Impact of fiscal adjustment on income distribution in Pakistan.
Iqbal, Zafar ; Siddiqui, Rizwana
This study provides a quantitative assessment of selected fiscal
adjustment policies on income distribution in Pakistan. Using a latest
social accounting matrix for the year 1989-90 and the static fixed-price
model, various simulation exercises have been performed. The results
show that reduction in subsidies has more adverse impact on the incomes
of the richest rural and urban households, implying that the richest
people in the country are the greater beneficiaries of subsidies
provided by the government. The evidence also suggests that a
contraction in government current spending appears to have a negative
impact on the incomes of all urban and rural household groups but the
largest reduction appears in the income of the richest rural, followed
by the poorest urban. The simulation results indicate that a decline in
public expenditure on education and health affects the poorest urban and
poorest rural more than the relatively better-off urban and rural income
groups. Further, the estimates of Gini-coefficients show that reduction
in consumption subsidies improves income distribution in both rural and
urban areas of Pakistan. Conversely, reduction in subsidies on
production worsens income distribution both in urban and rural areas,
while reducing overall government current expenditure leads to
deterioration of income distribution in urban areas but improves it in
rural areas marginally. Similarly, reduction in government expenditure
on education and health adversely affects income distribution in both
urban and rural areas of Pakistan.
1. INTRODUCTION
Structural adjustment reforms advocated by the World Bank and the
IMF began in Pakistan in 1988. The Bank-Fund adjustment programmes were
intended primarily to overcome a variety of macroeconomic distortions as
well as resolve a set of deep-rooted structural problems in the economy.
After more than a decade of intensive adjustment reforms, there is no
consensus on the effects they have had on Pakistan's economy. More
recently, the important area of research has been the analyses of the
social impact of adjustment reforms, particularly on income distribution
and poverty, using an appropriate quantitative framework. This paper
attempts to contribute to a better assessment of fiscal reforms under
structural adjustment and their impact on income distribution in
Pakistan.
In general, poverty and income distribution in developing countries
are closely related to internal and external economic policies adopted
by the government. Since 1988, under the rubric of structural adjustment
programme (SAP), Pakistan has made use of fiscal, monetary and trade
policies to correct her macroeconomic imbalances and to improve social
indicators. Besides macroeconomic performance, it is hard to
substantiate with proof that these programmes protect the poor. For
example, Khan (1993) found that only 7 out of 55 developing countries
opting for SAP had a favourable impact on the living standard of the
poor of these countries. A number of studies including Anwar (1996);
Khattak and Jaffery (1995) and Kemal (1994) have found that SAP was
accompanied by rising income inequality and poverty in Pakistan. (1)
This paper uses a simple static fixed-price SAM-based framework to
analyse distributional impact on incomes of rural and urban households
in Pakistan. This methodology is useful because social accounting matrix
(SAM) represents the whole economy and it does not need a large data
set. The SAM frameworks have been interpreted specifically valid for
fiscal adjustment.
There are two main objectives of the paper. First, it develops a
latest social accounting matrix for the year 1989-90 with possible
disaggregation of the households sector based on income levels. The
first social accounting matrix (SAM) for Pakistan was constructed by the
PIDE (1985) for the year 1979-80. SAM-1979-80(1985) had been
disaggregated into 8 products, 12 activities and 10 households groups.
Cohen (1987) used, this SAM(1984-85) for estimating the impact
multipliers and as a baseline data system for consistency model. The SAM
for the year 1984-85 developed by the Federal Bureau of Statistics (1993), did not provide a disaggregation of the households sector. This
omission drastically reduced the significance of data for analysis of
the households sector, particularly if distributive and redistributive
aspects are to be emphasised. This paper fills this gap. The second
objective of the paper is to analyse the impact of fiscal reforms
relating to subsidies (production and consumption subsidies), government
current expenditure and expenditure on health and education on incomes
of various urban and rural households in Pakistan. Thus, it attempts to
seek an appropriate answer of the main research question: whether or not
fiscal reforms under structural adjustment have had adverse effects on
income distribution in Pakistan. However, this study captures only some
of the main fiscal policy variables involved in structural adjustment
reforms, not all by any means.
The plan of the paper is as follows. Following introduction,
Section 2 presents historical overview of fiscal adjustment reforms and
income distribution in Pakistan. Section 3 describes methodology and
data. Results are discussed in Section 4. Final section gives concluding
remarks.
2. OVERVIEW OF FISCAL ADJUSTMENT POLICIES AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION
Fiscal performance of Pakistan had deteriorated significantly by
1987-88. Budget deficit had reached a staggering 8.5 percent of GDP in
that year. A large portion of government expenditure was being utilised
on subsidies: consumer subsidies were supposed to help the poor and
production subsidies to provide assistance in production process and for
exports. There were many tax exemptions. Pakistan badly needed tax
reforms with efficiency and equity objectives as well as to reduce
budget deficit by revenue generation alongside reduction in current
expenditure to free resources for development expenditure. A number of
recommendations on fiscal adjustment were made by the IMF and the World
Bank under the adjustment programme started in 1988. (2) It was
recommended that tax revenue should be increased from 13.0 percent of
GDP in 1986-87 to 16.9 percent of GDP in 1992-93 with an increase in
direct tax revenue from 1.9 percent of GDP to 3.3 percent of GDP and
indirect tax revenue from 11.2 percent of GDP to 13.6 percent of GDP. At
the same time, it was emphasised to bring a gradual reduction in
government total expenditure from 26.7 percent of GDP in 1987-88 to 24.8
percent of GDP in 1990-91 by reducing current expenditure with main
emphasis on lowering subsidies from 1.7 percent of GDP to 0.5 percent of
GDP. Since 1988, therefore, the government has been trying to reverse
the inherited trend in fiscal balance by broadening the tax base,
abolishing tax exemptions and tax holidays and increasing the elasticity
of tax system by shifting the emphasis from imports to domestic
consumption. Initially, consumption subsidies were allowed to cushion the poor against rising prices of essentials, such as wheat and edible
oils, while production subsidies were aimed at promoting economic
activities in larger national interest. Key indicators of fiscal policy
in Pakistan are reported in Table 1. Under the deregulation plan and to
move towards more market oriented economy, subsidies have been
substantially withdrawn from 1.7 percent of GDP in 1988-89 to 0.5
percent of GDP in 1997-98. Current and development expenditures have
also declined, respectively, from 19.8 percent to 18.8 percent of GDP
and from 6.9 percent to 3.1 percent of GDP. Fiscal deficit has declined
from 8.5 percent of GDP in 1987-88 to 4.7 percent of GDP during 1998-99.
Table 1 also shows that public expenditure on education and health have
also declined, even though SAP was designed to increase expenditure on
education and health. Similarly, though the fiscal adjustment programmes
emphasise resource mobilisation and low income groups were supposed to
be protected, recent studies show that income inequality has increased
during the period of adjustment in Pakistan.
Historical trend in income distribution indicated by
Gini-coefficients along with GDP growth rates are presented in Table 2.
