Impact of village-specific, household-specific, and technological variables on poverty in Punjab.
Azid, Toseef ; Malik, Shahnawaz
Rural poverty remains a serious problem in Pakistan, with more than
30 percent of rural population living in absolute poverty. In rural
Pakistan there is a big gap between rich and the poor. While the stake
of competition for position and status concerns the rich, the struggle
for survival in the midst of increasing crises embarrasses the poor. The
rural poor--the pauperised class--are week and powerless with inadequate
command over resources relative to needs, in fact, the polarisation
process which is making the rich richer and poor poorer is a consequence
of poverty. Neither the poor nor the outside well wishers have the power
to break the vicious deprivation trap. It is consensus that rural social
structure is responsible for rural underdevelopment.
A number of attempts can be seen in the literature having discussed
the different dimensions of the above phenomenon related to developing
economies in general and to Pakistan in particular, e.g., [Ahmad (1993);
Ali (1997); Allaudin (1975); Gazdar and Zaidi (1994); Jafri (1999); de
Kruijk and Leeuwen (1985); Mahmood (1984); Mahmood (1999); Malik (1988);
Malik (1996); Mujahid (1978); Naseem (1973, 1996); Shirazi (1995); Tahir
and Ali (1999); Ali and Tahir (1999) and Bhatti et al. (1999)]. The
present study is the continuity of the above efforts. However, this
study discusses the enigma of poverty based on a village study.
Within above setting, a village survey has been conducted in the
Southern Punjab. The study analyses the determinants of rural poverty in
the above village and its relation with productive assets, tools and
instruments, gender, rural employment, household size, earner size,
education level, etc. The analysis explicitly takes into account such
attributes as the village specific, household specific and technological
variables.
The study has three sections. Section I discusses the results of
the logit model taking poverty as the dependent variable (poverty is one
otherwise zero), in this section analysis presented is based on all
income earners. In Section II an attempt is made to split up the whole
series of households into different groups depicting the different level
of per capita income which can differentiate the poor and the poorest.
This is because in the dynamic state it is necessary to know that how
many income groups exist in the village. For achieving this objective,
an iterative methodology is developed. It may be helpful for the
policy-makers to differentiate between poor and the poorest. Whereas
Section Ill presents the concluding remarks.
SECTION I
As mentioned the study is based on a village survey conducted in
Punjab containing 90 households. The village 'Wanda' (District
Bhakkar, Punjab)I situated at a distance of 10 KM from the river Indus,
which forms the boundary with the North-West Frontier Province, could be
taken as a fair representative of the characteristics of the two
provinces. The survey carried out in October/November 2000, makes no
claim to being completely representative of rural Pakistan. We do feel,
however, findings based on this sample, when broadly interpreted, can
serve as useful generalisations [Malik (1996)]. The survey was a one
shot exercise. Within the community, the objective was the total
enumeration of household. The village had 90 households and 100 percent
enumeration was obtained.
The risk of poverty for a household is taken to be a random event
the occurrence of which is assumed to depend on village-specific (mainly
infrastructural), technological and household specific variables.
Empirical estimates of the risk of the poverty (or the probability of a
household being poor conditional upon the set of explanatory variables)
are obtained from a logit model.
The explanatory variables are classified into three categories: (1)
village-specific, (2) technological, and (3) household-specific.
The list and description of the variables is given as:
Village-specific Variables
1. Tr If a bus or railway service exists between the nearest market
and the village, the variable takes the value 1, and 0 otherwise.
2. Me If household visits the health centre, the variable takes the
value 1, and 0 otherwise.
3. Cr If household availed the credit facility, the variable takes
the value 1, and 0 otherwise.
Technological Variables
4. Tra If tractors are used by household, the variable takes the
value 1, and 0 otherwise.
5. El If household used electricity for farming, the variable takes
the value 1, and 0 otherwise.
6. HYV Gross cropped area under HYV in acres.
Demographic Variables
7. HS Number of persons in a household.
8. [(HS).sup.2]
9. De Ratio of number of members (<14 and > 65 years) to HH
size.
10. Age Age of head of the household.
11. [(Age).sup.2]
12. PR Ratio of number of workers to number of adults (i.e.
household members > 14 years).
