 0.530 3549.17 1.69
1976-77 1.405 12955.8 1.91
1977-78 0.272 4122.20 2.31
1978-79 0.158 3381.1 1.62
1979-80 0.643 15551.7 1.58
1980-81 0.568 17285.0 1.73
1981-82 1.843 79287.9 2.04
1982-83 4.468 244097. 2.55
1983-84 0.116 7905.3 2.70
1984-85 0.951 72352.6 2.04
1985-86 0.168 16156.3 2.65
1986-87 0.469 53376.6 3.34
1987-88 0.148 20645.0 3.39
1988-89 0.044 7181.87 3.52
1989-90 0.201 37479.9 3.32
1990-91 0.020 4721.45 3.06
1991-92 0.005 1359.20 3.29
1992-93 0.025 7201.01 2.61
1993-94 0.018 5775.17 2.37
1994-95 0.016 5507.70 2.18
Nepal
Year SNIP MV EXT
1970-71 0.181 5.15 0.07
1971-72 0.382 32.11 0.17
1972-73 0.105 12.39 0.20
1973-74 0.009 1.79 0.30
1974-75 0.021 6.10 0.41
1975-76 0.026 9.11 0.32
1976-77 0.025 14.80 0.48
1977-78 0.018 23.23 1.25
1978-79 0.016 23.49 1.30
1979-80 0.032 56.37 1.34
1980-81 0_013 33.64 2.55
1981-82 0.042 139.3 1.93
1982-83 0.025 114.2 3.93
1983-84 0.016 99.98 4.59
1984-85 0.007 55.15 3.40
1985-86 0.031 324.7 3.60
1986-87 0.049 708.3 4.77
1987-88 0.212 4473 6.42
1988-89 0.009 225.8 5.79
1989-90 0.008 290.0 8.05
1990-91 0.006 287.9 7.59
1991-92 0.006 329.8 5.62
1992-93 0.004 296.6 4.78
1993-94 0.004 392.6 4.81
1994-95 0.002 270.3 5.59
* In country's respective currency.
Appendix Table 2
The Secondary Market Prices of External Debt Outstanding (SAARC)
Maldives
Year SMP MV EXT
1976-77 0.027 0.023 0.02
1977-78 0.007 0.420 1.34
1978-79 0.054 4.326 1.24
1979-80 0.007 0.638 1.20
1980-81 0.102 22.416 2.02
1981-82 0.068 19.984 2.46
1982-83 0.409 190.954 3.76
1983-84 0.359 195.228 3.90
1984-85 5.360 3129.123 3.58
1985-86 0.909 536.078 3.26
1986-87 0.666 327.451 2.55
1987-88 0.016 10.908 2.09
1988-89 1.154 722.962 1.60
1989-90 0.104 62.705 1.30
1990-91 .007 5.392 1.34
1991-92 5.179 4312.226 1.37
1992-93 0.013 13.138 1.90
1993-94 0.078 97.866 2.98
1994-95 0.115 166.176 3.43
Bhutan
Year SMP MV EXT
1976-77 -- -- --
1977-78 -- -- --
1978-79 -- -- --
1979-80 -- -- --
1980-81 0.028 0.067 0.01
1981-82 0.043 0.112 0.02
1982-83 0.037 0.395 0.06
1983-84 0.034 0.630 0.09
1984-85 0.030 0.931 0.11
1985-86 0.026 2.858 0.25
1986-87 0.024 6.419 0.37
1987-88 0.014 7.440 0.50
1988-89 1.117 1043.309 0.82
1989-90 0.011 13.166 0.92
1990-91 0.014 19.165 0.90
1991-92 0.007 14.492 1.13
1992-93 0.035 75.887 1.20
1993-94 0.004 10.026 1.37
1994-95 0.007 19.223 1.34
Where: SMP = secondary market price of the debt.
MV = Maximised value of external debt outstanding.
EXT - External debt outstanding to export ratio.
Appendix Table 3
Estimates of the Price Equation of External Debt Outstanding
Countries
Dependent
Variable PAK IND BANG S.LAN
CONST. -1.34 0.36 -1.29 3.07
0.00 (0.42) (-2.37) * (1.71) **
LEXT 0.26 -0.85 -1.2 -5.66
(0.40) 0.00 0.00 (-2.78) *
GREXP 0.004 -0.016 0.004 0.03
(0.75) (-0.83) (0.62) (0.93)
[R.sup.2] 0.02 0.15 0.44 0.26
D. IV 0.89 0.79 0.82 I.50
Figures in parentheses refer to t-statistics.
* Significant at 5 percent. ** Significant at 10 percent.
Table 1
Foreign Debt and Credit-worthiness
(Estimates of the Price Equation of External Debt Outstanding)
Countries
Dependent PAK IND BANG S.LAN
Const. 0.69 0.92 0.34 2.36
(1.30) (2.81) ** (5.70) ** (3.47) **
Ext -0.02 -0.07 -0.04 -0.61
(-0.19) (-0.73) (-4.59) ** (-2.21) *
Grexp 0.0018 -0.012 -0.009 0.024
(0.35) (-1.03) (-0.02) (-2.55) *
[R.sup.2] 0.94 0.81 0.51 0.30
D.W 1.71 1.76 1.47 2.01
Countries
Dependent NEPAL MALDI BHUT
Const. 0.082 0.04 0.087
(2.83) ** (0.05) (0.61)
Ext -0.0095 0.27 0.03
(0.00) (0.75) (0.20)
Grexp 0.0002 0.02 -0.002
(-0.22) (0.82) (-0.29)
[R.sup.2] 0.80 0.67 0.13
D.W 1.53 2.25 2.08
Figures in the parentheses refer to t-statistic.
* Significant at 5 percent. ** Significant at 10 percent. Where
PAK stands for Pakistan, IND for India, BANG for Bangladesh,
S.LAN for Sri Lanka, MALDI for Maldives and BHUT for Bhutan.
Table 2
Impact of Debt Reduction
(Estimation of Price Elasticity of External Debt)
Countries
PAK IND BANG S.LAN
Price Elasticities 0.39 -1.22 -0.61 2.68
([1-t.sub.x](S.E) 0.48 -0.35 1.51 0.68
Countries
NEPAL MALDI BHUT
Price Elasticities -0.07 0.14 0.07
([1-t.sub.x](S.E) 0.68 -0.15 0.05
* Based on Appendix Table 2.