Earnings differential between public and private sectors in Pakistan.
Nasir, Zafar Mueen
The paper explores the earnings differential between public and
private sectors in Pakistan. The private sector is further divided into
formal and informal sectors for comparison purposes. It utilises an
expanded version of the human capital model to determine important
determinants of earnings in each sector. Using standard technique, the
earnings are decomposed into two parts, i.e., differential due to
personal characteristics and due to earnings structure of the particular
sector. The Labour Force Survey 1996-97 is used for the analysis of wage
differential. Results indicate that workers in public sector earn more
than both private formal as well as informal sector workers. These
earnings are higher due to their superior personal human capital
endowment, however, the wage structure of the public sector is not
helping them. The informal sector workers are earning lower than both
public sector and private formal sector workers due to both personal
characteristics and wage structure of the informal sector
I. INTRODUCTION
The paper provides an analysis of wage differential between the
employees of public and private sectors. The private sector is divided
into the formal and informal sectors. In the formal sector, workers are
protected through legislation, but in the informal sector no such
protection is available to the work force. The main objective of the
paper is to highlight as well as determine the extent of exploitation of
regular wage employees in different sectors. We investigate the role of
wage-related personal characteristics of individuals in determining
their wages and compute the differentials in earnings through the use of
earnings functions. These differentials are also decomposed into the
difference due to personal characteristics and the difference due to the
structure of wages. (1) The study is important because the role of
public sector is rapidly changing as the major source of employment. Not
only has the creation of new jobs in the public sector been banned, many
of the workers in this already-crowded establishment may lose jobs under
the public sector rightsizing policies as well as through the
privatisation of public sector concerns.
Wages in the public sector are determined through the political
process or by service regulations rather than on the basis of
productivity [Gunderson (1979)]. Therefore, the employees in the public
sector enjoy higher wages as compared to other sectors. This is one of
the sources of wage differential in different sectors. In contrast to
the public sector, wages in the private sector are determined by the
demand and supply conditions of the labour market. While there is a wage
differential between the public and private sectors, wages differ rather
significantly across formal and informal sectors within the private
sector. No doubt, employees in the private formal sector have a higher
content of human capital; but mainly because of the legal cover they
earn a relatively higher income than the workers in the informal sector
who virtually have no legal protection. Because of their vulnerability,
the employees in the informal sector face considerably higher
exploitation as compared to both employees of the public sector and the
private formal sector. The study tests the hypotheses that:
(a) the employees in the public sector are enjoying economic rent,
and that
(b) the informal sector workers suffer more exploitation as
compared to the employees of the public and private formal sectors.
The paper is organised as follows. Section II provides the overview
of the situation of different sectors in Pakistan. Section III
formulates the theoretical model. Section IV deals with the data
characteristics and limitations. Empirical results are discussed in
Section V. Major findings and policy implications are presented in
Section VI.
II. PUBLIC AND PRIVATE SECTORS IN PAKISTAN
The public sector of Pakistan is not very significantly different
from that of the other developing countries. Because of the high
unemployment in the country, and as one of the major employers in the
past, it is still an attractive sector of employment. However, with
significant political interference and the pursuit of non-commercial goals, it is marred by inefficiency. The overstaffing and noncommercial
pricing policy has not only led to high cost structure and low
profitability; it has also driven most of the public sector
establishments to the brink of insolvency [Faruqee, Ali and Choudhry
(1995)]. Because political forces rather than economic considerations
guided most of the actions in the public sector, these establishments
have led to an increase in the financial burden on the
already-resource-deficient national exchequer.
The mounting fiscal imbalances forced government to take serious
notice of the situation. On the advice of international financial
institutions, the Government of Pakistan adopted a Structural Adjustment
and Stabilisation Programme in the late 1980s to remove the fiscal
imbalances. One essential condition of the programme was to make the
public sector more productive and cost-efficient by rightsizing/
downsizing. As a result, since 1990, new recruitment is banned and many
departments/ministries/corporations are going through the process of
either downsizing or privatisation. (2) Moreover, despite continuous
escalation of the cost of living since 1994, no significant relief in
salaries has been provided. It is estimated that the real wages have
eroded by about 50 percent for most public sector employees since 1994.
(3)
Since the main concern of the paper is to compare the earnings
between the public and the private sectors, it is interesting to discuss
briefly the structure of the jobs in the private sector. The private
sector in Pakistan provides long-tenure, high-wage, as well as
short-term and low-paid jobs. The first kind of job exists in the formal
sector where the entry is relatively difficult and requires not only a
high content of human capital but also strong links. The jobs in this
sector are of primary nature, and because of their characteristics are
closely related to the public sector jobs. In contrast to the formal
sector, the jobs in the informal sector are of secondary nature, and
this sector is the biggest employer in Pakistan. (4) The entry in this
sector is relatively easy and skill requirement for employment is also
quite low. Although wages are determined by the market conditions, they
are relatively low in this sector because of its low skill component
[Kemal and Mahmood (1993)]. The working conditions and remuneration are
unsatisfactory in the absence of any legal cover to the employees in
this sector [Ghayur (1993)]. It attracts only those workers who cannot
find jobs in the other two sectors. Therefore, in the light of the
prevailing situation, in the study we shall deal with the formal and
informal private sectors separately.
