Educational quality and labour market performance in developing countries: some evidence from Pakistan.
Akbari, Ather H. ; Muhammed, Naeem
I. INTRODUCTION
Several studies have shown that investment in the quality of
education has a higher payoff than investment in quantity alone. (1)
However, in many developing countries, investment in improving
educational quality is still accorded a lower priority than investment
in educational quantity. Countries which commit more resources towards
education are generally observed to expand their enrolment ratios while
paying little attention on improving such schooling inputs as
student-teacher ratio that contribute towards improvement of educational
quality (Table 1). (2) There is also a tendency to allocate minimal
resources towards upgrading existing schools by improving quality of
teaching, facilities, and curricula. Greater emphasis is placed on rapid
expansion of the number of educational institutions to reach out a large
proportion of population. (3)
This paper provides further evidence on the benefits of improving
schooling quality in developing countries by analysing data from
Pakistani labour markets. In particular, we focus on obtaining the
quantitative impact of educational quality contributors on the rate of
return to investment in schooling. (4) One can provide several reasons
to highlight the importance of this study for Pakistan. First, the
government of Pakistan launched a comprehensive Social Action Programme
(SAP) in 1993 with the objective of improving the country's social
indicators. The programme covers elementary education, primary health
care, population welfare and rural water supply. Investment on education
is recognised to be the most important determinant of future economic
growth. Hence education is accorded the highest priority, receiving
about 70 percent of designated resources during the first phase of the
programme (1993-96) and expected to receive about 66 percent during the
second phase (1997-2002). However, despite the findings of a World Bank
study [World Bank (1996)] that the class size and teacher qualification
are important determinants of student performance in Pakistan and that
parental demand for education is strongly affected by their perception
of its quality, very little emphasis has been placed in the programme on
improving this component of educational planning. This is evident in
poor performances of two important educational quality indicators: (1)
the student-teacher ratio at the primary school level which reflects a
student's exposure to his/her teacher and (2) the percentage of
trained teachers teaching in primary schools. Over the four year period
ending in 1997 since the inception of SAP, the number of primary schools
in Pakistan rose by about 22 percent, and the corresponding student
population rose by 30 percent. However, the student-teacher ratio
remained unchanged at its pre-programme level (Figure 1). (5)
Furthermore, while more than 90 percent of teachers teaching in primary
schools are classified by the government statistics as
"trained", about 93 percent of these teachers had low levels
of training [Pakistan (1996)]. (6)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Yet another indication of the low priority given to educational
quality improvement in the SAP is the absence of any direct information
collected by the Pakistan Integrated Household Survey (PIHS) on the
profiles of school teachers and the delivery of education in schools.
(7)
The second reason for the importance of this study is the
relationship between child labour and the quality of education.
According to a Human Rights Commission report published in 1994, around
12 million Pakistani children under the age of 14 (half of these being
under the age of 10), work as indentured servants for wages [Todaro
(1999)]. Although these wages are pitiably low, nevertheless, they
represent an opportunity cost of attending school for these children.
Sensitivity to this opportunity cost will be greater if the educational
system failed to offer good quality education thereby raising future
economic prospects for the household. Indeed the World Bank study [World
Bank (1996)] also observed the relationship between educational quality
and parental demand for education in Pakistan by noting that "Poor
parents in Pakistan are willing to sacrifice a great deal to educate
their children if they believe the education will be of sufficient
quality to justify the cost and effort". (p. 10). (8) A Pakistani
newspaper also reported recently that 40 percent
'out-of-school' kids in South Asia are from Pakistan and that
dismal educational quality is one of the main reasons for this poor
achievement of the education sector [Business Recorder (2000)].
Finally, a quantitative assessment of the importance of educational
quality enhancement can direct policy-makers in establishing priorities
within the education sector.
Section II provides a brief overview of the state of school and
university level education in Pakistan. Method used to analyse the
impact of educational quality on educational returns is presented in
Section III which also discusses the data used for analysis and the
econometric model employed. Section IV discusses the results of
econometric estimation and the resulting magnitude of educational
quality impact on educational rate of return. Section V concludes the
study.
II. EDUCATION IN PAKISTAN: A BRIEF OVERVIEW
Since the birth of Pakistan in 1947, its educational planning
relative to other countries in the South Asian region can be
characterised as full of high ambitions but very little achievements.
Saad (1999) notes that the Pakistani education sector has suffered in
the hands of "political undulations and instability experienced by
the country intermittently". Six policy documents have been
produced on education, all of which reflect a political emphasis and one
observes no sequential transition from one policy to another. As a
consequence, education has suffered on both counts of quantity and
quality. Table 2 provides an inter country comparison of educational
data, available for 1990, for five South Asian countries, it is observed
that Pakistan's educational expenditure was about 3.4 percent of
GNP, slightly exceeded by India only. However, its illiteracy rate was
among the highest in the region, at about 65 percent which was lower
than Nepal's only.
Although the participation rate at primary education level is about
75 percent, half of the children who are enrolled drop out. (9)
According to Pakistan (1998), the main reason for this high drop out
rate is "poor quality of instruction, harsh attitude of teachers,
lack of physical facilities and inefficient managerial system".
Ahmed (1997) has noted that in the 1990s, approximately one-quarter of
the primary school teachers were untrained, 16 percent of primary
schools were without a building of their own and the number of teachers
per school was considerably low in less developed areas. These
statistics are even poorer in less developed provinces and rural
regions.
Another study based on the Pakistan Integrated Household Survey
(PIHS) whose findings are reported in Pakistan (1998a) has attributed
two other demand side factors, income and parental education, to be
important determinants of school enrolments. Parental education affects
male and female enrolments differently in that mother's education
affects only girls' enrolments while father's education
affects both. In rural areas, school distance is important in
determining girl enrolments.
The state of higher education in the public sector is also very
discouraging. Pasha (1995) highlights the problems which affect the
delivery capability of higher education systems of many developing
countries to include "under endowed institutions, demoralised administrations, dismotivated faculty and students, poor quality
instructions, campus violence, irrelevant and outdated nature of
curricula". Pakistan is no exception to this general rule.
Political interference on campus has further aggravated the problems
facing public sector universities in Pakistan. Universities are
unresponsive to the forces of market demand and are mostly
supply-oriented. Their research base is rather weak.