It shows that the economy has been growing satisfactorily, but income
distribution has worsened over the period 1988 to 1999. (3)
Gini-coefficients for Pakistan as a whole and for rural and urban areas,
reported in Table 2, show an increase from 0.35, 0.31 and 0.35 in
1987-88 to 0.40, 0.35 and 0.40 in 1993-94, respectively. Most recent
estimates of Gini-coefficients for the year 1998-99 also show that
income inequality has worsened since 1993-94 [see Siddiqui and Iqbal
(1999)]. Table 2 also shows that on the whole, income distribution
during the period under consideration has worsened in urban areas as
compared to rural areas except in 1990-91. (4)
3. METHODOLOGY AND DATA
This section briefly describes the salient features of the social
accounting matrix used for analysis (5) and explains the simple static
fixed-price SAM-based model used to analyse the impact of selected
fiscal policies under structural adjustment on households incomes.
Structure of a Social Accounting Matrix
Interest in social accounting matrix has emerged in the last three
decades, when it has been extensively used as a tool for policy
analysis. (6) The SAM framework is also commonly used in computable
general equilibrium (CGE) models for analysing structural adjustment
reforms and their impact on income distribution and poverty in
developing countries, for example, Robinson (1988) and Taylor (1990)
provided a comprehensive survey on SAM-based CGE modelling. The
classification and disaggregation of accounts in a social accounting
matrix can take various forms, depending on how the constituent accounts
are defined and depending on one's analytical interests and
specific policy concerns.
As a pre-requisite, the compilation of a comprehensive input-output
(I-O) table started in Pakistan in 1975-76 and the first detailed I-O
table was produced in 1983. The social accounting matrix for the year
1979 was published in 1985 by the Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics (1985). The Federal Bureau of Statistics (FBS) compiled a
social accounting matrix for the year 1984-85, using I-O table and
Institutional Sector Accounts for the same year. The FBS produced the
second I-O table for the year 1989-90. The information presented in I-O
table 1989-90 includes supply and use tables and the industry by
industry flow table. The I-O table provides an elaboration of production
account of the system of national accounts in Pakistan for the year
1989-90. The Integrated Economic Accounts (IEA) have also been compiled
in conjunction with the I-O table for 1989-90. (7) The IEA was developed
using different data sources including National Accounts Statistics;
Balance of Payment Statistics; Household Income and Expenditure Survey
and Public Finance Statistics. The IEA provide a comprehensive overview
of inter-relationships between economic agents involved in income
generation, distribution, accumulation and finance in the economy. The
full details of the methodology and data sources used in the preparation
are described in the main documents of I-O table and IEA for 1989-90.
(8)
Since the FBS did not produce the SAM for the year 1989-90, we
attempt to compile the SAM for 1989-90, using I-O table and IEA for the
same year. This effort yields a 28 x 28 social accounting matrix of
Pakistan reported in Appendix. Table 1. (9) The SAM-1989-90, presents a
summarised but comprehensive picture of the whole economy by showing the
interrelationship among different aspects of economic transactions in
production, consumption, and investment. According to standard
accounting; principles of a SAM, incoming (income) in one account is
balanced by an outgoing (expenditure) of another account. Since incoming
and outgoing are recorded in a single entry system, the SAM is a square
matrix by definition. For every row there is a corresponding column and
sum along the row is equal to the sum along the corresponding column.
The SAM 1989-90 presents four types of accounts: factors accounts,
institutions accounts, activities accounts, and the rest of the world
(ROW) account. These accounts are disaggregated on the basis of
requirements and availability of data. Factors of production account is
disaggregated into labour and capital accounts. Institutions accounts
consist of households, firms (non-financial and financial), government,
and rest of the world. Households account is further disaggregated by
four income categories of rural and urban households. These accounts
elaborate the inter-institutional linkages. Production account is
disaggregated into agriculture, industry, education, health and other
sectors. Further disaggregation of production account is also made on
the basis of goods for domestic market and for export market. Finally,
it presents consolidated capital account. Since the analysis mainly
focuses on the households sector, the following sub-section describes
the disaggregation of the households by income groups and their sources
and uses of income in more detail.
Sources and Uses of Incomes of Households
(a) Sources of Income of Households
Table 3 shows the sources of incomes of various urban and rural
income groups during the year 1989-90. These estimates are derived from
Appendix Table 1. Both urban and rural households are classified into
four income groups namely lowest income group having monthly income up
to Rs 2500, low income group, with monthly income ranging between Rs
2501 and Rs 4000, middle income group with monthly income range of Rs
4001-Rs 7000 and high income group earning above Rs 7001 per month.
Table 3 indicates that wages and salaries contribute the highest share
of 54.2 percent in the total income of the urban lowest income group
while the remaining sources of income of this group are operating
surplus (42.2 percent), dividends from firms (1.1 percent), transfers
from the government (1.1 percent) and transfers from the rest of the
world (1.3 percent). Similarly, for the low income group, wages and
salaries contribute 46.7 percent, operating surplus 44.7 percent,
dividends from firms 4.3 percent, transfers from the government 0.56
percent, and transfers from the rest of the world 3.7 percent in its
total income. In contrast, the middle and the high income groups,
respectively, receive largest share of income from operating surplus
46.7 percent and 40.1 percent. The remaining sources of incomes of both
these income groups are, correspondingly, wages and salaries 38.8
percent and 28.5 percent, dividends from firms 5.8 percent and 11.6
percent, transfers from the government 1.0 percent and 2.1 percent, and
transfers from the rest of the world 7.7 percent and 17.7 percent of
their total incomes.
Among rural households, operating surplus contributes the largest
share in incomes of all the four categories of rural income groups, i.e.
56.6 percent, 68.3 percent, 72.0 percent and 61.5 percent in incomes of
the lowest, low, middle and high income groups, respectively. The other
sources of incomes of all the four rural income groups are,
correspondingly, wages and salaries 37.4 percent, 21.3 percent, 15.5
percent, and 7.6 percent; dividends from firms 2.6 percent, 5.2 percent,
7.4 percent, and 17.1 percent; transfers from the government 0.75
percent, 0.5 percent, 0.31 percent, and 4.3 percent; and transfers from
the rest of the world are 2.7 percent, 4.7 percent, 4.8 percent and 9.6
percent.
(b) Uses of Income by Rural and Urban Households
The respective columns of the social accounting matrix reported in
Appendix Table 1 give uses of income by the various rural and urban
income groups, which are the same as defined earlier in the case of
sources of incomes. The uses of incomes are summarised in Table 4. By
definition total uses of income are equal to total income from all
sources of the respective income groups. Starting with urban households,
the largest share of total income is spent on manufactured products by
all the four urban income groups; the share being 56.0 percent, 45.8
percent, 38.4 percent, and 22.7 percent for the lowest to the highest
income groups. The second largest expenditure component is on
agricultural product where the lowest income group spends 43.2 percent,
low income group 34.9 percent, middle income group 28.2 percent and high
income group 15.7 percent of their total incomes. On other activities
(including services), lowest income group spends 29.8 percent, low
income group 27.2 percent, middle income group 25.0 percent and high
income group 23.9 percent of their incomes. Table 4 also shows that all
these groups spend a small fraction of their income i.e. less than 2
percent on education an health. It is interesting to note that all the
urban income groups pay less than 1 percent of their incomes as direct
taxes to the government. It is also evident from Table 4 that both the
urban lowest and low income groups are net dissavers (i.e. -30.8 percent
and -10.0 percent of their income, respectively) while the other two
groups middle and high income groups save, respectively, 6.0 percent and
35.4 percent of their total incomes.