Considering the significant differences in the public, private
formal, and private informal sectors, it will be an interesting exercise
to explore the factors that determine the wage rates in the three
sectors (i.e., public, private formal, and private informal) and the
wage differentials among them. A number of studies have explored the
differences in earnings in the public and private sectors and a majority
of them have found public sector wages to be higher than those in the
other sectors [Smith (1976); Gunderson (1979); Lindauer and Sabot
(1983); Mann and Kapoor (1988); Gaag, Stelcner, and Vijverberg (1989);
Terrell (1993)]. Most of these studies have included regular as well as
non-regular workers in their analysis. The present study departs from
the previous studies on two counts. First, it analyses the informal
sector in the private sector in addition to the formal sectors both in
the private and public sectors; secondly, it includes only salaried
workers in the analysis. (5) The sample is restricted to only male
employees to avoid the problems associated with field enumeration of
females employees in the sample. (6)
III. THEORETICAL MODEL
Separate earnings functions that include human capital and other
characteristics of workers to determine their wages are estimated. A
semi-log earnings function defined below is estimated:
ln W = [[beta].sub.0] + [summation] [[beta].sub.i] [X.sub.i] + u
... (1)
where W is the monthly earnings of workers and [X.sub.i] is the
vector of personal characteristics of the workers. Experience of the
workers is one of the main characteristics of workers; in the
specification, age and its square terms are used as a proxy for
experience. (7) The quadratic term of age in the basic human capital
model of Becker (1964) and Mincer (1974) captures the diminishing
returns to experience with time. Other variables include the marital
status and occupation of the workers. This equation will be estimated
for each sector of employment separately. The Chow test is used to test
whether the sectors are structurally different from each other or not
(i.e., public and private, public and informal, and private and
informal). (8)
The difference in wages may arise due to two reasons. First, the
difference in wages may arise due to a difference in endowment and
productivity-related personal characteristics of the workers, and these
include different levels of human capital, occupational difference, and
other endowments. More productive workers will get higher compensation
relative to the workers, who on average have a lower level of
productivity-related characteristics. Second, the wage differential may
arise due to the wage structure across different sectors, i.e.,
employees with the same endowments may get different remuneration in
different sectors.
To measure the wage differential, the mean of log wages between
different sectors is used in calculations. The absolute difference
[D.sub.ij] is calculated as:
[D.sub.ij] = Ln [W.sub.i] - Ln [W.sub.j] ... (2)
Where i = high-wage sector and j = other sector.
Because of the nature and skill requirements of different sectors,
a strong possibility exists for the marked difference in the wage
structure of different employers and the endowments of their employees.
The total wage differential may be decomposed into two parts: the first
part is due to the difference in the wage structure and the second part
is due to the wage-related characteristics and endowments of the workers
employed in different sectors. (9)
The model of wage differential across groups i and j simply is:
Ln [W.sub.i] = [f.sub.i]([X.sub.i]) = [summation] [[beta].sub.i] X
i ... (3)
Ln [W.sub.j] = [f.sub.j] ([X.sub.j]) = [summation] [[beta].sub.j]
[X.sub.j] ... (4)
where [X.sub.i] and [X.sub.j] are the mean values of the vectors of
characteristics of sector i and j respectively.
The gross difference can be expressed as:
[D.sub.ij] = Ln [W.sub.i] - Ln [W.sub.j] = [[f.sub.i]([X.sub.i]) -
[f.sub.i] ([X.sub.j]) + [f.sub.i]([X.sub.j]) - [f.sub.i]([X.sub.j])] ...
(5)
where [f.sub.i]([X.sub.j]) is the mean wage that employees of
sector j would receive if they were paid according to the wage structure
of sector i.
[D.sub.ij] = [[summation][[beta].sub.i] [X.sub.i] - [summation]
[[beta].sub.i] [X.sub.j]] + [[summation][[beta].sub.i] [X.sub.j] -
[summation][[beta].sub.j] [X.sub.j]] ... (6)
= [summation][[beta].sub.i] [X.sub.i] - [X.sub.j] +
[summation][[beta].sub.i] - [[beta].sub.j]] [X.sub.j] ... (7)
The first term in Equation (7) gives the part of the total
difference in the average logarithmic earnings of the two groups of
workers that exists due to the difference in the average amounts of
earnings-related characteristics, and the second term gives the part due
to total difference in average logarithmic earnings of the two groups,
which exists due to the rate at which both sectors compensate their
workers having the same characteristics. The size of this term will
depend on the difference in the values of the regression coefficients
estimated from earnings equations of the two groups. This strategy
allows the determination of the part attributable simply to a difference
in the structure of pay and a difference in the endowment of the workers
which drive a wedge between pay levels in different sectors of
employment.
IV. DATA CHARACTERISTICS AND LIMITATIONS
The data set used in this study is drawn from the Labour Force
Surrey (LFS) 1996-97, collected by the Federal Bureau of Statistics (FBS). The LFS data provide detailed socio-economic information about
more than 110,000 individuals. The information on labour market
activities is provided on the individuals of 10 years of age and older.
To adjust for seasonal variations, the data collection is spread overall
the years. The survey collects comprehensive information on various
activities of workers. The information about age, literacy, education,
training, occupation, employer type, and earnings is particularly
important for this study. Before proceeding to other details of the
data, it is imperative to say a few words about the information
collected through the Labour Force Surveys in Pakistan. Since 1965, the
Labour Force Surveys are the major source of information of labour
market statistics. A comparison of the LFS with other data sources shows
the superiority of the LFS because of greater internal and external
consistencies [Zeeuw (1996)]. Since 1990, the questionnaire of the LFS
has been revised twice and a numbers of other changes are made to
improve the quality of data collection as well as coverage of different
sub-groups. The latest Labour Force Surrey 1996-97, used in this study,
properly identifies the public, private, and informal sectors of
employment. (10) This feature of the LFS is lacking in other surveys of
this series. The main problem was the identification of the informal
sector. The following guidelines are used in the LFS 1996-97 to identify
the informal sector:
(i) all household enterprises owned and operated by own-account
workers, irrespective of the size of the enterprise (informal
own-account enterprises);
(ii) household enterprises owned and operated by employers with
less than 10 persons engaged; and
(iii) all household enterprises engaged in agricultural activities
or wholly engaged in non-market production excluded.