Khan (1991) provides evidence on inefficient utilisation of
resources in public sector universities in Pakistan. Examining data on
three public sector universities, his research shows the existence of
significant excess capacity. Extremely low passing rates in public
universities is another indication of inefficient utilisation of public
resources. Less than half of the students who appear for their degree
examinations are able to pass and a significant proportion of those who
do pass do so with mediocre performance that is valued very low in the
labour market. The poor performance of students in public sector
universities is partly attributed to easy entry requirements in those
universities.
It is interesting to note, however, that several Centres of
Excellence, Centres of Advanced Studies, Area Study Centres and
mono-disciplinary institutions that are affiliated with public
universities have made good contributions and have been applauded
internationally. (10) This shows that with appropriate restructuring of
the system it is possible to improve the quality of higher education in
Pakistan.
One outcome of the dismal picture of the public education system in
Pakistan, as noted by Khan (1999) has been the emergence of
"dualism" in the education sector whereby a high quality
private sector schooling has grown with a poor and deteriorating quality
public sector schooling. Since the 1980s, enrolments in private sector
schools have quadrupled (11) which is reflective of a general discontent
of public school system. Zaidi (1999) notes that even low income areas
have their fair share of private schools, simply because there is a
demand for a minimum standard of quality, which most government schools
are unable to provide. However, he also notes that the lack of any
regulations and controls of entry into the education sector may also
have resulted in some deterioration of the quality of private sector
education. (12)
Despite the growth of private sector schools and universities which
are generally perceived to be providers of better quality education,
public sector will continue to play a major role in provision of
education at all levels in Pakistan. This is mainly due to (1) the high
cost of education in the private sector which makes the private sector
education inaccessible for general population and (2) the unwillingness
of bureaucrats in that country to engage into any political risk and
hence the desire to maintain status quo by continuing to subsidise education despite past inefficiencies [Pasha (1995)]. (13) To produce
labour force members that are comparable to those produced by better
quality private sector institutions, policy-makers will have to respond
aggressively to change the labour market's perception of public
sector education by committing resources towards better delivery of
education.
III. METHODOLOGY AND DATA
In economics of education literature, benefits of educational
quality improvement have been measured by analysing the effect of
educational quality enhancing variables on two outcomes: student
achievement on standardised test scores [for e.g., World Bank (1996) and
Kingdon (1996)] and post schooling earnings of individuals [Behrman and
Birdsall (1983); Card and Krueger (1992, 1992a, etc.)]. Various
schooling inputs are viewed as contributors of better schooling quality.
These include the physical infrastructure, availability of books,
student-teacher ratio, educational qualifications of teachers,
expenditure per student, average term length, average teacher pay, etc.
(14) A summary of the findings on the impacts of each of these schooling
inputs on schooling outcomes in various developing countries can be
found in Harbison and Hanushek (1992).
In relation to Pakistan, we were able to find two studies that
assess the role of relevant schooling inputs in enhancing educational
quality impacts. One study, Nasir and Nazli (2000) has analysed the role
of education, technical training, school quality and literacy and
numeracy skills on the earnings of wage earners and salaried persons by
using micro data based on the PIHS of 1995-96. Assuming private schools
to be providers of better quality education, these authors include a
dummy variable for private schools in their model. The results indicate
a 7 percent rate of return associated with each additional year of
schooling. Private schooling has positive, significant and substantial
effect on individual earnings. A graduate of private school earns 31
percent higher income compared to the graduate of public school. The
authors conclude that employers in Pakistan value the skills of private
school graduates higher than those of public school graduates.
It is not clear in the above study as to what level of education
does the dummy variable for private schools refer. An individual may
have acquired part of his or her training in private sector and part of
the training in public sector. A yet another shortcoming of this study
is the inappropriate specification of the earnings model. As will be
discussed below, educational quality itself affects the rate of return
to schooling and hence should be incorporated in the earnings model,
accordingly.
Another important recent study on the impact of educational quality
in Pakistan is by Behrman, Khan, Ross and Sabot (1997) who used 1989
micro data on rural households to assess the impact of various schooling
inputs, used indicators of educational quality, on cognitive
achievements of individuals. (15) The analysis has been performed within
a human capital production function context. Various schooling inputs
such as student-teacher ratio; teachers' quality as measured by
their schooling, training and experience; and school equipment and
infrastructure, are considered as determinants of an individual's
cognitive achievement. The cognitive achievement is measured in this
study by performance on specially designed tests of literacy and
numeracy. Results indicate that student-teacher ratio and teacher
quality are important determinants of student cognitive achievement.
Availability of school equipment and infrastructure have little effect.
Hence, the authors concluded that investments which increase student
exposure to teachers and those that improve teacher quality are likely
to have higher returns than those that improve physical infrastructure
and equipment.
In this study, we analyse the effect of an important educational
quality predictor, the student-teacher ratio in primary schools, on the
post schooling income of individuals earned through employment. In other
words, this study extends the Behrman, Khan, Ross and Sabot's
(1997) analysis by assessing the impact of an educational quality
predictor on the labour market performance of individuals. (16) The
analysis will also permit a more accurate measurement of the marginal
rate of return to investment in educational quantity than that conducted
by others such as Shabbir and Khan (1991); Shabbir (1991, 1993, 1994)
and Nasir and Nazli (2000), all of whom either ignore the role of
educational quality inputs in earnings model or include it incorrectly.
An accurate measurement of the marginal rate of return to educational
investment is essential in forming appropriate priorities within the
social sector of the economy.
Following Mincer (1974), the following earnings model in semi
logarithm form is now standard in human capital theory literature:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (1)
Where [LnY.sub.i] is the natural logarithm of annual earning of
individual i, S is the number of years of schooling completed by this
individual, E is the number of years of post-schooling experience in
labour market and U is the stochastic error term. The relationship is
quadratic in experience to account for a concave earnings-experience
profile during post schooling years. (17) The concavity of
earnings-experience profile implies a decline in marginal returns to
post schooling experience as the individual ages. For details on the
derivation of the above earnings model, the reader may refer to Mincer
(1974).