13. Fm Ratio of female workers to male workers in a household.
14. Ed The variable takes the value 1 if the highest educational
level of any household member is higher than primary education, and 0
otherwise.
The dependent variable is 1 if household is under poverty line and
0 otherwise. In the empirical estimations the effect of Tr variable is
not measured because it is available to every respondent.
The logit model is used to study the above phenomenon. The
explanation of the results is as below:
We estimated the effect of two village specific variables, i.e.,
credit (Cr) and medical (Me) facility used by the households. It is
observed that the credit variable, Cr, possesses a significant
coefficient, with a negative sign. As it is common in the rural areas
that two sources of income namely, farm and non-farm are available. May
be credit facility can enhance the efficiency of the inhabitants which
in turn increase their farm as well as non-farm income. The coefficient
of Medical (Me) also possessed a negative significant coefficient
(-0.0723). It depicts that medical facility has negative effect on the
poverty. A typical household in the rural areas may enhance his income
through hiring out his wage labour. On the contrary, a prolonged illness
will not allow him to increase his income level.
The next group of variables, tractor (Tra), electricity (El), and
high-yield variety seeds (HYV), capture the effects of the adoption of
the new technology on poverty among the rural households. All these have
the significant coefficients with the expected negative sign. Their
coefficients are -0.3461, -0.5341, and -0.1109 respectively.
The demographic variables, Hs, [(Hs).sup.2], De, Age and
[(Age).sup.2] produce a few surprises. Note that first three variables
have significant coefficients. The fact that the coefficient of Age and
[(Age).sup.2] are not significant suggests that across different age
groups (of household heads) the risk of poverty did not vary. The
structure of the rural society shows that instead of age the economic
opportunities have the significant role in the growth of the income of
the household. The coefficients of Hs and [(Hs).sup.2] are statistically
significant, the signs are positive and negative and the values are
0.0327 and -0.0012 respectively. This implies that with an increase in
household size the poverty will reduce. The coefficient of De (0.8650)
has positive significant effect on the poverty. The coefficient of Pr
(0.0034) is insignificant and gave the inconclusive results. Fm has a
negative effect on the poverty, the value of coefficient is -0.1469. It
implies that female earners among low income households supplement
household income by working on nearby farms or in the relatively
affluent homes as maids, subject to the constraints imposed by domestic
cores, and religious and social considerations. Given the male
participation rate, it is hypothesised that the higher the female
participation, the higher the total household income and lower the risk
of poverty.
Ed (-0.0143) has also negative effect on the poverty. It implies
that the more educated has more potential to exploit the resources and
technology.
From the above results it is concluded that variables belonging to
each of three groups village specific, technological and household
specific exercised a strong influence on the risk of being poor of
understudy households. The risk of poverty is determined by a diverse
set of factors belonging to these groups.
SECTION II
In this section an effort is made to estimate the different
segments of the households according to their per capita income. It is
observed that in a series of households' per capita income a jump
is occurred after some observations. It implies that next observation is
not of the present segment and belongs to the next segment of the
household. One can observe that in a rural society a small difference in
the income of the household makes no difference but a large difference
essentially changes the social status. So on the basis of that it is
assumed that economic and social status of the households belonging to
each segment which are significantly different to each other is not
similar.
Procedures for splitting up the data into different segments are
available in the literature, but almost all the existing literature
deals with time-series analysis. Because time is the most important
variable which guides the analyst in splitting up the data into
different segments, for example data before and after war, would
naturally be split into three segments: peace, war and peace. Similarly
data before and after on oil crises, would be split into two segments
and so on. Similarly when economists deal with the techniques of
production, they separate data into different sections according to
time, and one segment is different to others due to some major events
(such as war, innovation, any major political decision, a major social
change, etc.) which are thought to have significant effects on the
economic variables, e.g., [Brown and Popkin (1962)]. However, in the
existing literature it is hard to find statistical techniques which can
be used to split up cross-section data into different segments which are
significantly different from each other. As discussed in the
introduction, an attempt is made to split up the series into different
segments depicting the different level per capita income which can
differentiate the poor and poorest. With this objective in mind an
iterative methodology is developed in this section [Azid (1994)]. The
main features of the methodology are as below:
(a) The data of the per capita income of each and every household
is arranged according to the ascending order.