The data set indicates that the informal sector is the biggest in
size on the basis of employment as compared to the other sectors. It
absorbs about two-thirds, i.e., 64.6 percent of the non-agricultural
labour force. It is found that 36.7 percent of the workers in the
informal sector are self-employed, 26.5 percent are unpaid family
helpers, and 23.2 percent are engaged in piece-rate work or other casual
work. The regular wage and salary workers, another important group,
forms 11.3 percent of the informal sector employment.
This survey provides data on all categories of the labour force in
the public and private sectors. Employees of the federal, provincial,
and local government and other establishments run by the government
administration are included in the public sector. The employees of big
establishments employing more than ten workers are included in the
private formal sector. Although the final sample of the study includes
only regular wage employees, the survey sample covers all sorts of
workers. It is observed that the coverage of regular wage employment is
higher in the formal sectors (both in the public and private sectors).
The majority of these individuals is of full-time employees who work
more than 35 hours per week. (11) Accordingly, a higher percentage of
casual or non-regular workers is observed in the informal sector.
The data on earnings include both cash and payments in kind. The
current value of the in-kind benefits such as free or subsidised housing
and transportation is included in the overall earnings reported in the
survey. The other benefits such as bonuses are not included in these
earnings. (12) It is important to mention that the data on earnings is
not available for all sub-groups, but it covers fully the regular wage
and salaried group. Because the aim is to gauge the extent of
exploitation of wage employees, we restricted our sample to only regular
wage and salary workers who reported some earnings. (13)
The final sample of regular salaried workers with positive earnings
consists of 4997 individuals. In that, approximately 56 percent are
employed in the public sector, 18 percent in the private sector, and 26
percent are working in the informal sector. The summary statistics
provided in Table I reveals that there are considerable differences
among workers employed in these sectors. Some of the important
differences are highlighted here as a prelude to the regression
analysis.
It is observed that relatively young and less-educated workers are
employed in the informal sector and the majority of them are either
working as labour or as service workers. It is noted that highly
educated workers are concentrated in the public sector. On average, a
higher percentage (i.e., 11 percent) of these workers have received
vocational or on-the-job training as compared to the workers of the
other sectors. It is consistent with the definition of the informal
sector. The professional, associate professional, and clerical workers
have higher representation in the public sector whereas higher
percentage of managerial workers is located in the private formal
sector. It may also be noted that workers in the public sector, on
average, earn Rs 3902 per month, which is higher than the earnings in
both the private formal and informal sectors.
To further highlight the difference in these sectors, we present
average monthly earnings of workers of different age groups in the
public, private, and informal sectors in Table 2 and plot them in Figure
1. The association of earnings with age signifies the role of experience
for higher earnings because age is used as a proxy for experience in the
analysis. (14) It is interesting to note that although there are
significant differences in compensation for workers in different
sectors, yet the age-earnings profiles follow the life-cycle pattern in
all three sectors of employment where income increases with age for some
time, reaches the peak and then declines. Some interesting observations
can be made on the basis of these age-earnings profiles.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The workers in the public sector start at a higher level of
earnings and reach a higher peak as compared to the other two sectors.
They attain the highest level of earnings in the age group 51-60.
Because of the slow rise in the earnings of the public sector employees,
the profile of the private formal sector workers surpasses the profile
of the public sector employees in age group 21-30. The profile of public
sector employees remains below the profile of the private formal sector
workers till the age group 31-40 but surpasses it afterwards. The
earnings of the workers in the public sector stay at a higher level till
the age of 60 as compared to the private formal sector when the earnings
of the private formal sector again exceed theirs. The main reason behind
the smooth age-earnings profile of the public sector employees till age
60 is the relatively uniform pay scale system adopted by the government.
The sharp decline in the earnings experienced by the public sector
employees afterwards is due to the retirement benefits, which are much
lower than the regular job benefits. The age-earnings profile of workers
in the private formal sector shows lower earnings at the start but then
there is a sharp rise in the earnings with age, till the age group
41-50, when their earnings reach the peak and start declining
afterwards. The decline in the earnings of the private sector workers is
slow and smooth, unlike the public sector workers, who experience a
sharp decline once they reach the peak of their earnings.
Interestingly, the peak in the informal sector is attained in the
age group 31-40, much earlier than in the other two sectors of
employment. Moreover, the peak earnings of the informal sector are also
lower than the peak earnings of the other sectors. This is in conformity
with the characteristics of informal sector employment. The profile of
these workers remains below the profile of the other two sectors. This
means that the life-long earnings of the workers in the informal sector
are lower than in the other sectors of employment. This shows the
vulnerability of workers to the conditions of the informal sector, where
workers have no legal protection against unjust wages and working
conditions.
On the basis of this information, it seems that there are
significant differences in the characteristics and earnings of workers
in these three sectors, it is, therefore, imperative to further explore
these sectors to see what factors play the major role in wage
determination and the extent of differential in earnings in these
sectors. The ordinary least squares estimation technique is used to
control for different characteristics of the workers and gauge the
difference in earnings. The regression results and decomposition of wage
differential are presented in the next section.
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The estimates of the earnings functions for different sectors are
reported in Table 3. The Chow test reveals that there are structural
differences in these sectors and a single equation does not explain the
differences in earnings. For this reason, separate equations are
estimated for all three sectors. Judged by the F-statistics and adjusted
[[bar.R].sup.2], model specification is good and the majority of the
variables included in the models are important determinants of earnings.
It is further noted that most of the variables included in the earnings
equations are estimated with statistical precision (low standard error).