Among rural households, Table 4 shows different uses of incomes by
the lowest, low, middle and high income groups in Pakistan. Very much
like the urban households, all rural income groups spend the largest
proportion of their incomes (i.e. 57.3 percent, 42.2 percent, 33.4
percent, and 16.6 percent, respectively) on manufactured goods. While
the second largest consumption component is agricultural product on
which they spend, correspondingly, 45.9 percent, 34.1 percent, 26.2
percent, and 12.8 percent of their total incomes. The expenditure on
other commodities (including services) remains 23.7 percent, 19.5
percent, 17.4 percent, and 11.0 percent, respectively. Like the urban
income groups, the rural income groups also spend a small proportion of
their income on health and education which is even lesser than spending
by the urban groups. The rural income groups also pay a small amount of
their incomes (i.e. less than 1 percent except highest income group
which pays 1.3 percent) as direct taxes to the government. Table 4 shows
that the rural lowest income group is a net dissaver of 28.6 percent of
its income while the other three groups are savers as the low income
group saves 2.9 percent, middle income group 21.7 percent, and high
income group 57.7 percent of their total incomes.
A Static Fixed-Price SAM-Based Model
A static fixed-price SAM-based model is used to calculate the
impact multipliers of socioeconomic linkages using the social accounting
matrix for the year 1989-90 reported in Appendix Table 1. This simple
model provides multipliers in a general equilibrium framework. The
multipliers can be further decomposed to derive the direct and indirect
effects and the main causal linkages underlying the structure of the
economy. The multiplier model used in this study resembles Pyatt and
Round (1985) includes Leontief input-output multipliers and the impact
of exogenous shocks on income generation, distribution and consumption.
The procedure of the multiplier analysis is as follows. In a SAM-based
analysis, it is a common practice to take government accounts, capital
accounts, and the rest of the world accounts are assumed to be
exogenously determined. Thus, exogenous accounts are taken into vector
x. All other accounts treated as endogenous accounts are denoted by
vector y. The x and y vectors are connected by a matrix A, which is
formed by dividing each cell in the SAM by its column total. The model
can thus be written as Equation (1) where the inverse of matrix A is the
matrix of aggregate multipliers [M.sub.a].
y = Ay + x = [(I - A).sup.-1] . x = [M.sub.a] . x ... ... ... ...
(1)
The matrix of aggregate multipliers [M.sub.1], [M.sub.2], and
[M.sub.3] derive direct, open and closed-loop effects. [M.sub.1]
captures the effects of one group on itself through direct transfers.
[M.sub.2] captures the open or cross-effects of the multiplier process
whereby an injection into one part of the system has repercussions on
other parts. [M.sub.3] shows the closed or full circular effects of an
income injection going round the system and back to its point of origin
in a series of repeated and dampening cycles. The expression for the
decomposition is a multiplicative one, which is written as follows:
y = ([M.sub.3] . [M.sub.2] . [M.sub.1]) . x ... ... ... ... ... ...
(2)
Pyatt and Round (1977), following Stone, respecify the
decomposition in Equation (2) in an additive form, giving Equation (3)
as:
y = (I + T + O + C) . x ... ... ... ... ... (3)
where
I = initial impulse or identity multiplier (unit increase)
T = ([M.sub.1] - I) named as transfer multiplier
O = ([M.sub.2] - I) . [M.sub.1] named as open-loop multiplier
C = ([M.sub.3] - I) . [M.sub.2] . [M.sub.1] named as closed-loop
multiplier.
In this study, we undertake the multiplier analysis using Equation
(1) and simulate the effects of exogenous changes relating to fiscal
policy in Pakistan. The simulation results are further decomposed using
Equation (3), which provides transfer, open and closed loop effects of
exogenous shocks on income distribution of aforementioned various urban
and rural income groups. The results are reported in Appendix Table 2.
4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
The results of selected adjustment polices on households incomes
and income distribution represented by Gini-coefficients are described
in the following subsections.
Impact of Fiscal Adjustment Policies on Households Incomes
At the outset, it is important to mention that the multipliers need
to be interpreted with caution because of several restrictive
assumptions underlying the multiplier methodology. For example, first,
the size of the multipliers depends on the choice of the exogenous
variables, which in turn depends on the problem studied. Second, the SAM
framework describes an endogenous economy with fixed relative prices.
Third, cell entries of the SAM are amounts, i.e., products of prices
times quantities which are not explicitly disentangled. Fourth, the
coefficient matrix in the SAM framework is a matrix of fixed average
proportions. Finally, the SAM framework considers the demand side only.
(10)
The aggregate multipliers ([M.sub.a]) and its decomposition into
initial impulse (I), transfer multiplier (T), open-loop multiplier (O),
and closed-loop multiplier (C) are reported in Appendix. Table 2. The
results show that values in column ([M.sub.a]) give the
'backward' linkages of the endogenous accounts, which indicate
the measure of the opportunities offered to suppliers arising from
marginal changes in final demand (i.e. exogenous accounts). The
multipliers for all endogenous accounts imply a high degree of
integration. For the production sectors, backward linkages are strongest
for the education, followed by agriculture, health, other sectors and
industry. Among the households income groups, the largest backward
linkage is for the urban poorest (HU1 having income less than Rs 2500
per month) and the smallest for the rural rich (HR4 having income more
than Rs 7000 per month). Table 5 which summarises the simulation results
of changes in various fiscal policy variables on all households income
groups along with other endogenous accounts should be the prime focus of
attention. Here, the simple simulation exercise assesses the nature of
socio-economic linkages in Pakistan's economy. The simulation
results are briefly explained as follows. (11)
(i) 50 Percent Reduction in Subsidies
In almost all the structural and sectoral adjustment programmes,
much emphasis has been placed on reduction in subsidies. As indicated
earlier in Table 1, since the start of SAP, subsidies have been
significantly reduced from Rs 7.3 billion in 1988-89 (1.7 percent of
GDP) to Rs 3.2 billion (0.5 percent of GDP) in 1997-98, showing one of
the most significant compliance indicators of structural adjustment
programmes in Pakistan. Using the simple model described above, the
simulations arc performed by reducing the overall subsidies as well as
consumption and production subsidies separately by 50 percent. The
results reported in Table 5 show that the most pronounced effect of
reduction of overall subsidies is on the incomes of the richest rural
(HR4 having income more than Rs 7000 per month) and the richest urban
(HU4 having income more than Rs 7000 per month) as their respective
incomes declined by 3.5 and 2.3 percent. This is followed by the poorest
urban and poorest rural (HU1 and HR1 both having income less than Rs
2500 per month) as their incomes are reduced by 2.1 percent and 1.9
percent, respectively. By halving consumption and production subsidies
separately the production subsidies alone seem to affect the poorest
group the most followed by the poorest urban and poorest rural. These
results imply that the richest people in the country are the greater
beneficiary of government subsidies. Among the producing sectors, the
reduction in overall subsidies has more adverse impact on the
agriculture sector, followed by industry, other sectors, health, and
education. Table 5 also shows that the operating surplus of capital
declines more than wages of the labour from a reduction in overall
subsidies.