(b) The corresponding series of the income of the households is
converted into the cumulative format then transformed into percentage.
(c) Take the difference of per capita income, from a larger value
to the next lower, i.e., from the bottom to the top of the series (data
is in ascending order).
(d) The difference is regressed on the relevant percentage of total
income of the village.
(e) Delete the first observation and again regress on the
percentage of the total income, and repeat the procedure.
(f) The 'jump mean of square' is obtained by taking the
difference of the total sum of squares of the first regression from the
next regression, divided by the degree of freedom (which is obviously
equal to one).
(g) The 'error mean of squares' is the total sum of
squares of the next regression divided by the total degrees of freedoms.
(h) The F-value is the ratio of 'jump mean of squares' to
'error mean of squares'. If the value is significant at these
degrees of freedom, then continue the procedure, otherwise stop the
iteration; there is no need to go further.
(i) The values between any two significant jumps are regarded as
representing one segment.
By using the above methodology, different segments of the
households based on their per capita income can be found, which are
prevailing simultaneously, and a line can be drawn between various
segments.
By applying the above technique fourteen segments are found in the
given series of households' per capita income. Table 1 depicts the
full description of the segments according to their first and last
observation.
Table 1 depicts the fourteen segments which are statistically
significant to each other based on the households per capita income (for
the reconfirmation of the statistical significance of these segments we
apply the Kruskal-Wallis H Test). (2) It is observed from the above
table that than 28.8 percent households have only 13 percent share in
the per capita income whereas 12 percent households have 46 percent
(approximately). 86.6 percent households have less than 54.13 percent
share in the per capita income. This gives us a skewed distribution of
income with a Gini coefficient of 0.372. In the third segment
(416.66-510.42) in which poverty line is falling we found more cluster
of the households, absolute number is 22. Most of the households are
falling from 3rd to 9th segments. For the empirical analysis we will not
consider the first two and the last five segments assuming them as
abnormal observations.
Table 2 depicts the share of per capita income and number of
households from 3rd to 9th segments.
An attempt is made to estimate the correlation between percentage
of the household and their share in the per capita income. The estimate
is positive (0.209) but not significant. It gives more strength to our
hypothesis that every segment is independent to each other and has
different social and economic characteristics. Owing to above, an
attempt is made to see the effect of specific variables on these
segments separately (segment nine is not examined because of the lower
degree of freedom).
Segment 3rd to 8th are classified as:
Segment Number Classification
03 Poorest
04 Poorer
05 Poor
06 Lower Middle
07 Middle
08 Upper Middle
Table 3 presents results of an (OLS) analysis of the variations in
per capita income of the households on the basis of distinct classified
groups. This is an alternative explanation of the relation between the
set of variables and per capita income of the households. Most of the
results are similar to those of the logit analysis and hence the
findings of Section l are confirmed.
As expected the two village-specific variables, medical facility
and credit, have positive effect on the per capita income of the
households of all the classified groups. Medical facility seems to show
strange positive effects in favour of lower income segments whereas the
coefficients of credit seem to benefit more the higher income segments.
The technological variables, use of tractor, electricity and HYV
have shown positive significant relationship with the per capita income
irrespective of classified groups. The lower income groups seem to have
benefitted from hiring the tractor services which is available to every
household. On the other hand, HYV benefits more the higher income
segments due perhaps to the reason that they have larger areas of land
where HYV is used. The electricity benefits all uniformly.
Each of four household-specific variables namely, household size,
dependency ratio, participation rate and female-male ratio produce
coefficients with expected signs. The coefficient of household size and
dependency ratio are inversely related whereas those of participation
rate and female-male ratio are positively related to per capita income
of households. However, a significant feature of the results is observed
that each segment has its own magnitude of coefficient with different
level of significance. This suggests that for a meaningful analysis
different segments of a population of households may be analysed
separately, e.g., Engel elasticity for each segment may be estimated
which has its own significance in the economic literature [Mathur
(1967)].
SECTION III
Summary and Concluding Remarks
Some general observations based on the major findings of the study
are made here to put the discussion in perspective:
(a) Most of the variables belonging to each of the three groups of
village-specific, technological and household-specific showed a strong
influence on the risk of being poor for the village households.