Although the pattern of estimated coefficients displays no major
surprise, there is some difference, which needs to be addressed. It is
noted that the importance of human capital varies by sector. In general,
the magnitude of coefficients for different educational categories is
relatively smaller in the public sector than the magnitude in both the
private formal and informal sectors. The private formal sector does not
treat workers with five years of education differently from those with
no education, as there is no statistically significant premium
associated for five years of education in this sector. The premium for
primary education in the public sector is 6.40 percent, whereas in the
private informal sector it is 24.7 percent, which is quite high relative
to that in the public sector. As the demand for higher education is low
in the informal sector as compared to the other two sectors, workers
with below-degree education have much higher returns relative to
illiterates in the informal sector in comparison with the other sectors.
The relatively high demand of educational skills of workers in the
private formal sector is fetching the highest rewards for degree
education (both simple and professional) relative to illiterates in this
sector. (15)
The coefficients of variable AGE (proxy for experience) in all
three sectors are statistically significant but different in magnitude.
The highest earnings are associated with the private informal sector
followed by the private formal sector. In the public sector, the returns
are almost half those in the private informal sector. The negative and
statistically significant square term of age confirms the non-linear
age-earnings profiles in all three sectors of employment.
Training has a positive impact on earnings because it brings 9.02
percent, 8.84 percent, and 7.11 percent premium for public, private
formal, and private informal sector workers respectively. The high
returns associated with training in the public sector suggest that
workers get benefit in the form of incremental salary, additional
allowance, or promotion due to training, in accordance with the
government policy. The higher earnings associated with age, education,
and training provide clear support to the human capital theory in the
public and private sector [Becket (1964) and Mincer (1974)]. (16)
The returns to non-human capital variables are also the source of
difference in the estimates of different sectors. For example, marriage
is associated with higher wages for men in the U.S. labour market.
Married workers earn more because they are more productive than single
workers [Becket (1981, 1985); Kenny (1983); Greenhalgh (1980)]. It has
also been claimed that married workers have characteristics such as
punctuality and motivation, which are valued highly by the employer and
therefore higher wages are paid to such workers [Nakosteen and Zimmer
(1982); Becker (1981); Keely (1977)]. In this study, the premium on
marriage is significantly high in both the private formal and informal
sectors as compared to the public sector, where returns are not
significantly different from zero. As there are no considerations for
efficiency and productivity in the public sector, these findings are not
surprising. The private formal and informal sectors pay more to married
workers due to their consideration for productivity-enhancing
characteristics of workers.
The coefficients associated with different occupations reveal that
managerial workers earn the highest premium and the service workers earn
the least in all three sectors. The premium associated with managerial
work is 69.2 percent, 68.7 percent, and 34.6 percent in the public,
private, and informal sectors respectively. (17) It is noted that
professional workers earn a significantly higher premium in all three
sectors but associate professionals earn statistically significant
premium in only the public sector. Furthermore, the clerical workers do
not earn statistically significant premium in the informal sector,
whereas the returns are 8 percent and 12.5 percent in the public and
private formal sectors respectively. Production workers receive the
highest premium in the private sector, where they earn 25.6 percent more
than the reference group. The returns for drivers and other skilled
workers such as machine-operators are also high in the formal sector,
where they earn 21 percent higher wages relative to those of the
labourers. The returns for these workers are 9.9 percent and 17.6
percent in the public and informal sectors respectively.
Decomposition of Earnings Differential
The differential in the earnings is calculated by using statistics
in Table 1 and estimates of earnings functions presented in Table 3. The
decomposition of earnings differential is based on the Equation 7.
First, we shall discuss the earnings differential between the public and
private sectors, and this will be followed by the earnings differential
between the public and the informal sectors. The earnings differential
between the private formal and informal sectors will be discussed at the
end.
Public and Private Formal Sector
The statistics presented in Table 1 reveals that workers, on
average, earn monthly earnings of Rs 3902 in the public sector and Rs
3697 in the private formal sector. This suggests that workers in the
public sector earn Rs 205 more than the private formal sector workers.
(18) This difference in average earnings is the result of the difference
in average endowments (wage-related characteristics) of workers and the
difference in the pay structure of the public and private sectors. The
decomposition of this difference is presented in Table 4. The table
contains two columns, which present the relative contribution of each
factor in the earnings differential of these sectors.
Our calculations indicate that workers in the public sector
establishments earn 215.49 percent more due to their superior endowments
and 115.37 percent less due to their pay structure. (19) In rupee terms,
public sector workers earn Rs 442 more than private sector due to their
endowments and earn Rs 237 per month less than private sector workers
due to their poor pay structure. In this case, public sector employees
with the same endowments are compensated at a lower rate as compared to
private sector workers. If both kinds of workers were paid at the same
rate (by private pay structure), the public sector workers would have
received monthly earnings of Rs 4187.93, which is Rs 286.10 more than
what they receive currently in the public sector. These hypothetical earnings are 13 percent more than those in the private sector. This
suggests that workers in the public sector are not paid according to
their skills and, therefore, are subject to exploitation.
The contribution of each variable towards the part of differential
that exists due to personal characteristics is presented in Column 2 of
Table 4. The positive sign associated with the factor in this column
indicates that workers in the public sector enjoy the earnings advantage
due to that particular factor whereas the negative sign means that
workers of the other sector are receiving higher benefits due to that
characteristic. The calculations presented in Table 4 indicate that
Column 2 contains more positive signs than negative signs. It is also
noted that the magnitude of the factors with positive signs is greater
than the factors with negative signs. This suggests that workers in the
public sector establishments earn more than those in the private sector
because their wage-related characteristics favour them more than the
private sector workers. It is observed that the human capital factors
such as education and experience are benefiting public sector employees
more than private sector workers.