In the above relation, the coefficient of schooling variable, r,
reflects the marginal rate of return to an additional year of schooling
investment. If the equation is used to explain variations in pre-tax
earnings, then 'r' represents social rate of return to
schooling. If variations in post-tax earnings are explained, then
'r' represents private rate of return to schooling. (18)
As Behrman and Birdsall (1983) have argued, schooling in the above
equation is represented merely by "quantity", often measured
in terms of years of schooling. Variations in schooling quality affect
the rates of return to schooling as better quality education generally
receives higher reward in labour market. (19) Hence, ignoring the impact
of educational quality contributors will introduce an omitted variables
bias in the above earnings equation.
Many studies [for e.g., Wachtel (1976)] have modified the above
earnings equation to incorporate the effect of schooling quality on
rates of return to schooling. The following modified form of earnings
equation is used:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (2)
Where Q is an educational quality contributor variable and W is the
stochastic error term. This equation is derived by replacing S in
Equation (1) by "effective schooling", which is assumed to be
a quadratic function of schooling quantity (S) and quality (Q), and then
limiting the approximation to effective schooling to linear terms only.
However, Behrman and Birdsall (1983) have criticised the above
modification on two grounds. First, this specification does not
explicitly incorporate the human capital theory prediction that
educational quality improves the rate of return to schooling quantity.
Second, this specification implies that the quality of schooling can
affect earnings even if an individual has no schooling (Q may be nonzero even if S=0). Another modified form of Equation (1) is presented by
these authors as under:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCI.] (3)
Where V is the stochastic error term in the equation. This equation
is obtained by explicitly representing the rate of return (r) to
investment in schooling (S) as a quadratic function of schooling quality
and is preferred over Equation (2). (20) We thus base our analysis on
the estimation of Equation (3).
We base our estimations on micro data obtained from the Labour
Force Survey (LFS) of 1996-97. The LFS is conducted annually by the
Federal Bureau of Statistics (Government of Pakistan) and provides
detailed information on such aspects of labour force members as age,
education, employment, unemployment, types of employment, hours worked,
wages, etc. About 96 percent of the labour force residing in rural and
urban areas of each of the four provinces is covered by the survey. A
sample of 20,400 households was drawn from which 20,221 were enumerated due to non response from the remaining. Data were collected by direct
interviews. The total sample for the year was evenly distributed for
enumeration on monthly basis to offset the effect of seasonal
variations. However, the information collected refers to the week prior
to the date of enumeration. The entire sample was based upon 476 primary
sampling units (PSU). These are distributed in each division of the
province in such a way that equal number of sample PSUs were covered in
each month of the year as to take care of the seasonal variations. The
allocation of PSUs to provinces is proportional to their population.
Higher proportion of PSUs were allocated to urban domain of the
population as it was more heterogeneous. To account for sample
variability, a separate weighting variable is included in the micro
data. We thus based our analysis on the weighted sample. (21)
Furthermore, we confined our analysis to a sample of those workers who
reported non-zero employment income. (22)
The dependent variable in our analysis, is the logarithm of monthly
employment income. Information on monthly employment income was reported
by the respondents of the LFS.
One of the independent variables in the earnings model includes
years of schooling (S). The LFS questioned respondents on their highest
level of educational attainment. Following standard procedure in
literature, we converted the levels of schooling into years of
schooling. The absolute conversions that we used for this study are
provided in Appendix A.
Another independent variable in our model is the number of years of
labour market experience (E). No question was asked in the LFS about the
respondent's labour market experience. Hence, we followed the
standard procedure in literature [for example Mincer (1974)], and
calculated the number of years of experience as: E = Current Age-Number
of years of schooling--5. This calculation assumes that the individual
entered the education system at age 5.
The third independent variable in our model is the all important
educational quality contributor variable, Q. Several studies in
literature have shown the significance of primary education in
determining the future productivity and labour market performance of
individuals. (23) Therefore, in our earnings model, we wished to include
a variable that incorporated the quality of education offered at the
primary school level. An important educational quality contributor is
the student-teacher ratio which reflects student exposure to teacher. As
discussed by Kurian (1991), this ratio is particularly important in
primary schools where children need more individualised attention. A
lower student-teacher ratio implies greater student exposure to teachers
during primary school attendance, thereby raising his/her classroom
learning potential, which is expected to translate into higher labour
market productivity in future years. The higher labour market
productivity, in turn, is expected to result in higher potential for
labour market earnings. Hence, a lower student-teacher ratio can be
considered as reflective of higher educational quality acquired by the
individual. A higher student-teacher ratio reflects otherwise.
Computations of student-teacher ratio were based on published data.
Pakistan (1996) provides data on the number of primary school teachers
and corresponding student enrolments in each of the four provinces,
further classified by the region of residence as urban and rural. The
LFS micro data allowed us to match these data for each respondent. In
sum, our quality variable has a total of eight observations, one for
each of the two regions (urban and rural) in each of the four provinces.
Hence, these observations vary across individuals in our micro data
according to their province and region of residence.
We realise that there are several issues related to our above
methods of computations of variables. We now turn to a discussion of
some of those issues.
First, our computation of experience variable assumes that after
age 5, each individual remained employed when not attending school. This
assumption is commonly made in earnings function studies that are based
on micro data that do not collect direct information on labour market
experience of individuals. To minimise the possibility of disruptions in
employment, we restricted our analysis to only male workers as they are
expected to be more permanently attached to the labour force than female
workers. (24)
The second issue relates to the quality contributor variable, i.e.,
the student-teacher ratio in primary schools. This issue arises because
the student-teacher ratio for the year 1994 has been used and not for
the years during which the individual attended primary school. (25) This
approach is expected to create a bias in estimation if the
student-teacher ratio changed significantly or if the individual's
place of residence at the time of survey were different from the one
where primary school was attended.
The available published data from the Government of Pakistan
sources allow us to estimate a time series of the student-teacher ratio
only nationally and not separately for provinces and urban rural
regions. In a separate regression, we used these time series data with
appropriate lags to account for the average educational quality during
the five years the individual acquired primary school education. A
perfect co-linearity between SQ and [SQ.sup.2] variables prohibited us
from obtaining meaningful results. We therefore decided in favour of the
1994 cross sectional data on student-teacher ratio which have been
computed separately for each province and place of residence, defined as
urban or rural. (26) Hence, we have accounted for provincial and
regional variations in our educational quality variable. We do not
expect these variations to have changed significantly over time.