(b) It has been shown that the probability of failing below the
poverty line is lower for a village household with a larger area to
cultivate for its own, a smaller number of dependents, greater
participation in farm and non-farm work and a higher education level
which increases the non-agricultural opportunities available to a
village households. The other such variables are availability of credit
and medical facilities to the households.
(c) As expected, the adoption of new technology in farming had a
strong poverty reducing effect among the village households.
(d) On the contrary, the probability of falling below the poverty
line is greater if the village population has fewer alternative
opportunities for the labour households and hence fewer access to
gainful employment.
(e) An attempt is made to split up the whole series of households
into different income segments to differentiate poor and the poorest.
This exercise enables us to know that the village income distribution is
highly skewed with a Gini coefficient equal to 0.37 and a landholding Gini coefficient very close to 0.50. In such a setting the large income
groups and land owners benefit at the expense of sections of small
landowners tenants and agricultural labourers.
(f) An alternative explanation of the relation between
village-specific, technological and household specific variables and per
capita income of households has been provided using OLS analysis as the
basis of distinct classified groups. Most of the results are similar to
those of the logit analysis thus confirming those results.
APPENDICES
Appendix I
BACKGROUND TO VILLAGE SURVEY
The village (called 'Wanda' located in Punjab province)
survey was conducted in 2000, for six continuous weeks. The survey was
mainly based on a household questionnaire largely concerned with
quantitative economic analysis. The format of the questionnaire was such
that the information could easily be transformed on an individual basis.
The modes of the data collection were the following:
(i) direct questioning of household head and other members;
(ii) extracting data from participant observation; and
(iii) interviewing of selected informants.
The survey was a 'one-shot' exercise, and repeated survey
were not possible. The event of the recent past (agricultural data,
etc.) had to be based on memory recall of respondents with cross
checking from co-residents.
Within the community, the objective was the total enumeration of
households. The village had 90 households and 100 percent enumeration
was obtained. In general, households tended to have multiple attributes
in terms of sectoral and organisational involvements. Data on production
activities, income and employment were obtained.
The village consisting of 99 households is connected to the nearest
town (called 'Darya Khan' at a distance of 8 miles) by a
single metalled road. It was electrified only two years ago and has
educational facility upto the primary level. The primary health centre
is located at distance of 3 miles.
The village agricultural land is plain and mostly cultivable. The
land-tenure system consists of both owner-cropping as well as
share-cropping. The main crops of the area are wheat, sugar cane, maize,
sorghum and cotton.
Appendix II
KRUSKAL-WALLIS H TEST
Purpose: To determine whether the distributions in ranks for three
or more independent samples differ significantly from those proposed for
three or more populations.
Sampling Distribution: H statistics distributions are estimated by
Chi-square. Assumptions of the Test:
(i) independent and Random observations;
(ii) three or more independent samples; and
(iii) ordinal level of measurement (expressed as ranks) in
dependent variable.
Typical Hypothesis:
[H.sub.0] : H=0
[H.sub.1]: H [not equal to] 0
Tabular Statistic: H statistic as estimated by chi-square with d.f
= K-1 from Table [D.sub.4].
Test Statistic:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where [SIGMA][R.sub.i] = sum of ranks in each sample
N = number of scores in all samples combined
[N.sub.i] = Number of scores in each sample.
Authors' Note: We would like to thank Dr Rehana Siddiqui
Senior Research Economist, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics,
Islamabad, for her valuable comments on this paper.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, M. (1993) Choice of a Norm of Poverty Threshold and Extent
of Poverty in Pakistan, Ministry of Finance, Islamabad. (Mimeographed.)
Ali, M. S. (1997) Poverty Alleviation: The Existing Situation. In
Mohibul Haq Sahibzada (ed.) Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan. Institute
of Policy Studies. 93-114.
Ali, S., and Sayyid Tahir (1999) Dynamics of Growth, Poverty and
Inequality in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 38:4.
Allauddin, T. (1975) Mass Poverty in Pakistan: A Further Study. The
Pakistan Development Review 14.
Amjad, R., and A. R. Kemal (1997) Macroeconomic Policies and Their
Impact on Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development
Review 36:1, 39-68.