(ii) 5 Percent Reduction in Government Overall Current Expenditure
One of the major concerns of the structural adjustment programmes
is the reduction of public current expenditure in order to correct the
persistent fiscal imbalances in Pakistan. On the basis of concerted
efforts, public current expenditure has reduced from 19.8 percent of GDP
in 1987-88 to 18.0 percent of GDP in 1997-98. The main results of a 5
percent reduction in government current expenditure on incomes of urban
and rural households are presented in Table 5. To standardise
simulations, the level of government overall current expenditure has
been reduced by 5 percent below the level of base year 1989-90. The
results indicate that a contraction in government spending has a
negative impact on the incomes of all the urban and rural household
groups. The largest reduction appears to be in the income of the richest
rural (HR4), followed by poorest urban (HU1), whose incomes are reduced
by 1.9 percent and 1.8 percent, respectively. Among factors of
production, labour income is affected more (1.9 percent reduction) than
capital income (1.7 percent decline). For the production sector,
reduction in government current spending has more adverse impact on
education followed by health, other sectors, agriculture and industry.
(iii) 10 Percent Reduction in Government Expenditure on Education
and Health
In the recent adjustment reforms, it has been greatly emphasised to
increase investment on education and health in order to enhance human
capital in the country. The role of human capital in explaining
variation in the rate of growth of output is one that has been given
considerable attention in the current literature as human capital is
perceived as a primary source of economic growth. (12) In spite of this
positive relationship, the government expenditure on education and
health in Pakistan has declined from 3.4 percent of GDP in 1987-88 to
3.0 percent of GDP in 1997-98. Table 5 reports the simulation results of
a 10 percent decline in public expenditure on education and health. It
is clear that this policy action reduces activities in the education
sector by 7.6 percent and the health sector by 5.1 percent. It also
shows that the poorest urban (HU1) and poorest rural (HR1) are more
adversely affected than the other relatively better-off urban and rural
income groups. Similarly, income of the labour declines relatively more
than operating surplus of the capital.
(iv) Simulation Results of Simultaneous Shock of all Three Policies
Because of interlinkages, it is essential that rather than pursuing
individual policies a complete package is implemented. Thus, all the
aforementioned policy variables (i.e. 50 percent reduction in overall
subsidies, 5 percent reduction in overall government current
expenditure, and 10 percent reduction in government expenditure on
education and health) are now taken together and policy simulations are
performed collectively. The results of the combination of policy reforms
are reported in Table 5, which show that all joint policies have
considerable negative impact on incomes of rural and urban households
groups. Among the urban households, the poorest income group absorbs the
greatest heat than the other income groups as its income is reduced by
4.5 percent. Among rural households, the richest rural income group is
affected more as its income is reduced by 5.5 percent, followed by the
poorest rural income group whose income is declined by 4.1 percent.
Among factors of production, the adverse impact is more serious on
labour income than capital income. Among production sectors, combined
adjustment policies have considerable negative impact on education,
followed by the health sector as activities in these sectors decline by
11.9 percent and 9.1 percent, respectively.
Impact of Fiscal Adjustment Policies on Income Distribution
More recently, reduction in poverty and improvement in income
distribution have been the main objectives of Structural Adjustment
Programmes in Pakistan. As the main purpose of the study is to make some
judgement about the impact of fiscal adjustment policies on income
distribution in Pakistan, we focus on the widely used indicator of
income distribution i.e. Gini-coefficients which are calculated from the
original data on urban and rural households income reported in SAM,
1989-90 (Appendix Table 1). Table 6 shows the actual Gini-coefficient
(Gini Actual) for urban households is 0.3878 and for rural households
0.3874. The Gini Actual is compared with the calculated
Gini-coefficients based on incomes of urban and rural households
generated through simulation exercises (reported in Table 5). If the
calculated Gini-coefficient based on simulation is higher than the
actual Gini-coefficient, it implies that the respective adjustment
policy has adverse impact on income distribution in Pakistan and vise
versa.
Both the actual and calculated Gini-coefficients are reported in
Table 6. Gini 1 based on first policy simulation (50 percent reduction
in consumption subsidies) shows that reduction in consumption subsidies
improves income distribution in both rural and urban areas of Pakistan,
but improvement in income distribution in rural areas is more than in
urban areas as Gini 1 for urban areas falls from actual 0.3878 to
calculated 0.3871. For rural areas, the Gini 1 falls from Gini Actual
0.3874 to calculated 0.3853. This result also supports the above
findings that the richest people in urban and rural areas are the
greater beneficiaries of government subsidies as simulation results in
Table 5 show that reduction in consumption subsidies has more adverse
effect on incomes of the urban and rural richest groups as compared to
the poor income groups. Conversely, calculated Gini-coefficient (Gini 2)
based on second simulation exercise (50 percent reduction in production
subsidies) shows that reduction in subsidies on production worsens
income distribution both in urban and rural areas, but income
distribution is worst in urban areas as compared to rural areas of
Pakistan as Gini 2 increases to 0.3881 and 0.3876 for urban and rural
households, respectively. Simulation 3 represents that 50 percent
subsidies on consumption and production are reduced simultaneously. The
results show that the negative impact of reduction in production
subsidies is cancelled out by the positive impact of reduction in
consumer subsidies. However, the positive effect dominates and income
distribution in both areas improves although more in rural areas of
Pakistan. Fourth simulation exercise is undertaken by reducing 5 percent
overall government current expenditure. This policy has worsened income
distribution in urban areas but improved in rural areas marginally.
Simulation 5 shows 10 percent reduction in government expenditure on
human capital indicators represented by health and education. It shows
that this policy adversely affects income distribution in both urban and
rural areas as Gini 5 is raised from Gini Actual 0.3878 to 0.3882 for
rural areas and for urban areas from 0.3874 to 0.3877. Finally, when the
model is simulated by giving all the above mentioned policy shocks
collectively, it worsens income distribution in urban areas but improves
in rural areas of Pakistan as the calculated Gini 6 for urban households
increases from Gini Actual 0.3878 to 0.3882 and for rural areas it
declines from Gini Actual 0.3874 to 0.3858. Though policy implications
derived from these results are limited in nature a fair idea can be
obtained about the impact of adjustment policies on income distribution
in Pakistan.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The first objective of this exercise is to understand
Pakistan's economy, The starting point therefore is to design a
social accounting matrix that, through appropriate choice of
classifications, can capture its important characteristics and the
problems it faces. Therefore, the latest social accounting matrix for
the year 1989-90, using the Integrated Institutional Accounts and
Input-Output Table for the same year, is compiled. The matrix framework
provides useful information about the structure of Pakistan's
economy. Within this framework, the preferred classifications of various
accounts are undertaken according to policy objectives. Here, the matrix
is used as a tool for structural analysis to provide a quantitative
description of the process of production, consumption, distribution, and
accumulation.