However, to further minimise the bias, we also considered only those men
in the sample who were aged between 15 and 35 years at the time of
survey as did Behrman and Birdsall (1983) in their study on Brazil.
Finally, we argue that the current educational quality contributors
in a region are also expected to affect an individual's labour
market productivity in that region, and hence earnings, in another way.
This is because the current educational quality contributors reflect the
prevalent working environment in the region which is complementary to
the individual's productivity as he works with workers who were
locally educated.
IV. DISCUSSION OF RESULTS
Table 3 presents some descriptive statistics on the variables used
in our earnings models. We note that an average worker in our sample had
acquired 7.4 years of education and 13.9 years of labour market
experience and earned about 2465 rupees per month in 1996. (27) The age
of the average worker, not reported in Table 3, was 26 years. We have
mentioned earlier that we used student-teacher ratio data for the year
1994 since it was the closest year to 1996 whose data were reliable. The
average student-teacher ratio was 43.58. The wide variation in the
student-teacher ratio, from a minimum of 26 to a maximum of 76.77, is
worth noting.
Table 4 reports the values of the student-teacher ratio across the
four provinces and also for each region, urban and rural, in each
province. Overall, in the province of Sindh, the student-teacher ratio
is significantly lower than the national average. Punjab and NWFP have
about the same ratio while Balochistan has the highest. One striking
feature of Table 4 data is the rural-urban differences. With the
exception of Sindh, the rural regions in each province exhibit lower
primary school student-teacher ratio than in urban regions. This result
can be attributed to lower enrolments in rural primary schools in the
three provinces.
We now turn to our regression results. We estimated both Equations
(1) and (3) using the Ordinary Least Squares method of estimation.
Equation (1) is the traditional basic earnings equation that specifies
the logarithm of annual earning as a function of the years of schooling
(S), years of post-schooling experience (E) and to account for the
concavity of experience-earnings profile, the square of experience
variable ([E.sup.2]). As discussed earlier, this is the most commonly
used specification in literature when estimation of the rates of return
to schooling is desired. (28) Results of our estimation are reported
below:
Ln [Y.sub.S.Q] = 6.772 + 0.0716S + 0.046E- 0.0005 [E.sup.2]
(4145.1) (840.6) (240.4) (82.1)
[R.sup.2] = 0.213; figures in parentheses are 't'
statistics. Number of observations: Weighted sample: 2,751,876.
Unweighted sample: 4,097.
All coefficients are statistically significant at 0.05 level and
their signs are as expected. The negative sign of the coefficient of the
[E.sup.2] variable confirms the concavity of the experience-earnings
profile indicating diminishing marginal returns to post schooling
experience.
The marginal rate of return to schooling investment is 7.16 percent
in the above equation. (29) This value of the marginal rate of return is
obtained by multiplying the coefficient of the S variable by 100 and
measures the percentage change in earnings accruing to an individual due
to an extra year invested in education. The computed value of 7.16
percent educational rate of return is within the 6 to 9.7 percent range
reported in other earnings function studies on Pakistan which we have
mentioned earlier in this section. Thus, if one ignored the effect of
educational quality on earnings, it may be concluded that an extra year
of schooling in Pakistan increases the potential labour market earnings
of an individual by 7.16 percent. This value is about 71 percent higher
than the 1996 growth rate of Pakistani Gross Domestic Product (GDP),
which was about 4.19 percent. Since wages and salaries form an important
component of GDP, these results suggest that education plays an
important role in determining the economic growth in Pakistan.
Now the above results may be misleading if a correct specification
of earnings equation must include educational quality as an independent
variable. Furthermore, if educational quality does affect the returns to
schooling investment, then this information will be important for
policy-makers, who confront the issue of allocation of limited funds to
alternative uses.
In the previous section, we presented Equation (3) as the preferred
specification of earnings equation that includes educational quality
variable as an independent variable. Our estimates of that equation are
presented below:
Ln [Y.sub.S.Q] = 6.807 + 0.152S - 0.004SQ + 0.000042 [SQ.sup.2] +
0.044E-0.0005 [E.sup.2] (4166.7) (350.9) (185.3) (178.6) (232.4) (78.9)
[R.sup.2] = 0.223; again figures in parentheses are 't'
statistics. Number of observations: Weighted sample: 2,751,876.
Unweighted sample: 4,097.
All variables in this equation are also statistically significant
at 0.05 level. We also computed an F statistic to test the significance
of adding the quality variable, Q, in the traditional earnings equation.
The computed F statistics was 17708.3 while the tabulated F-value at
0.01 level of significance was 4.61. We thus reject the hypothesis that
the quality variable, as defined by the student-teacher ratio, has no
impact in the earnings model. Hence, any educational rate of return
estimates for Pakistan that are based on an earnings model that does not
include educational quality variable as one of the determinants, are
likely to be biased.
In the above estimation, the coefficients of the two experience
variables and also the constant term are about the same as in the
traditional earnings model estimated earlier (Equation 1). The
coefficient of S variable has changed significantly, from 0.0716 in the
previous estimation to 0.152. However, it is important to note that the
coefficient of S variable alone can no longer be interpreted as the
marginal rate of return to schooling because of its interaction with the
quality variable in the new equation. The marginal rate of return to
schooling is computed in the new equation as under:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Based upon Equation 3 estimates, we perform the above computation
using the average value of 'Q' variable which is 43.58 in our
sample. This computation yields a marginal rate of return to schooling
of only 5.74 percent as opposed to 7.16 percent rate which was based
upon the estimates of traditional earnings function (Equation 1). Hence,
if the number of students per teacher at the primary level of education
is held constant, an additional year of schooling is expected to raise
the potential earnings of an individual by 5.71 percent which is about
32.3 percent higher than the GDP growth rate. We conclude that the
estimates of the educational rates of return based on traditional
earnings model have an upward biased.
The above pattern of our results is consistent with the Behrman and
Birdsall (1983) study on Brazil which also showed an upward bias in
educational rate of return calculated from estimates of traditional
earnings model.