Azid, T. (1994) Segments of the Directly Ordered Data: A Cross
Section Analysis. Paper presented in the second Iranian Statistics
Conference held at Ferdowsi University of Mashhad, Iran.
Besley, T. (1996) Political Economy of Alleviating Poverty: Theory
and Institutions in Michael Bruno and Boris Pleskovic (eds.) Annual
World Bank Conference on Development Economics, World Bank.
Bhatti, M. A. et al. (1999) A Sectoral Analysis of Poverty in
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 38:4.
Brown, M., and J. Popkin (1962) A Measure of Technological Change
and Return to Scale. Review of Economic and Statistics 44, 402-414.
de Kruijk, H., and M. van Leeuwen (1985) Changes in Poverty and
Income Inequalities in Pakistan during 1970s. The Pakistan Development
Review 23,3-4. 407-19.
Gaiha, R. (1985) Poverty, Technology and Infrastructure in Rural
India. Cambridge Journal of Economics 9, 221-245.
Gazdar, H., S. Howes, and S. Zaidi (1994) Pakistan: Recent Trends
in Poverty. Mimeo. Background Paper for Pakistan Poverty Assessment,
World Bank Islamabad.
Jafri, S. M. Younas (1999) Assessing Poverty in Pakistan. In A
Profile of Poverty in Pakistan. Islamabad: Mahbubul Haq Center for Human
Development and UNDP.
Mahmood, M. (1999) Macro Explanations of Poverty. In A Profile of
Poverty in Pakistan. Islamabad: Mahbubul Haq Center for Human
Development and UNDP.
Mahmood, Z. (1984) Inequality in Pakistan: An Analysis of Existing
Evidence. The Pakistan Development Review 23:2-3, 365-76.
Malik, M. H. (1988) Some New Evidence on the Incidence of Poverty
in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 27:4, 509-515.
Malik, S. (1996) Determinants of Rural Poverty in Pakistan: A Micro
Study. The Pakistan Development Review 35, 171-187.
Mathur, P. N. (1967) An Appropriate System of Deflation of Sectoral
Income in a Developing Economy: Illustrated by the Industrial Sector of
the Indian Economy (1950-51 to 1962-63). The Review of Income and
Wealth, Journal of the International Association for Research in Income
and Wealth. Income and wealth Series 13:1
Mujahid, G. B. S. (1978) A Note on Measurement of Poverty and
Income Inequalities in Pakistan: Some Observations and Methodology. The
Pakistan Development Review 17:4.
Naseem, S. Mohammad (1973) Mass Poverty in Pakistan: Some
Preliminary Findings. The Pakistan Development Review 13:4.
Naseem, S. Mohammd (1996) The Informal Sector and Urban Poverty
Alleviation in Pakistan. In ESCAP: Role of Informal Sector in Poverty
Alleviation. New York: United Nations.
Shirazi, N. S. (1995) Determinants of Poverty in Pakistan. Pakistan
Economic and Social Review 33: 1&2, 91-101.
Tahir, Syed, and Salman Syed Ali (1999) Growth with Equity: Policy
Lessons From Experience of Pakistan. In Growth with Equity. Bangkok:
ESCAP.
(1) See Appendix I.
(2) See Appendix II.
Comments
The study by Dr Azid and Dr Malik is based on information of 90
households of a village. It is divided in two parts, in the first part,
the authors apply a Logit Model to examine the role of technological,
village and household-specific variables on probability of being poor.
The authors conclude that most of the variables have expected signs and
the results are statistically significant, in the second part, the
authors divide the data by income segments and conclude that
household-specific and village-specific characteristics affect poverty.
The paper is very interesting in terms of methodology adopted and
the conclusions drawn. However, I would like to give few suggestions to
clarify the results.
(1) It will be useful to add some discussion on the characteristics
of the village, like the population size, education and health status of
the population and the major occupations, land holdings and others.
(2) It will be interesting if the authors add a brief discussion
for the rationale of applying the segmentation approach in the second
part. It will be useful to know how this approach can improve the
understanding about the poverty.
(3) It is not clear whether the unit of observation used in the
regression analysis is household or individual. Furthermore, how the
segmentation of highest group was done as there is only one household in
that group?