The earnings differential due to structural difference in the two
sectors is presented in Column 3 of Table 4. It is observed that there
are more negative signs than positive ones in the column. This implies
that workers in the private establishments are compensated at a higher
rate for the same characteristics in comparison to public sector
workers. This reduces the overall earnings advantage of public sector
employees which they receive due to their superior endowments. In
general, our results are in line with other studies [Gunderson (1979);
Mann and Kapoor (1988); Gaag, Stelcner, and Vijverberg (1989)].
Public and Private Informal Sector
The earnings differential between the public and private informal
sectors and its decomposition into different parts are presented in
Table 5. For the calculations of this differential, the same technique
as discussed in the previous section is utilised. We observed that there
is a big gap between these sectors in terms of the earnings of workers.
The total differential in the average log monthly earnings of the public
and the informal sector is 0.5261. The decomposition of this
differential indicates that human capital and other wage-related
characteristics account for 0.3299 of the differential. The pay
structure contributes 0.1962 to the total differential as public sector
workers are paid at a higher rate than those in the informal sector for
the same characteristics. In rupee terms, the differential, on average,
stands at Rs 1596 per month in favour of public sector workers. Of this
total differential, Rs 1001 exists due to the difference in the personal
characteristics of the worker and a difference of Rs 595 exists due to
the difference in the pay structure of the public and the informal
sector. In this case, workers in the informal sector are compensated at
a lower rate than public sector workers for the same characteristics.
The informal sector workers would have earned Rs 3205 instead of Rs 2306
if they were paid at the public sector rate for their characteristics.
The contribution of different characteristics presented in Column 2
of Table 5 indicates that age and higher education (i.e., Matric and
above) offer more gain to public sector employees whereas training and
below-Matric education favours informal sector workers. From Column 3,
it is observed that most of the characteristics have a negative sign,
indicating that workers in the informal sector are paid at a higher rate
than the public sector workers for the same characteristics. These
findings highlight the extent of exploitation of the workers in the
informal sector as compared to employees in the public sector.
Private Formal and Informal Wage Differential
We have adopted the same methodology to calculate the wage
differential of the private formal and informal sectors. The earnings
differential and its decomposition are presented in Table 6. The
observed total differential in the private formal sector and informal
sector is 0.4720. The part of total differential that exists due to the
difference in endowment is 0.2526, and the part due to the difference in
wage structure is 0.2195. This decomposition suggests that workers in
the private sector not only have higher endowments but are also
compensated at a higher rate than those in the informal sector for the
same characteristics and endowments. In rupee terms, workers in the
private formal sector earn Rs 1391 more than the informal sector worker.
These workers earn Rs 745 more due to the superior contents of their
human capital and other endowments, and Rs 647 due to the superior pay
structure. If workers in the informal sector were paid according to the
pay structure of the private sector, they would have earned Rs 2847
instead of Rs 2305.61.
Column 2 of Table 6 indicates that most of the factors favour the
private formal sector workers, as there are few negative signs in that
Column. The informal sector workers receive the benefits of eight and
less years of schooling, including literacy and training. Column 3
indicates that for most of the characteristics, the private sector
workers are paid at a higher rate, which increases their earnings
significantly over the informal sector workers. This means that workers
in the private formal sector have good prospects not only due to their
personal characteristics but also due to the rate at which they are
compensated.
The decomposition of earnings differentials supports the view that
informal workers face more exploitation as compared to the other
sectors. These results support our hypothesis regarding the workers in
the informal sector. Another startling finding is about the public
sector employees who are found to be equipped with superior endowments
but are subject to exploitation by the public sector. If they were paid
according to their endowments, they would have earned much more than
what they were actually earning.
VI. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The analysis of the earnings differential in the public, private,
and informal sector is presented in this article. The main purpose of
this study is to highlight the exploitation of wage employees in
different sectors of employment in Pakistan. The role of personal
characteristics of urban male workers is explored in the first part
while the earnings differential and its decomposition is presented in
the second part of the study. The earnings functions that include human
capital and other endowments are estimated separately for each sector.
The results show that the informal sector workers are exploited due
not only to their poor skills but also the wage structure of the
informal sector. The public sector employees have superior endowments
but the wage structure in that sector does not favour them. This is an
indication of their exploitation. Only workers of the private formal
sector enjoy both the benefits of their skills and the wage structure of
the sector.
The regression estimates of employees of different sectors indicate
that the human capital variables are the major determinants of their
wages. The other variables such as the occupation of workers have some
role in the public, private, formal, and informal sectors. The wage
premium for married workers is quite high in the private (both formal
and informal) sector whereas no premium has been found in the case of
public sector work. This result is in line with the rules determining
the wages in the public sector.
The decomposition of the wage differential indicates that the
earnings advantage for the employees in the public sector is mainly due
to the superior contents of their human capital and other endowments. It
is further noted that the earnings advantage due to personal
characteristics and endowments in the public sector is offset by the
wage structure of private sector that pays compensation at higher rates
for the same characteristics relative to the public sector. In the case
of the informal sector, the benefit of both personal characteristics and
wage structure goes to the public sector. Similarly, the benefit of
personal characteristics and wage structure goes to the formal sector
when the wage differential within the private sector is decomposed.
One can draw many policy implications from this analysis. The major
concern is the exploitation of workers in the informal sector. This
sector needs immediate attention from the government, first, to start
the programmes to train and educate these workers. Secondly, they should
be provided a protective cover so that the exploitation stops. The
labour policy should include some measures to discourage the
casualisation of jobs for the benefit of these workers. As for public
sector workers, they should he compensated according to their endowments
and more incentives be given to more productive workers. If these
measures are not implemented, the public sector will lose its skilled or
talented manpower, which may have serious repercussions for the economy
as a whole.