V. CONCLUSIONS
This study has provided further evidence on the importance of
educational quality in determining the rate of return on educational
investment in developing countries. Using data on Pakistani male
workers, schooling quality was measured by the differential labour
market earnings of individuals who had been exposed to different levels
of an important schooling input, i.e., student-teacher ratio. This ratio
not only represents the environment in which an individual may have
acquired education in the past but also represents the environment in
which present complementary workers may have been educated.
We have shown that an estimate of educational rate of return based
on the traditional Mincerian earnings equation, which does not
incorporate the effect of quality contributing schooling inputs, has an
upward bias. This estimate yielded a marginal rate of return of 7.16
percent which was 71 percent faster than the Pakistani GDP growth rate
during 1995-96. However, a correct specification of the earnings
equation in which the impact of quality contributing variable is held
constant, yields the result that the marginal rate of return on
schooling investment is only 5.71 percent or 32.3 percent faster than
the GDP growth rate in Pakistan. This decline in the value of
educational rate of return due to incorporation of an educational
quality contributing variable is consistent with that reported for
Brazil in a previous study. Policy-makers confronted with the allocation
of limited resources to different sectors on the basis of financial
rates of return must take this "quality adjusted" rate into
account in order to make a correct choice.
We now use the above results to obtain the quantitative impact of
variations in student-teacher ratio on the rate of return to schooling
investment. This quantitative impact will allow policy-makers to
maintain a student-teacher ratio that would obtain the desired rate of
return to schooling investment. The 5.71 percent rate of return to
schooling investment in the present study was computed using the sample
average value of 43.58 students per teacher at primary school level.
Table 2 provided the average student-teacher ratio for several countries
including five South Asian countries. These were, Bangladesh, India,
Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka. Sri Lanka had the lowest primary
student-teacher ratio, at 28 students per teacher, in the mid-nineties.
If we consider this ratio in our computations, we observe that the rate
of return to schooling investment in Pakistan will rise to 7.3 percent
which is about the same as that yielded by the conventional earnings
function estimates. (30) Since the rate of return to schooling
investment essentially measures the growth rate in wages and salaries
which are an important component of GDP, these results show significant
benefit in terms of economic growth in improving educational quality in
Pakistan.
The finding that the student-teacher ratio is significantly lower
in rural regions than in urban regions in three out of four provinces is
also important. We noted that this result could be due to a lower
student enrolment in rural areas, which in turn may be due to lower
number of rural primary schools. In the light of the present study
results and those of Behrman, Khan and Sabot's (1997), there are
several implications of this observation. First, any increase in primary
schools in rural areas must be accompanied by a corresponding increase
in the number of better educated teachers. This implication should also
be seen in the light of Zaidi's (1999) suggestion that greater
emphasis on increasing the number of schools may have actually resulted
in a decline in educational quality. Second, a replication of Behrman,
Khan and Sabot's (1997) study on the impact of educational quality
enhancing variables on cognitive achievement of students in urban
Pakistan is also warranted to draw comparison with results for rural
Pakistan. Finally, this result may also be seen in the light of the
current rural/urban job quota system in government departments which
aims to fill in a certain number of vacancies with individuals holding
rural residencies (domicile). (31)
The present study has an important caveat in that it used only one
educational quality contributor, the student-teacher ratio at the
primary level of education, to determine the educational quality impact
on labour market performance of individuals. A more comprehensive study
should also consider other contributors of educational quality such as
teachers' training and educational attainment, teachers'
salaries, school equipment and infrastructure, etc. (32) Due to paucity of reliable data, we were unable to analyse the impacts of these
educational quality enhancing variables on labour market performance.
However, as we noted earlier, Behrman, Khan and Sabot (1997) who used
another data set for Pakistan, found that only the student-teacher ratio
and teachers' education and training have an effect on cognitive
achievement of individuals. Since better cognitive achievement of
students is expected to result in better productivity, which in turn
translates into improved labour market earnings, the present study
strengthens the case for improving the student-teacher ratio by
providing a quantitative assessment of its impact on labour market
earnings. When more data are available, it will be useful to assess the
impacts of other educational quality contributors on an
individual's labour market performance.
APPENDIX
Appendix A
Level of Schooling Years of Schooling
No Formal Education 0
KG, Nursery 1
KG but below Primary 3
Primary but below Middle 6
Middle but below Matriculation 8
Matriculation but below Intermediate 10
Intermediate but below Degree 12
Degree in Engineering 16
Degree in Medicine 16
Degree in Agriculture 16
Degree in Other (e.g., BA/B.Sc./B.Com. etc.) 14
Postgraduate 16
Authors' Note: We acknowledge, with many thanks, the useful
comments and suggestions made on an earlier version of this paper by the
discussant Dr V. Lanz and other participants of the Productivity and
Growth session of the Canadian Economics Association meeting held in
2000 at Vancouver, Canada. Helpful comments made by Dr S. R. Khan are
also appreciated. The study also benefitted from the comments made by
the participants of a seminar on education issues held at the Institute
of Business Administration, University of Karachi.
REFERENCES
Ahmed, M. (1997) Education. In R. Raza (ed.) Pakistan in
Perspective: 1947-97. Karachi: Oxford University Press.
Akbari, A. H. (1996) Provincial Income Disparities in Canada: Does
the Quality of Education Matter? Canadian Journal of Economics 29,
$337-339.
Akbari, A. H., and T. Ogwang (1996) The Canadian Earnings Functions
Under Test. Applied Economics Letters 4, 133-139.
Behrman, J. R., and N. Birdsall (1983) The Quality of Schooling:
Quantity Alone is Misleading. American_Economic Review 66:2, 928-946.
Behrman, J. R., S. Khan, D. Ross, and R. Sabot (1997) School
Quality and Cognitive Achievement Production: A Case Study for Rural
Pakistan. Economics of Education Review 16:2, 127-142.
Blinder, A. S. (1976) On Dogmatism in Human Capital Theory. Journal
of Httman Resources 11:1, 8-22.
Business Recorder (2000) 40 percent 'Out-of-school' Kids
in South Asia from Pakistan.
(www.businessrecorder.com/story/S0000/S0000/S0000105.htm).
Card, D., and A. B. Krueger (1992) Does School Quality Matter?
Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the
United States. Journal of Political Economy 100:1, 1-39.
Card, D., and A. B. Krueger (1992a) School Quality and Black-White
Relative Earnings: A Direct Assessment. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 107:1, 151-200.
Colclough, C. (1982) The Impact of Primary Schooling on Economic
Development: A Review of Evidence. World Development 10:3, 167-185.
Deaton, A. (1998) The Analysis of Household Surveys: A
Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. Baltimore and London:
The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Harbison, R. W., and E. A. Hanushek (1992) Educational Performance
of the Poor: Lessons from Rural Northeast Brazil. World Bank. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Heckman, J. J. (1979) Sample Selection as a Specification Error.
Econometrica 47: 1,153-161.
Khan, S. R. (1991) Financing Higher Education in Pakistan. Higher
Edncation 21, 207-222.
Khan, S. R. (1999) Reforming Pakistan's Political Economy.
Lahore/Karachi. Vanguard Books (Pvt.) Ltd.
Kingdon, Geeta Gandhi (1996) Student Achievement and Teacher Pay: A
CaseStudy of India. London School of Economics and Political Science (The Development Economics Research Programme No. 74.)
Kingdon, Geeta Gandhi (1996a) Private Schooling in India: Size,
Nature and Equityeffects. London School of Economics and Political
Science. (The Development Economics Research Programme No. 72.)
Kurian, G. T. (1991) The New Book of World Rankings (Third
Edition). New York. Mincer, J. (1974) Schooling, Experience and
Earnings. New York and London: Columbia University Press.
Nasir, Z. M., and H. Nazli (2000) Education and Earnings in
Pakistan. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
(Research Report No. 177.)
Pakistan, Government of (1998a) PIHS Edacation Sector Performance
in the 1990s. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics
Pakistan, Government of (1996) School Education Census 1993-94.
Islamabad: Ministry of Education.
Pakistan, Government of (1998) Fifty Years of Pakistan in
Statistics. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (1999) Economic Survey. Islamabad: Finance
Division.
Pasha, H. (1959) Political Economy of Higher Education: A Study of
Pakistan. Pakistan Economic and Social Review 33:1&2, 19-36.
Psacharopoulos, G. (1994) Returns to Investment in Education: A
Global Update. World Development 22:2, 1325-1344.
Ramamurti, R. (1999) Why Haven't Developing Countries
Privatised Deeper and Faster? World Development 27:1, 137-155.
Saad, I. (1999) Education in Pakistan. In M. Ahmed and K. Ghaus
(eds) Pakistan: Prospects and Perspectives. Karachi: Royal Book Company.
Shabbir, T. (1991) Sheepskin Effects in the Returns to Education in
a Developing Country. The Pakistan Development Review 30:1, 11-19.
Shabbir, T. (1993) Productivity Enhancing vs Credentialist Effects
of Schooling in Rural Pakistan. International Food Policy Research
Institute, Washington, D. C. (Mimeographed.)
Shabbir, T. (1994) Mincerian Earnings Function for Pakistan. The
Pakistan Development Review 33:1, 11-18.
Shabbir, T., and A. H. Khan (1991) Mincerian Earning Functions for
Pakistan: A Regional Analysis. The Pakistan Economic and Social Review
29:2, 99-112.
Simon, J. L. (1992) Why Don't State Incomes Converge?
Effective Worker Pay Does Not Differ Among States. Economics of
Education Review 2, 195-215.
Todaro, M. P. (1999) Economic Development. Addison-Wesley (United
States). UNESCO (1995) World Education Report. UNESCO Publishing and
Bernan Press. Wachtel, Paul (1976) The Effect on Earnings of School and
College Education Expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics 58,
326-331.
World Bank (1993) The World Development Report. New York: Oxford
University Press.
World Bank (1995) Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and
Politics of Government Ownership. New York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank (1996) Pakistan Improving Basic Education: Community
Participation, System Accountability, and Efficiency. Population and
Human Resources
Division Country Department 1: South Asia Region. (Report No.
14960-PAK.) World Bank (1998) World Development Indicators. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Zaidi, S. Akbar (1999) Issues in Pakistan "s Economy. Karachi:
Oxford University Press.
(1) For example, please see Behrman and Birdsall (1983); Card and
Krueger (1992, 1992a). Schooling quality in these studies is measured by
the average schooling of teachers, pupil-teacher ratio, the average term
length and the relative pay of teachers.
(2) Out of the ten countries whose data are reported in Table 1,
seven expanded their primary level enrolmant ratios over the fifteen
year period 1980-95. These countries also reported a rise in their share
of educational expenditures in GDP and a rise in student-teacher ratios
in primary schools. Although one country, Iran, reported a fall in its
share of educational expenditure in GDP, its enrolmant ratio and
student-teacher ratio were also on the rise.
(3) At an Institute of Business Administration (University of
Karachi) seminar presented by the first author on issues related to
provision of education in Pakistan, an official from the Pakistani
Ministry of Education confirmed this to be indeed the case in Pakistan.
(4) The rate of return to schooling is measured as the percentage
change in labour market earnings of an individual when he or she
acquires an additional year of schooling.
(5) Zaidi (1999) notes that emphasis on increasing the number of
schools may have caused a decline in educational quality.
(6) An earlier survey conducted by the British Council in 1980 had
found that the number of untrained teachers working at the primary level
was four times that at the secondary level.
(7) Conducted by the Government of Pakistan with the assistance of
World Bank, the PIHS is an annual national survey whose objective is to
provide the household and community level data necessary to study the
impact of SAP.
(8) This point is also consistent with the human capital theory
prediction that demand for education rises with improvement in its
quality which promises better expected return in future.
(9) Pakistan (1998).
(10) A recent World Bank study [World Bank (1995)] also makes note
of this fact.
(11) Khan (1999).
(12) Zaidi (1999) is also aware that the growth of private schools
has led to a clear divide in Pakistani education sector along class and
linguistic lines as many of these schools, especially the ones that are
considered to be of better quality, serve the "elite or
English--speaking population". Kingdon (1996a) has discussed equity
considerations of private sector education expansion in India. In sum,
equity effects of the expansion of private sector education have been of
concern to authors in developing countries.