(4) How the poverty line is determined? Is it national poverty line
or the village-specific poverty line?
(5) The results presented in Table 3 are quite confusing. Sometimes
it contradicts the results presented in the earlier tables. For example,
the results for the household size variable are different in the two
parts but no explanation is provided for this change.
(6) Occupational choice is an important variable for determining
individual's earnings. The authors may include this variable in the
model.
(7) Based on Table 3, the authors conclude that village and
individual characteristics are important determinants of income in each
segment. But it does not tell us whether the differences in coefficients
across segments are statistically significant or not.
(8) The authors should add the number of observations for each
regression equation in Table 3.
Incorporating these details in the paper will improve the
exposition of the paper and the researchers and policy-makers will be
able to benefit from the findings.
Rehana Siddiqui
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Toseef Azid is Associate Professor, Department of Economics,
Bahauddin Zakariya University, Multan. Shahnawaz Malik is Professor and
Chainnan, Department of Economics, Bahauddin Zakariya University,
Multan.
Table 1 Description of the Segments Based on Households' Per Capita
Income
Size of Segment Number
No. (Per Capita Income) of HH Share in the Total Income (%)
1 300.00 01 00.28
2 333.33 03 01.28
3 416.66-510.42 22 13.00
4 520.80-555.50 11 20.29
5 583.33-638.83 8 25.05
6 666.66-700.00 11 33.05
7 714.25-800.00 9 40.73
8 833.33-1071.42 13 54.13
9 1166.66-1833.33 6 68.81
10 4166.66 1 76.63
11 4583.33 1 81.79
12 5000 1 87.41
13 5500 1 93.67
14 6750 1 100.00
Source: Based on village survey conducted by the authors.
Table 2
Households and Their Share in the Per Capita Income in the Selected
Segments (%)
No. Size of Segment HH (%) Share in the Total Income
3 416.66-510.42 24.44(6) 11.72(5)
4 520.80-555.50 12.22(4) 07.29(2)
5 583.33-638.83 08.88(2) 04.76(1)
6 666.66-700.00 12.22(4) 08.00(4)
7 714.25-800.00 10.00(3) 07.68(3)
8 833.33-1071.42 14.44(5) 13.40(6)
9 1166.66-1833.33 06.66(1) 14.68(7)
Note: Values in the parenthesis show their relative ranks.
Source: Based on village survey conducted by the authors.
Table 3
Regression Results of the Classified Segments
Groups
[right arrow]
Variables Lower
[down arrow] Poorest Poorer Poor Middle
Me 0.6439 0.7342 0.5417 0.3218
(2.07) * (1.38) (1.33) (1.09)
Cr 0.3421 0.562 0.9845 0.3322
(1.07) (2.38) * -1.33 (2.10) *
Tra 0.4208 0.6589 0.8703 0.0975
(2.90) * (2.90) * (2.39) * (2.65) *
El 0.7508 0.9357 0.76 0.409
(2.09) * (2.88) * (2.76) * (2.99) *
HYV 0.4458 0.6809 0.0089 0.0023
(21.02) -1.54 -1.23 (2.96) *
HS -0.0965 -0.2987 -0.0721 0.651
(-2.07) (-2.79) * (2.19) * (2.19) *
De -0.8934 -0.0954 -0.6408 -0.0842
(-1.04) (-2.54) * (-2.23) * (-2.69) *
PR 0.4398 0.4095 0.4093 0.095
-0.97 (2.39) * -0.93 -1.09
Fm 0.2334 0.2392 0.239 0.3003
(2.04) * (2.45) * (2.73) * (2.60) *
Groups
[right arrow]
Variables Upper
[down arrow] Middle Middle
Me 0.4433 0.7735
(0.98) * (2.65) *
Cr 0.534 0.8541
(2.76)* (2.90) *
Tra 0.9418 0.0967
-0.89 -0.65
El 0.0872 0.3008
(2.66) * (2.43) *
HYV 0.0234 0.0486
(2.67) * (2.52) *
HS -0.9736 -0.8531
(-2.75) * (2.35) *
De -0.078 -0.063
(-1.53) (-1.25)
PR 0.0933 0.063
(2.86) * (2.830 *
Fm 0.2508 0.039
(1.09) -1.35