Author's Note: I wish to thank A, R. Kemal, Director, PIDE,
and an anonymous referee of this journal for valuable suggestions. I
alone bear responsibility for any shortcomings of the paper.
REFERENCES
Afzal, M., and Zafar Mueen Nasir (1987) Is Female Labour Force
Participation Really Low and Declining in Pakistan? A Look at
Alternative Data Sources. The Pakistan Development Review 26:4 699-710.
Ashraf, J., and B. Ashraf (1993) An Analysis of the Male-Female
Earnings Differential in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 32:4
895-904.
Becket, G. (1964) Human Capital. New York: Columbia University
Press.
Becker, G. (1981) A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, Mass:
Harvard University Press.
Becker, G. (1985) Human Capital, Effort, and the Sexual Division of
Labour. Journal of Labour Economics 3: 33-58.
Bilquees, Faiz (1994) Real Wages of the Federal Government
Employees: Trends from 1977-78 to 1991-92. The Pakistan Development
Review 33:229-251.
Birdsall, Nancy, and L. Fox (1985) Why Males Earn More: Location
and Training of Brazilian Schoolteachers. Economic Development and
Cultural Change 33: 533-56.
Blinder, Alan (1973) Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and
Structural Estimates. Journal of Human Resource 8: 827-55.
Faruqee, R., Ridwan Ali, and Yusuf Choudhry (1995) Pakistan's
Public Agriculture Enterprises: Inefficiencies, Market Distortions, and
Proposals for Reform. The World Bank, Washington, D. C. (World Bank
Discussion Papers No. 305.)
Gaag, V. D. J., M. Stelcner, and W. P. M. Vijverberg (1989)
Public-Private Sector Wage Comparisons and Moonlighting in Developing
Countries: Evidence from Cote d' Ivoire and Peru, Living Standards Measurement Study. The World Bank, Washington, D. C. (Working Paper No.
52.)
Ghayur, Sabur (1993) The Informal Sector of Pakistan: Problems and
Policies. Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Islamabad. (The Informal Sector
Study No. 3.)
Greenhalgh, C. (1980) Male-Female Wage Differentials in Great
Britain: Is Marriage an Equal Opportunity? Economic Journal 90: 751-775.
Gunderson, M. (1979) Earnings Differentials between the Public and
Private Sectors. Canadian Journal of Economics 12: 228-242.
Irfan, M. (1983) Determinants of Female Labour Force Participation
in Pakistan. Studies in Population, Labour Force and Migration Project.
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. (Report No. 5.)
Keeley, M. (1977) The Economics of Family Formation. Economic
Inquiry 15: 238-250.
Kemal, A. R., and Zafar Mahmood (1993) Labour Absorption in the
Informal Sector and Economic Growth in Pakistan.
Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Islamabad.
Kenny, L. (1983) The Accumulation of Human Capital during Marriage
by Males. Economic Inquiry 21: 223-231.
Knight, J. B., and R. H. Sabot (1982) Labour Market Discrimination
in a Poor Urban Economy. The Journal of Development Studies 19: 67-87.
Lindauer, D. L., and R. H. Sabot (1983) The Public/Private Wage
Differential in a Poor Urban Economy. Journal of Development Economics
12: 137-52.
Malkiel, B. G., and J. A. Malkiel (1973) Male-Female Differential
in Professional Employment. American Economic Review 63: 693-705.
Mann, P. S., and B. L. Kapoor (1988) Earnings Differentials between
Public, Private, and Joint Sectors in Punjab (India). The Journal of
Development Studies 25: 97-111.
Mincer, J. (1974) Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York:
NBER and Columbia University Press.
Nakosteen, R,. and M. Zimmer (1982) Marital Status and Earnings of
Young Men. Journal of Human Resources 22: 248-268.
Smith, S. (1976) Pay Differentials between Federal Government and
Private Sector Workers. Industrial and Labour Relations Review
29:179-97.
Terrell, Katherine (1993) Public-Private Wage Differential in
Haiti: Do Public Servants Earn a Rent? Journal of Development Economics
42:293-314.
Zeeuw, Martin de. (1996) The Household Integrated Economic Survey
of Pakistan 1990-91: Internal and External Consistency. The Pakistan
Development Review 35:1 71-84.
(1) For example, see Smith (1976); Gunderson (1979); Lindauer and
Sabot (1983) and others.
(2) Despite the ban on vacancies, the Government recruited new
staff in the 1990s in the presence of over-manning in various
departments.
(3) This situation persists despite the fact that real wages of all
the Federal Government servants were found to be negative over the
entire period of 1977-92 [Bilquees (1994)].
(4) The new estimates of the Labour Force Survey 1996-97 measure
the informal sector employment at 64.4 percent, which is the highest of
all sectors.
(5) Other studies either focused on the public and private sectors
only or included a third sector, which is not well-defined. For example,
Mann and Kapoor (1988) included joint sector, which has elements of both
the public and private sectors. Terrell (1993) divided the public sector
into two sectors, i.e., publicly run establishments and public
administration. These divisions are not helpful to distinguish the
sectors clearly in the case of Pakistan.
(6) Based on different sources of information, female labour market
participation is low as compared to their male counterparts [Afzal and
Nasir (1987)]. There are social and cultural arguments for this, but the
dominant among them is the enumeration problem [Irfan (1983)]. Most of
the information is missing on females and that creates estimation and
comparison problems.
(7) Age as a proxy for experience is used due to the
non-availability of data on actual experience. The other method to
calculate experience, i.e., age-education-6 is not possible as the data
on education is available for levels instead of years. The other reason
for not using the imputed experience is to avoid bias in estimates as
the school-going age in Pakistan is not uniform [Ashraf and Ashraf
(1993)].