(13) Indeed this later observation is consistent with Ramamurti
(1999) and World Bank (1995) who find that privatisation has seen little
success in developing countries due to political, institutional, and
economic constraints.
(14) In yet another approach, the effect of educational quality
differences across regions within a country are explored by isolating
this effect from the effect of current working environment. Earnings of
foreign born, individuals most of whom did not grow up where they
presently live so their human capital is not affected by quality
differences in education in the place of current residence, are compared
with those of native born for most of whom the opposite applies. A proxy
variable for the current working environment in the region is introduced
in each earnings equation. This variable is expected to be significant
determinant of the earnings of foreign born but not for native born, if
educational quality does vary across regions. Using Canadian data,
Akbari (1996) has shown that the working environment has a significant
effect on the earnings of foreign as well as native born, leading to the
conclusion that persistent earnings differences across Canadian
provinces may be largely due to differences in working environment and
not due to differences in educational quality. Applying the stone
approach on United States data, Simon (1992) found opposite result.
(15) The data are collected since 1986, four times a year, on a
sample of randomly selected households by the International Food Policy
Research Institute under the auspices of the Pakistan Ministry of Food
and Agriculture. In 1989, special human capital modules were
administered to obtain measures of respondents' cognitive
achievements and corresponding schooling inputs.
(16) We wanted to incorporate the impacts of teachers'
educational qualifications and salary into our analysis, but were
constrained by the availability of reliable data. However, with respect
to teacher salary, it is worth noting that some authors have suggested
that this may not be an appropriate indicator of educational quality in
developing countries. For instance Kingdon (1996) has found for India
that teacher incentives, including salaries, are not determined by
teacher characteristics that produce improved student achievement.
(17) The suggested concavity of earnings profile, the relationship
of earnings ([Y.sub.i]) with the number of years of experience (E), is
accounted for by the addition of the [E.sup.2] term. The
semi-logarithmic form is used under the presumption that errors of such
specification are normally distributed as well as homoscedastie.
However, using data for different countries, several authors have found
that the hypotheses of normality and homoscedasticity of error terms
does not always hold. Akbari and Ogwang (1996) who have conducted this
analysis for Canada, have also reviewed the evidence for other
countries. In the present study, normality and homoscedasticity
assumptions are maintained without testing. Such tests will be the
subject of another study.
(18) While calculating the marginal rate of return in this manner,
the cost of schooling is the income foregone by the individual due to
postponement of labour market earnings by one more year.
(19) This assumes that better quality education is scarce in the
overall educational endowment of the economy. Scarcity of better quality
education may be reflected in the higher tuition fee paid in private
schools and universities than in public school system as private sector
is generally viewed to provide better quality education.
(20) For detailed derivation of Equations (2) and (3), please see
Behrman and Birdsall (1983).
(21) For the importance of the weighting of household sample data
in developing countries, please see Deaton (1998).
(22) As noted by Heckman (1979), confining the analysis to employed
individuals with non-zero wages may give rise to a sample selectivity bias, which we have not explored in this paper.
(23) Colclough (1982) provides a review of such studies.
(24) Blinder (1976) notes, "Using the (experience) proxy for
prime-age white males is probably appropriate, but using j (the
experience proxy) for females is hazardous ...". The females'
labour three participation rates, as well as employment, may be
discontinuous due to child raising and family responsibilities, social
attitudes and discrimination.
(25) Student and teacher data for 1994 were used since these were
the most reliable and consistent data for the year closest to 1997--the
year for which earnings are used.
(26) This method also follows the previous study on Brazilian data
by Behnnan and Birdsall (1983).
(27) The 2465 rupees value is the geometric mean of earnings which
is obtained by taking anti-log of the mean value of [LnY.sub.SQ] which
was 7.81.
(28) This specification has been discussed in the previous section.
(29) Mathematically, the coefficient of S variable is [partial
derivative] LnY/[partial derivative] S which measures the proportionate
change in labour market earnings resulting from an extra year invested
in education.
(30) This computation also implies that decreasing the
student-teacher ratio by 10 students increases the rate of return by
1.02 percentage which is only slightly higher than Card and
Krueger's (1992) U.S. result of 1 percentage increase in the rate
of return for every 10 students decrease in the student-teacher ratio.
(31) It may also be noted that besides private farm, government is
the major employer in rural regions.
(32) As mentioned earlier, teacher salary may not be an appropriate
indicator of educational quality in developing countries. The reviewer
of this paper noted that since student-teacher ratio is lower in rural
regions it may not be reflective of better educational quality in
corresponding schools, rather a reflection of lower enrolments in rural
schools (of course implying implicitly that rural schools deliver poorer
quality education). We contend that whatever be the reason for regional
differences in student-teacher ratio, our analysis shows that it does
have the potential in Pakistan to enhance educational returns. Similar
results have been shown for other countries for whom literature views
student-teacher ratio as an important educational quality contributor.
Perhaps a future analysis of Pakistani data can address the regional
differences in economic achievements of individuals possessing identical
educational qualifications.
Comments
The authors have addressed an important topic of Education and
Earnings in the context of human capital formation and increasing
productivity and economic growth, with a particular focus on educational
quality as an important component of the whole process. The subject has
been widely studied and a vast body of literature exists on various
aspects of the relationship between education and earnings in both
developed and developing countries including Pakistan. This paper is
also an attempt in that direction. Using data from the 1996-97 Labour
Force Survey (LFS), the paper provides good empirical evidence on the
positive impact of education and experience on income, and that
educational quality contributes significantly to increasing productivity
and economic growth.
As I read the paper as a reviewer, I found a number of caveats and
problems in the data used and in the methodological estimation of the
variables used in the analysis. To begin with, the authors have
judiciously reviewed the earlier studies done on the subject to set the
ground for describing their objective and method of analysis. Using the
conventional and most commonly used Mincerian earning function,
specification of the estimation model is described including a quality
indicators student-teacher ratio, as an additional input to the
equation. At this point, the authors need to spell out whether there has
been any modifications or other forms of functions that can be used for
estimating the earning function and the justification for using this
method for the analysis.