Using a static fixed-price SAM-based model, related simulation
exercises are performed to describe the impact of three key fiscal
adjustment policies namely 50 percent reduction in subsidies, 5 percent
reduction in overall public current spending, and 10 percent reduction
in public spending on education and health (referred to as human
capital) on incomes of various urban and rural households groups in
Pakistan. The main conclusions are as follows:
First, the results show that reduction in subsidies has the more
adverse impact on the incomes of the richest rural and urban households,
implying that the richest people in the country are the greater
beneficiaries of government subsidies. The second most affected income
groups of falling subsidies are the poorest urban and poorest rural. In
particular, consumption subsidies are basically to provide assistance in
consumption to the poor but the richest urban and rural groups are
benefiting more. Second, the effects of a contraction in government
spending appear to be negative on the incomes of all the urban and rural
household groups. The largest reduction appears in the income of the
richest rural, followed by poorest urban. Third, the simulation results
show that reduced public expenditure on education and health slows down
activities in the education and health sectors. It also shows that the
poorest urban and poorest rural are affected more than the other
relatively better-off urban and rural income groups. Finally, the
results of the combinations of the policy reforms show that all joint
policies have considerable negative impact on incomes of all the rural
and urban households groups. Among the urban households, the poorest
income group are affected more than the other income groups. Among rural
households, the richest rural income group is affected more, followed by
the poorest rural income group.
Regarding the impact of adjustment reforms on income distribution,
the estimates of Gini-coefficients show that reduction in consumption
subsidies improves income distribution in both rural and urban areas of
Pakistan. Conversely, reduction in subsidies on production worsens
income distribution both in urban and rural areas. Reducing overall
government current expenditure worsens income distribution in urban
areas but improves it in rural areas marginally. Similarly, reduction in
government expenditure on human capital indicators adversely affects
income distribution in both urban and rural areas. Finally, all policy
shocks collectively worsens income distribution in urban areas but
improve that in rural areas of Pakistan. It is worth noting that because
of several restrictive assumptions underlying the multiplier
methodology, policy implications derived from the results obtained in
the study are limited in nature though a fair idea can be obtained about
the impact of changes in exogenous demand, that is, the results show
that structural adjustment programmes have worse distributional impact
on urban and rural households incomes in Pakistan.
This analysis does not claim to cover all policy variables involved
in structural adjustment reforms. Only some of the main. There is thus a
need to explore the potential influence of other variables in future
research on this topic. However, the present analysis can be extended by
developing a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model for
Pakistan's economy in order to analyse all possible structural
adjustment policies on poverty and income distribution in Pakistan.
Appendix
Appendix Table 1
Social Accounting Matrix of Pakistan, 1989-90
Factors of
Production Institutions
HUI
Labour Capital (Urban)
(1) (2) (3)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3) 32446 25252
HU2 (Urban) (4) 37200 35573
HU3 (Urban) (5) 34383 41347
HU4 (Urban) (6) 29121 41005
HR1 (Rural) (7) 38959 59032
HR2 (Rural) (8) 17847 57223
HR3 (Rural) (9) 13040 60586
HR4 (Rural) (10) 6293 51040
Firms (11) 86339
Government (12) 126
Capital (13) -18408
Agriculture (14)
Industry (15)
Education (16)
Health (17)
Other Sectors (18)
Agriculture (19) 25837
Industry (20) 33485
Education (21) 406
Health (22) 556
Other Sectors (23) 17820
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28)
Total (29) 209289 457397 59822
Institutions
HU2 HU3 HU4
(Urban) (Urban) (Urban)
(4) (5) (6)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12) 329 640 649
Capital (13) -7973 5281 36215
Agriculture (14)
Industry (15)
Education (16)
Health (17)
Other Sectors (18)
Agriculture (19) 27784 24995 16085
Industry (20) 36436 34039 23174
Education (21) 742 851 1363
Health (22) 606 637 327
Other Sectors (23) 21677 22181 24415
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28)
Total (29) 79601 88624 102228
Institutions
HR1 HR2 HR3
(Rural) (Rural) (Rural)
(7) (8) (9)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12) 255 127 204
Capital (13) -29801 2408 18211
Agriculture (14)
Industry (15)
Education (16)
Health (17)
Other Sectors (18)
Agriculture (19) 47929 28600 22050
Industry (20) 59768 35334 28120
Education (21) 404 366 337
Health (22) 1004 594 549
Other Sectors (23) 24758 16347 14642
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28)
Total (29) 104317 83776 84113
Institutions
HR4
(Rural) Firms Government
(10) (11) (12)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3) 680 681
HU2 (Urban) (4) 3403 445
HU3 (Urban) (5) 5150 884
HU4 (Urban) (6) 11842 2191
HR1 (Rural) (7) 2719 786
HR2 (Rural) (8) 4325 419
HR3 (Rural) (9) 6231 263
HR4 (Rural) (10) 14209 3556
Firms (11) 45308
Government (12) 1079 24588
Capital (13) 47912 37787 -40165
Agriculture (14) 0
Industry (15) 4742
Education (16) 2
Health (17) 0
Other Sectors (18) 3534
Agriculture (19) 10618 0
Industry (20) 13805 0
Education (21) 204 14137
Health (22) 276 4231
Other Sectors (23) 9166 102438
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28) 20713
Total (29) 83060 131647 143452
Institutions Activities
Capital Agriculture Industry
(13) (14) (15)
Labour (1) 45681 45415
Capital (2) 157847 83837
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12) 1557 44845
Capital (13) 9165 20785
Agriculture (14)
Industry (15)
Education (16)
Health (17)
Other Sectors (18)
Agriculture (19) 1458 49893 103486
Industry (20) 96225 37381 227552
Education (21) 7 0 82
Health (22) 14 12 31
Other Sectors (23) 65348 55832 149439
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28)
Total (29) 163052 357368 675472
Activities
Other
Education Health Sectors
(16) (17) (18)
Labour (1) 13883 2839 101471
Capital (2) 2613 2815 210285
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12) 2 4 13799
Capital (13) 836 309 49996