(8) A statistically significant F-value will identify the
structural difference in the sectors and will lead to the conclusion
that these sectors be analysed separately.
(9) This strategy is commonly used in the literature to decompose wages of different groups [Blinder (1973), Birdsall and Fox (1985);
Malkiel and Malkiel (1973); and Knight and Sabot (1982)].
(10) There is detailed discussion on data issues in Pakistan in
Chapter One of the ILO Discussion Paper No. 33, which addressed the
employment, output, and productivity issues of Pakistan (2000).
(11) Those who work less than 35 hours are considered
under-employed in the survey.
(12) Such an inclusion would increase the differential even
further. We did not include this because of the low reporting of these
benefits.
(13) The sub-groups such as the self-employed, women, unpaid family
helpers, non-regular workers, and rural workers are excluded from the
analysis. The self-employed are excluded because it is difficult to
disentangle returns to physical capital and human capital and, secondly,
they do not fall strictly in the wage-earners' category. Women are
excluded due to their low coverage in the surveys in Pakistan. Another
reason is the problem with properly specifying their wage function due
to their sudden withdrawal and entry in the labour market. Unpaid family
helpers do not earn any wages, and non-regular and casual workers do not
qualify the criteria laid down for sample selection. As the rural sector
wage employment is very limited, therefore we exclude them also from the
analysis.
(14) It is important to note that the earnings associated with
different age groups do not show the returns to experience only. There
are other factors which also affect earnings and are not controlled here
to disentangle the returns to experience. The regression analysis will
be used to separate these returns.
(15) The highest returns are associated with professional education
in all three sectors
(16) Although the returns to public sector employees are determined
by the government pay policy, yet education does play a role to qualify
them for the jobs or for other benefits in the public sector.
(17) The estimated premiums are relative to labour, which is the
excluding category
(18) In the case of developed countries, Gunderson (1979) found 6.2
percent wage advantage for Canadian workers whereas Smith found 7
percent wage premium for US workers in the public sector. In developing
countries, Mann and Kapoor (1988) found a relatively high premium in
favour of the public sector workers in the Indian state of Punjab
whereas Gaag, Stelcner, and Vijverberg (1989) found no wage premium in
the case of workers of Peru and Cote d'Ivoire.
(19) It is noted that the proportion of workers with ten and more
years of schooling in the public sector is higher than in the private
sector (see Table 1).
Zafar Mueen Nasir is Senior Research Economist at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Definition and Summary Statistics of Variables
Symbol Definition Public Private
N Number of Observations 2793 890
Mean Mean
ln W Log of Monthly Earnings 8.2692 8.2152
(0.53) (0.60)
Human Capital Background
AGE Age in Years 37.13 34.12
ILL Having no Formal Education (Proportion) .1204 .2156
PRIM Completed Five Years of Schooling .0714 .0865
(Proportion)
MIDD Completed Eight Years of Schooling .0792 .1371
(Proportion)
MAT Completed Ten Years of Schooling .3915 .3124
(Proportion)
DEG General Degree Education (Proportion) .1545 .1337
PDEG Professional Degree Education .1527 .0843
(Proportion)
LIT Literacy (Proportion) .0303 .0304
TRAIN Job Training (Proportion) .0878 .1099
Occupations
PRO Professional (Proportion) .1834 .0843
APRO Associate Professional (Proportion) .1228 .0697
MANG Managerial Workers (Proportion) .1089 .1180
SERV Service (Proportion) .1271 .0910
CLER Clerical Workers (Proportion) .2077 .1382
OPER Operators and Drivers (Proportion) .0689 .1787
PROD Production Workers (Proportion) .0482 .1607
LABOR Labourers (Proportion) .1331 .1596
Other Characteristics
MS Marital Status (Proportion) .8319 .6876
Symbol Definition Informal Total
N Number of Observations 1314 4997
Mean Mean
ln W Log of Monthly Earnings 7.7431 8.1321
(0.54) (0.59)
Human Capital Background
AGE Age in Years 32.07 35.27
ILL Having no Formal Education (Proportion) .3599 .2001
PRIM Completed Five Years of Schooling .1743 .1011
(Proportion)
MIDD Completed Eight Years of Schooling .1446 .1067
(Proportion)
MAT Completed Ten Years of Schooling .2245 .3336
(Proportion)
DEG General Degree Education (Proportion) .0320 .1187
PDEG Professional Degree Education .0183 .1053
(Proportion)
LIT Literacy (Proportion) .0464 .0345
TRAIN Job Training (Proportion) .1100 .0976
Occupations
PRO Professional (Proportion) .0251 .1243
APRO Associate Professional (Proportion) .0464 .0933
MANG Managerial Workers (Proportion) .0259 .0887
SERV Service (Proportion) .2785 .1604
CLER Clerical Workers (Proportion) .0563 .1556
OPER Operators and Drivers (Proportion) .1644 .1135
PROD Production Workers (Proportion) .1766 .1019
LABOR Labourers (Proportion) .2268 .1625
Other Characteristics
MS Marital Status (Proportion) .5822 .7405
Note: Figures in parenthesis are the standard deviation.