For the estimation of variables, I would like to raise three major
points. First, as the model used requires data on single years of
schooling to explain a unit increment in income or earnings, it is noted
that the data used gives information on levels of education attained as
described in Appendix A, of the paper. It is not clear how these level
have been converted into completed years of schooling and what is the
justification for doing so. For example, KG, but below primary as 3
years of schooling, and primary but below middle as 6 years of schooling
and degree in agriculture as 16 years of education has been changed to
single years of schooling which is erroneous and questionable. In this
regard, more appropriate data with single year of schooling need to be
used to capture a unit increase in income.
My second point relates to the issue of quality indicator used in
the analysis. As we know, a number of indicators reflect quality of
education as has been mentioned in the paper as well. Subject to the
availability of data, the authors have selected only one indicator of
quality, student-teacher ratio, which has inherent problems in its
estimation and application to the labour force statistics used for the
analysis. As we may note, a different source of information, Education
Census of 1993-94, is used to estimate the student-teacher ratio and
then related to the experience and earnings in the labour market much
later in life. It is not clear how these data have been matched at micro
level to capture the effect of quality on individual earnings. There
seems to be a disjointed relationship between quality of education and
earnings because these data do not indicate whether those with high or
low student-teacher ratio at primary level years ago are the same people
experiencing higher incomes as reported in the 1996-97 Labour Force
Survey. Moreover, studentteacher ratio is affected by a number of
factors that is not spelt out in the paper. The quality indicator used
shows great variation across regions as indicated by Table 6, of the
paper. For example, student-teacher ratio in rural areas is lower than
urban areas. Does it mean that quality is better in rural than in urban
schools. Then, this ratio is much higher in urban Punjab and Balochistan
than other provinces reflecting the unevenness in the education data
used across provinces. Hence, these 8 observations of quality indicator
used for urban-rural areas in the four provinces are contradictory and
need further explanation.
There is no doubt that measurement of quality is a thorny issue and
has difficulties in choosing the data to measure the quality index. In
my view, a composite indicator of quality should be used incorporating
more than one measure of quality. Some studies have used private
schooling as a proxy of quality indicator which reflects better
student-teacher ratio, higher expenditure per pupil, better salary of
teachers, and better school facilities and teacher training, in this
regard, equally strong argument exists for using teacher training and
skills as a better indicator of quality, because teachers with no
training skills and a small class size may not give a good exposure to
quality schooling.
Another major point of concern relates to the gender question. It
is noted that the analysis refers to males only with no satisfactory
explanation and justification given to excluding females in the
analysis. There is enough research evidence on gender differentials in
earnings and gender variable has emerged as a significant variable in
other studies. With enchanged female enrolment and employment in recent
years through the initiation of Social Action Programme (SAP) and
structural adjustment policies in Pakistan, capturing gender
differentials in earnings has large implications in terms of policies
and programmes. It would, therefore be insightful to estimate earning
equations for females also.
In the concluding section of the paper, the discussion of results
and policy implications of the analysis remain inadequate. The findings
reflect the need for collecting more relevant information and data for
capturing quality related indicators in estimating educational earnings
function. We also need to be careful in selecting data for this type of
analysis to be able to derive more meaningful and accurate results.
In the end, I would like to reiterate my opinion that the paper
provides good empirical evidence on the importance of quality of
education in enhancing productivity and economic growth. Like most
research work on education and measurement of its quality, the analysis
may have some weaknesses and problems in the measures applied to the
income earners in the labour market. However, with some more efforts and
refinement of the quality measures used, the study could usefully add to
our knowledge about the role of educational quality in improving labour
market performance in Pakistan.
Naushin Mahmood
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Ather H. Akbari teaches in the Department of Economics, Saint
Mary's University, Halifax, Nova Scotia, Canada. Naeem Muhammed is
based at Lahore University of Management Sciences, Lahore
Table 1
Gross Enrolment Ratio, Educational E.rpendittrre as a Percentage
of GDP, and Pupil-Teacher Ratio in Primary Schools:
Selected Developing Countries, 1980 anti 1995
Gross Enrolment Ratio Educational Expenditure
in Primary Schools* (% of GNP)
Country 1980 (a) 1995 (a) 1980 (a) 1995 (a)
Bangladesh 61 92 1.5 2.3
India 83 100 2.8 3.5
Iran 87 99 7.5 4.0
Kenya 115 85 6.8 7.4
Mexico 120 115 4.7 5.3
Nepal 86 110 1.8 2.9
Nigeria 105 89 6.4 n.a.
Pakistan 39 74 2.0
Philippines 112 116 1.7 2.2
Sri Lanka 103 113 2.7 3.1
Student-Teacher Ratio
in Primary Schools
Country 1980 (b) 1995 (a)
Bangladesh 54 63 (c)
India 45 63
Iran 27 32
Kenya 36 31
Mexico 39 29
Nepal 38 39
Nigeria 41 37
Pakistan 37 41 (c)
Philippines 31 35
Sri Lanka 32 28
Sources: (a) World Bank (1998).
(b) UNESCO (1995).
(c) Data available for 1992 obtained from UNESCO (1995).
* Ratio of total school population, regardless of age, to the
population of age group that officially
corresponds to primary level of education.
Table 2
Public Expenditure and Illiteracy Ratio in Five
South Asian Countries, 1990
Public Expenditure on Illiteracy Rate
Country Education (% of GNP) (% of Population)
Bangladesh 2.0 64.7
India 3.5 51.8
Pakistan 3.4 65.2
Nepal 2.9 74.4
Sri Lanka 2.7 11.6
Solute: World Bank (1993).
Table 3
Descriptive Statistics on the Variables Used in Earnings Models
(Weighted Regressions, Males Aged 15-35)
Minimum Maximum Average
Variable Value Value Value
[LnY.sub.i] 0.00 10.82 7.81
S 0.00 16.00 7.4
E 1.00 30.00 13.9
Q 26.01 76.77 43.5 8
Source: Labour Force Survey, micro data (1996).
Table 4
Student-Teacher Ratio in Primary Schools; Pakistan,
Province and Regions, 1993-94
Region
Province Urban Rural Total
Punjab 61.31 43.48 46.84
Sindh 26.01 31.38 29.24
North Western Frontier
Province (NWFP) 49.56 46.38 46.89
Balochistan 76.77 37.93 51.36
Source: Pakistan (1996).