Agriculture (14)
Industry (15)
Education (16)
Health (17)
Other Sectors (18)
Agriculture (19) 175 0 7826
Industry (20) 505 2110 149984
Education (21) 33 0 112
Health (22) 0 176 23
Other Sectors (23) 999 670 101008
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28)
Total (29) 19046 8923 63504
Goods for Domestic Market
Agriculture Industry Education
(19) (20) (21)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12) 857 42844 0
Capital (13)
Agriculture (14) 353501
Industry (15) 568520
Education (16) 19044
Health (17)
Other Sectors (18)
Agriculture (19)
Industry (20)
Education (21)
Health (22)
Other Sectors (23)
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28) 12378 166554 0
Total (29) 366736 777918 19044
Goods for Domestic Market Goods for
Exports
Market
Other
Health Sectors Agriculture
(22) (23) (24)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12) 0 3
Capital (13)
Agriculture (14) 3867
Industry (15)
Education (16)
Health (17) 8914
Other Sectors (18) 608584
Agriculture (19)
Industry (20)
Education (21)
Health (22)
Other Sectors (23)
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28) 122 18153
Total (29) 9036 626740 3867
Goods for Exports Market
Other
Industry Health Sectors
(25) (26) (27)
Labour (1)
Capital (2)
HUI (Urban) (3)
HU2 (Urban) (4)
HU3 (Urban) (5)
HU4 (Urban) (6)
HR1 (Rural) (7)
HR2 (Rural) (8)
HR3 (Rural) (9)
HR4 (Rural) (10)
Firms (11)
Government (12)
Capital (13)
Agriculture (14)
Industry (15) 102210
Education (16)
Health (17) 9
Other Sectors (18) 22386
Agriculture (19)
Industry (20)
Education (21)
Health (22)
Other Sectors (23)
Agriculture (24)
Industry (25)
Health (26)
Other Sectors (27)
Rest of World (28)
Total (29) 102210 9 22386
Rest of
World
Rest of
World Total
(28) (29)
Labour (1) 209289
Capital (2) 457397
HUI (Urban) (3) 763 59822
HU2 (Urban) (4) 2980 79601
HU3 (Urban) (5) 6860 88624
HU4 (Urban) (6) 18069 102228
HR1 (Rural) (7) 2821 104317
HR2 (Rural) (8) 3962 83776
HR3 (Rural) (9) 3993 84113
HR4 (Rural) (10) 7962 83060
Firms (11) 131647
Government (12) 11544 143452
Capital (13) 30494 163052
Agriculture (14) 357368
Industry (15) 675472
Education (16) 19046
Health (17) 8923
Other Sectors (18) 634504
Agriculture (19) 366736
Industry (20) 777918
Education (21) 19044
Health (22) 9036
Other Sectors (23) 626740
Agriculture (24) 3867 3867
Industry (25) 102210 102210
Health (26) 9 9
Other Sectors (27) 22386 22386
Rest of World (28) 217920
Total (29) 217920
Appendix Table 2
Decomposition of Total Multiplier Effects (Backward Linkages)
Aggregate Initial Transfer
Multiplier Impulse Multiplier
([M.sub.a]) (I) (T)
Labour 12.436 1.000 .000
Capital 10.095 1.000 .000
HU1 (Urban) 14.310 1.000 .000
HU2 (Urban) 12.199 1.000 .000
HU3 (Urban) 10.540 1.000 .000
HU4 (Urban) 7.607 1.000 .000
HR1 (Rural) 14.053 1.000 .000
HR2 (Rural) 10.890 1.000 .000
HR3 (Rural) 8.969 1.000 .000
HR4 (Rural) 5.199 1.000 .000
Firms 4.119 1.000 .369
Pro. Agriculture 11.297 1.000 .000
Pro. Industry 10.169 1.000 .000
Pro. Education 12.379 1.000 .000
Pro. Health 11.193 1.000 .000
Pro. Other Sectors 10.215 1.000 .000
Dem. Agriculture 11.889 1.000 .000
Dem. Industry 8.432 1.000 .000
Dem. Education 13.379 1.000 .000
Dem. Health 12.042 1.000 .000
Dem. Other Sectors 10.920 1.000 .000
Open-Loop Closed-loop
Multiplier Multiplier
(O) (C)
Labour 2.022 9.414
Capital 1.856 7.240
HU1 (Urban) 2.436 10.874
HU2 (Urban) 2.048 9.151
HU3 (Urban) 1.745 7.794
HU4 (Urban) 1.205 5.402
HR1 (Rural) 2.389 10.664
HR2 (Rural) 1.808 8.082
HR3 (Rural) 1.458 6.511
HR4 (Rural) .768 3.431
Firms .503 2.248
Pro. Agriculture 1.933 8.364
Pro. Industry 1.712 7.457
Pro. Education 1.913 9.466
Pro. Health 1.886 8.307
Pro. Other Sectors 1.753 7.462
Dem. Agriculture 1.899 8.990
Dem. Industry 1.391 6.041
Dem. Education 1.956 10.423
Dem. Health 1.938 9.103
Dem. Other Sectors 1.844 8.075
Authors' Note: We are grateful to Dr Rehana Siddiqui and Dr G.
M. Arif for their useful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. The
research assistance provided by Abdus Sattar and Saghir Mushtaq is
highly acknowledged. We are also thankful to Federal Bureau of
Statistics, in particular, Syed Raisul-Hasan Rizvi, Mohammad Ramzan Shah, Abdul Razaq, and Zia-Ullah Khan for their help in providing
required data and useful discussions. This paper is a part of Micro
Impact of Macroeconomic Adjustment Policies (MIMAP-Pakistan) Project
under the supervision of Dr Sarfraz Khan Qureshi, former Director, the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. We are grateful
to the International Development Research Centre (IDRC), Ottawa, Canada for financial assistance for the MIMAP project. The authors are thankful
to anonymous referees of this journal for their helpful comments on an
earlier version of this paper. Any errors and omissions are of course
ours.
REFERENCES
Anwar, Tilat (1996) Structural Adjustment and Poverty: The Case of
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 35:4 911-926.
Arif, G. M., and S. Ibrahim (1999) The Process of Urbanisation in
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 37:4 507-522.
Barro, R. J. (1989) A "Cross-Country Study of Growth, Saving,
and Government. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,
Massachusetts. (NBER Working Paper No. 2855.)
Barro, R. J. (1991) Economic Growth in a Cross Section of
Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:2 407-443.
Barro, R. J., and J. W. Lee (1994) Losers and Winners in Economic
Growth. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development
Economics. 267-297.
Barro, R. J., and X. Sala-i-Martin (1995) Economic Growth. McGraw
Hill.
Becker, G., K. Murphy, and R. Tamura (1990) Human Capital,
Fertility, and Economic Growth. Journal of Political Economy 98:5 12-37.
Cohen, S. I. (1987) Modelling the Prospects of Economic Growth and
Social Development: Results of Circular Flow Planning Models Applied to
Pakistan, 1980-1993. The Pakistan Development Review 26:4 609-626.
Cohen, S. I. (1997) Economic Growth of Rich and Poor Countries: A
Social Accounting Matrix Approach. The Pakistan Development Review 36:4
765-790.
Cohen, S. I. (ed) (1993) Patterns of Economic Restructuring for
Eastern Europe. Aldershot: Avebury.
Iqbal, Z. (1996) Three Gap Analysis of Structural Adjustment in
Pakistan. PhD. Dissertation. Tilburg University, the Netherlands
(unpublished).
Iqbal, Z., and G. M. Zahid (1998) Macroeconomic Determinants of
Economic Growth in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 37:2
125-148.
Jaffery, S. M. Younas, and A. Khattak (1995) Income Inequality and
Poverty .in Pakistan. Pakistan Economic and Social Review 33:1&2
37-58.