Table 2
Average Monthly Earnings of Male Workers, by ,4ge Croup
Employer/
Occupation Public Private Informal Total
10-20 2413.8 2234.8 1681.7 1935.1
21-30 3492.7 3850.3 2547.8 3299.3
31-40 4397.4 5283.5 3249.0 4330.5
41-50 5396.1 5287.4 3007.0 4970.1
510 6184.7 5122.3 2822.1 5186.2
61+ 3144.7 4695.0 2449.7 2993.7
Total 3901.8 3696.7 2305.6 3401.9
Table 3
Coefficients of Ordinary Least Square Estimates for Different Sectors
(Dependent 0ariable = Log Monthly Earnings)
Variables Public Private Informal
Constant 6.9260 *** 6.6220 *** 6.1670 ***
(76.43) (49.40) (70.36)
AGE 0.0352 *** 0.0506 *** 0.0682 ***
(7.03) (6.38) (12.25)
AGESQ -0.0003 *** -0.0006 *** -0.0008 ***
(-4.80) (-5.74) (-11.27)
LITRACY 0.0549 0.0472 0.1450 ***
(1.22) (0.56) (2.51)
PRIM 0.0622 * 0.0824 0.221 ***
(1.87) (1.48) (6.42)
MIDD 0.1170 *** 0.1220 *** 0.3060 ***
(3.584) (2.54) (8.13)
MAT 0.2410 *** 0.3080 *** 0.3360 ***
(9.09) (7.14) (9.81)
DEG 0.5140 *** 0.6880 *** 0.6600 ***
(16.04) (11.75) (8.46)
PDEG 0.7270 *** 0.8360 *** 0.7470 ***
(21.73) (12.19) (6.78)
TRAIN 0.0864 *** 0.0847 * 0.0687 *
(3.43) (1.89) (1.77)
MANG 0.5260 *** 0.5230 *** 0.2970 ***
(15.31) (8.14) (3.74)
PROF 0.1780 *** 0.3470 *** 0.3040 ***
(5.82) (5.16) (2.98)
APROF 0.0851 *** 0.0431 0.0175
(2.73) (0.66) (0.281)
CLERK 0.0780 *** 0.1180 ** 0.0562
(2.76) (2.14) (0.976)
SERV 0.0057 0.0355 0.0029
(0.21) (0.61) (0.088)
PROD 0.0909 *** 0.2280 *** 0.0717 *
(2.40) (4.65) (1.90)
OPRAT 0.0942 *** 0.1920 *** 0.1620 ***
(2.81) (3.97) (4.11)
MS 0.0167 0.1440 *** 0.0644 *
(0.73) (3.38) (1.76)
F-statistics 171.78 61.21 50.39
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.509 0.535 0.390
N 2793 890 1314
* Signiticant at 10 percent level.
** Signiticant at 5 percent level.
*** Significant at 1 percent level.
Table 4
Relative Contribution of Variables to the Earnings Differential
behveen the Public and Private Formal Sectors
Wage
Variables Endowment Structure Total
Constant 0 0.3155 0.3155
AGE 0.105952 -0.525448 -0.419496
AGESQ -0.064339 0.349252 0.284914
PRIM -0.000939 -0.001747 -0.002687
MIDD -0.006774 -0.000685 -0.00746
MAT 0.019063 -0.020931 -0.001868
DEG 0.010691 -0.023264 -0.012573
PDEG 0.049727 -0.009189 0.040538
LITRACY -0.00000549 0.000234 0.000229
TRAIN -0.001909 0.000187 -0.001723
PROP 0.01764 -0.014247 0.003393
APROF 0.004519 0.002927 0.007446
MANG -0.004787 0.000354 -0.004433
CLERK 0.005421 -0.005528 -0.000107
OPRAT -0.010343 -0.017477 -0.02782
PROD -0.010226 -0.022032 -0.032258
SERV 0.000206 -0.002712 -0.002506
MS 0.00241 -0.087531 -0.085122
TOTAL 0.116305 -0.062336 0.053969
Table 5
Relative Contribution of Variables to the Earnings
Differential betfveen the Public and Informal Sectors
Wage
Variables Endowment Structure Total
Constant 0 0.8515 0.8515
AGE 0.178112 -1.05831 -0.880198
AGESQ -0.105046 0.514242 0.409197
PRIM -0.0064 -0.027679 -0.034079
MIDD -0.007652 -0.027329 -0.034981
MAT 0.040247 -0.021238 0.01892
DEG 0.062965 -0.004672 0.058293
PDEG 0.097709 -0.000366 0.097343
LIT -0.000884 -0.004181 -0.005065
TRAIN -0.001918 0.001947 0.0000289
PROF 0.028177 -0.003163 0.025015
APROF 0.006502 0.003137 0.009638
MANG 0.043658 0.005931 0.049589
CLERK 0.011809 0.001227 0.013037
OPRAT -0.008996 -0.011146 -0.020142
PROD -0.011672 0.003391 -0.008281
SERV -0.000863 0.00076 -0.000103
MS 0.00417 -0.027771 -0.023601
TOTAL 0.329919 0.196191 0.52611
Table 6
Relative Contribution of Variables to the Earnings
Differential between the Public and Private Sectors
Wage
Variables Endowment Structure Total
Constant 0 0.536 0.536
AGE 0.10373 -0.564432 -0.460702
AGESQ -0.081414 0.005697 0.124283
PRIM -0.007235 -0.024158 -0.031393
MIDD -0.000915 -0.026606 -0.027521
MAT 0.027073 -0.006286 0.020787
DEG 0.06997 0.000896 0.070866
PDEG 0.055176 0.001629 0.056805
LIT -0.000755 -0.004538 -0.005293
TRAIN -0.00000847 0.00176 0.001752
PROF 0.020542 0.001079 0.021622
APROF 0.001004 0.001188 0.002192
MANG 0.04868 0.005853 0.054022
CLERK 0.009664 0.003479 0.013144
OPRAT 0.002746 0.004932 0.007678
PROD -0.003625 0.027603 0.023977
SERV -0.006656 0.00906 0.002403
MS 0.015178 0.046343 0.061521
TOTAL 0.252643 0.219499 0.472141