James, J., and H. A. Khan (1993) The Employment Effects of an
Income Redistribution in Developing Countries. World Development 21:5
817-827.
Kemal, A. R. (1994) Structural Adjustment, Employment, Income
Distribution and Poverty. The Pakistan Development Review 33:4 901-911.
Khan, A. Rehman (1993) Structural Adjustment and Income
Distribution: Issues and Experiences. GENEVA: ILO, United Nations.
King, B. B. (1985) What is SAM? In Pyatt and Round (eds) Social
Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Lucas, R. (1988) On the Mechanics of Economic Development: W.A.
Mackintosh Lecture. Journal of Monetary Economics 22:1 3-42.
Mankiw, G. N., D. Romer, and D. N. Weil (1992) A Contribution to
the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:
407-437.
McGillivary, Mark, Howard White, and Afzal Ahmad (1995) Evaluating
the Effectiveness of Structural Adjustment Policies on Macroeconomic: A
Review of the Evidence with Special Reference to Pakistan. Pakistan
Journal of Applied Economics 11:1 57-75.
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (1985) A Social
Accounting Matrix of Pakistan, 1979-80. Volumes I and II. Preliminary
report prepared in the framework of collaborative research between PIDE
and Erasmus University Rotterdam, the Netherlands.
Pakistan, Government of (1993) Input-Output Table for 1984-85.
Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division.
Pakistan, Government of (1993a) Institutional Sector Accounts for
1984-85. Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division.
Pakistan, Government of (1993b) Social Accounting Matrix for
1984-85. Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division.
Pakistan, Government of (1996) Supply and Use Tables of Pakistan
1989-90. Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Finance Division, Economic Advisor's Wing.
Psacharopoulos, G. (1973) Returns to Education. San Francisco:
Jossey-Bass.
Pyatt, G. (1985) Commodity Balances and National Accounts: A SAM
Perspective. Review of Income and Wealth Series 31:1 155-169.
Pyatt, G. (1988) A SAM Approach to Modelling. Journal of Policy
Modelling 10:3 327-352.
Pyatt, G. (1991) SAMs, The SNA and National Accounting
Capabilities. Review of Income and Wealth Series 37:2 179-199.
Pyatt, G. (1991a) Fundamentals of Social Accounting. Economic
Systems Research 3:3 315-341.
Pyatt, G., and J. I. Round (1977) Social Accounting Matrices for
Development Planning. Review of Income and Wealth 23:4 339-364.
Pyatt, G., and J. I. Round (1979) Accounting and Fixed-Price
Multipliers in a Social Accounting Matrix Framework. Economic Journal
89: 850-873.
Pyatt, G., and J. I. Round (1985) Social Accounting Matrices: A
Basis for Planning. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Rizvi, S. R. H. (1996) Integrated Economic Accounts for 1989-90.
Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division, Government of
Pakistan.
Robinson, S. (1988) Multisectoral Models. In H. B. Chenery and T.
N. Srinivasan (eds) Handbook of Development Economics, Volume II.
Amsterdam: North-Holland. 885-947.
Romer, P. M. (1990) Human Capital and Growth. Paper Presented at
the Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Economic Policy, Rochester, New
York.
Saleem, M., T. Mahmood, N. Parveen, and M. A. Qasim (1985) P.I.D.E.
Input-Output Table of Pakistan's Economy: 1975-76. Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. (Research Report Series
No. 144.)
Siddiqui, R., and Z. Iqbal (1999) Social Accounting Matrix of
Pakistan for 1989-90. PIDE, Islamabad. (Research Report Series No 171.)
Siddiqui, R., and Z. Iqbal (1999a) Tariff Reduction and Functional
Income Distribution in Pakistan: A CGE Model, presented in MIMAP meeting
in Pakistan. (8 Nov.)
Taylor, L. (1990) Socially Relevant Policy Analysis, Structuralist
CGE Models for the Developing World. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Thorbecke, E. (1985) The Social Accounting Matrix and
Consistency-Type Planning Models. In Pyatt and Round (eds) Social
Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
White, Howard (1995) Is the World Bank Right About African
Adjustment? Prepared for Economic Research Seminar, Institute of Social
Studies, Den Haag, March.
World Bank (1988) Pakistan Growth Through Adjustment. (Report No.
7118-PAK.) World Bank (1989) Pakistan Medium-Term Economic Policy
Adjustment. (Report No. 7591-PAK.)
World Bank (1993) Pakistan: Economic Memorandum FY93, Progress
under the Adjustment Programme. (Report No. 11590-PAK.)
(1) The results of these studies nevertheless require careful
interpretation as they employ restrictive methodology to assess the
impact of structural adjustment reforms on income distribution. Use of
elaborate procedure has also been favoured by White (1995) and
McGillivary et al. (1994) who argued that performing counter factual
analysis using econometric or general equilibrium models is the most
legitimate approach to examining the relationship between poverty and
economic reforms.
(2) For more detail on structural adjustment reforms in Pakistan,
see World Bank (1988, 1989, 1993).
(3) The Gini-coefficient is a concentration measure which can be
derived from the Lorenz Curve derived by plotting the percentage of
total income received by various population groups. The Gini-coefficient
gives the area between the Lorenz Curve and the diagonal line of
absolute equality as a proportion of the total area under the diagonal
line.
(4) It is worthwhile mentioning that the values of Gini-coefficient
in rural and urban areas reported in Table 2 have changed rank in
1990-91 and 1992-93. Such fluctuations in the Gini-coefficient may have
been due to changing sampling bias, but this phenomenon needs further
scrutiny.
(5) For further details on Social Accounting Matrix of Pakistan for
1989-90, see Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999).
(6) For example, Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999); Cohen (1997, 1993);
Iqbal (1996); James and Khan (1993); Pyatt (1991, 1991a, 1988, 1985);
Pyatt and Round (1985, 1979, 1977); King (1985) and Thorbecke (1985) all
provide excellent introduction to SAMs and their uses.
(7) Institutional Sector Accounts for 1984-85 and IEA for 1989-90
have almost similar characteristics.
(8) For IEA, see Rizvi (1996) and for 1-O table see Pakistan 0996).
(9) Since the compilation of a SAM is quite flexible, it has been
condensed according to the need of the study and specific policy
objectives.
(10) For more detail on the limitations of SAM framework, see Cohen
(1993, 1997).
(11) the results should be interpreted with caution because of the
assumption of no supply constraints in the system.
(12) Iqbal and Zahid (1998); Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995); Barro
and Lee (1994); Mankiw et al. (1992); Barro (1991, 1989); Romer (1990);
Becker et al (1990); Lucas (1988) and Psacharopoulos (1973) argued that
promoting human capital is instrumental in enhancing economic growth.
Zafar Iqbal is currently working as Economist at the office of the
Senior Resident Representative, International Monetary Fund, Islamabad,
Pakistan. This paper was completed when he was Senior Research Economist
at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Rizwana
Siddiqui is Research Economist at the Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Key Indicators of Fiscal Policy in Pakistan (% of GDP)
Government Expenditure
Tax
Year Revenue Total Subsidies Health
1987-88 13.8 26.7 1.5 1.0
1988-89 14.3 26.1 1.7 1.0
1989-90 14.0 25.7 1.5 1.0
1990-91 12.7 25.6 1.1 0.9
1991-92 13.6 0.3 0.9 0.7
1992-93 13.3 26.0 0.7 0.7
1993-94 13.2 23.2 0.6 0.7
1994-95 13.7 22.8 0.4 0.6
1995-96 14.1 23.9 0.6 0.8
1996-97 13.5 22.3 0.5 0.8
1997-98 12.9 21.1 0.5 0.7
1998-99 13.8 18.4 -- 0.7
Government
Expenditure
Budget
Year Education Others Deficit
1987-88 2.4 21.8 8.5
1988-89 2.4 21.0 7.4
1989-90 2.2 21.0 6.5
1990-91 2.1 21.5 8.7
1991-92 2.2 22.7 7.4
1992-93 2.2 22.4 8.0
1993-94 2.2 19.7 5.9
1994-95 2.4 19.4 5.6
1995-96 2.4 20.1 6.3
1996-97 2.6 18.4 6.2
1997-98 2.3 17.6 5.4
1998-99 2.2 -- 4.7
Source: Pakistan (Various Issues).
Table 2
Trends of Gini-coefficients and Growth Rates of GDP
Gini-coefficients
Growth rate
Years Pakistan Rural Urban of GDP (%)
1987-88 0.35 0.31 0.37 6.44
1990-91 0.41 0.41 0.39 5.57
1992-93 0.41 0.37 0.42 2.27
1993-94 0.40 0.35 0.40 4.54
1998-99 * 0.41 0.37 0.41 3.11
Source: Pakistan (Various Issues).
* See Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999a).
Table 3
Sources of Households Income by Income Groups, 1989-90
(Percentage Shares)
Urban Households
Sources
of Income/Income Groups Lowest Low Middle High
Wages and Salaries 54.24 46.73 38.80 28.49
Operating, Surplus 42.21 44.69 46.65 40.11
Dividends from Firms 1.14 4.27 5.81 11.58
Transfers from Govt. 1.14 0.56 1.00 2.14
Transfers from ROW 1.28 3.74 7.74 17.68
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Rural Households
Sources
of Income/Income Groups Lowest Low Middle High
Wages and Salaries 37.35 21.30 15.50 7.58
Operating, Surplus 56.59 68.30 72.03 61.45
Dividends from Firms 2.61 5.16 7.41 17.11
Transfers from Govt. 0.75 0.50 0.31 4.28
Transfers from ROW 2.70 4.73 4.75 9.59
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Table 4
Uses of Households Income by Income Groups, 1989-90
(Percentage Shares)
Urban Households
Sources of Income/
Income Groups Lowest Low Middle High
Agriculture Product 43.19 34.90 28.20 15.73
Manufacturing Product 55.97 45.77 38.41 22.67
Education 0.68 0.93 0.96 1.33
Health 0.93 0.76 0.72 0.32
Others 29.79 27.23 25.03 23.88
Taxes Paid 0.21 0.41 0.72 0.63
Savings -30.77 -10.02 5.96 35.43
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Rural Households
Sources of Income/
Income Groups Lowest Low Middle High
Agriculture Product 45.94 34.14 26.21 12.78
Manufacturing Product 57.29 42.18 33.43 16.62
Education 0.39 0.44 0.40 0.25
Health 0.96 0.71 0.65 0.33
Others 23.73 19.51 17.41 11.03
Taxes Paid 0.24 0.15 0.24 1.30
Savings -28.57 2.87 21.65 57.68
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Table 5
Simulation Results by Changes in Fiscal Policy Variables
(Percentage Changes in Incomes)
50% Reduction 50% Reduction 50% Reduction
in Consumption in Production in Overall
Endogenous Accounts Subsidies Subsidies Subsidies
(1) (2) (3)
Labour (Wages) -0.66 -0.88 -1.54
Capital (Op. Surp.) -0.72 -0.92 -1.64
HU1 (Urban) -1.23 -0.87 -2.11
HU2 (Urban) -0.93 -0.85 -1.78
HU3 (Urban) -1.12 -0.81 -1.92
HU4 (Urban) -1.60 -0.69 -2.29
HR1 (Rural) -1.04 -0.86 -1.91
HR2 (Rural) -0.90 -0.85 -1.75
HR3 (Rural) -0.81 -0.84 -1.65
HR4 (Rural) -2.71 -0.73 -3.45
Firms -0.47 -0.60 -1.07
Pro. Agriculture -0.94 -0.88 -1.82
Pro. Industry -0.62 -1.03 -1.64
Pro. Education -0.32 -0.21 -0.53
Pro. Health -0.60 -0.43 -1.03
Pro. Other Sector -0.60 -0.92 -1.52
Dem. Agriculture -0.95 -0.89 -1.84
Dem. Industry -0.73 -0.80 -1.54
Dem. Education -0.32 -0.20 -0.52
Dem. Health -0.60 -0.43 -1.03
Dem. Other Sector -0.62 -0.67 -1.29
5% Reduction 10% Reduction
in Government in Government Total Effect
Overall Exp. on of All Three
Current Education and Policies
Endogenous Accounts Expenditure Health (3+4+5)
(4) (5) (6)
Labour (Wages) -1.87 -0.89 -4.18
Capital (Op. Surp.) -1.70 -0.43 -3.67
HU1 (Urban) -1.82 -0.67 -4.46
HU2 (Urban) -1.79 -0.62 -4.06
HU3 (Urban) -1.74 -0.56 -4.10
HU4 (Urban) -1.65 -0.46 -4.27
HR1 (Rural) -1.78 -0.58 -4.14
HR2 (Rural) -1.73 -0.50 -3.87
HR3 (Rural) -1.74 -0.47 -3.76
HR4 (Rural) -1.89 -0.38 -5.53
Firms -2.84 -0.28 -4.13
Pro. Agriculture -1.57 -0.47 -3.74
Pro. Industry -1.23 -0.32 -3.10
Pro. Education -4.16 -7.57 -11.85
Pro. Health -3.30 -5.06 -9.08
Pro. Other Sector -1.94 -0.30 -3.67
Dem. Agriculture -1.59 -0.47 -3.79
Dem. Industry -1.42 -0.38 -3.24
Dem. Education -4.16 -7.57 -11.85
Dem. Health -3.31 -5.06 -9.09
Dem. Other Sector -2.00 -0.31 -3.52
Table 6
Comparison of Gini-coefficients With and Without Policy Shocks
Urban Rural
Gini Actual 0.3878 0.3874
Gini 1 (Simulation 1) 0.3871 0.3853
Gini 2 (Simulation 2) 0.3881 0.3876
Gini 3 (Simulation 3) 0.3874 0.3855
Gini 4 (Simulation 4) 0.3881 0.3872
Gini 5 (Simulation 5) 0.3882 0.3877
Gini 6 (All Simulations) 0.3882 0.3858