Privatisation of electric power sector in Pakistan: some important issues.
Ghafoor, Abdul ; Weiss, John
The electric power sector in Pakistan is growing faster (11
percent) than the average growth rate of other developing countries (10
percent). However, the demand in Pakistan is growing even faster than
the supply and therefore power shortage has become a serious problem.
The problem is compounded by inefficiency of electric power sector.
Moreover there is underpricing, subsidising, overstaffing and inadequate
maintenance. Like many other developing countries, Pakistan has also
opted for "privatisation" in the form of transfer of ownership
as the first best solution. However. a wide range of literature argues
that such type of privatisation in the case of electric power may not
lead to miracles.
The present article attempts to analyse the past inefficiency of
the electric power sector in Pakistan and performs a diagnostic analysis
to identify sources and causes of inefficiencies. This analysis does not
necessarily support a strict privatisation based reform. The article
further discusses the salient feature of privatisation of electric power
sector in Pakistan and some important issues related to its feasibility.
It is noted that the privatisation of electric power sector in Pakistan,
as pursued now, may not resolve the problems of this sector. It may ease
short-run financial constraints but it may also create a number of
long-term problems such as inappropriate planning, greater energy
dependence and insecurity. It is also noted that current problems stem
primarily from institutional and organisational constraints faced by
public sector power enterprises. The key issue may not be a choice
between public or private ownership but to determine an appropriate
reform package based on either public/private or a mixed ownership
structure, that encourages greater private involvement and functions
well in the specific environment of Pakistan.
1. INTRODUCTION
Like many other developing countries, Pakistan announced a policy
shift towards the private sector in early 1980s which Was later enhanced
by the structural adjustment programme under the supervision of the IMF and the World Bank. Consequently, private sector investment increased
from 26 percent to 51 percent of total investment during 1978-88.
However, most of the privatised companies were in manufacturing
industry. Privatisation in the banking, electricity, telecommunications
and transport sectors was delayed because of lack of procedural clarity,
fear of unemployment among workers and the consequential emergence of
private monopolies resulting in increase in prices.
Recently, Pakistan has expanded the scope of its privatisation
programme to include infrastructure also with electric power sector at
the top of the agenda. The policy objective is to improve efficiency by
establishing a healthy and competitive infrastructure sector.
Privatisation of electric power sector expected to spur economic growth
and reduce fiscal deficits. But there are contrary opinions.
It has been argued in a number of studies that privatisation of
electric power may not lead to miracles. Even though it may ease short
run financial constraints, but it may also create a number of long-term
problems such as inappropriate planning and greater energy dependence
and insecurity. Even short-run financial benefits may be costly if the
sector is not properly regulated and supervised. Therefore, the key
issue may not be a choice between public and private ownership, but to
determine an appropriate and suitable reform (either public or private
or a mixed public-private structure) which could work better in the
specific environment of Pakistan. This article argues that the
privatisation of electric power in Pakistan, as pursued now, may not
resolve the problems of this sector. It presents a diagnostic analysis
of the sector and discusses some issues related to privatisation-based
reform and competition and efficiency.
2. SALIENT FEATURES OF ELECTRIC POWER SECTOR IN PAKISTAN
The power sector of Pakistan can be characterised as follows:
Structure
Pakistan's two power utilities are the Water and Power
Development Authority (WAPDA) and the Karachi Electricity Supply
Corporation (KESC). The former has a national coverage, whilst the
latter serves only the Karachi division and adjacent areas. WAPDA's
power plants are a mix of hydel and thermal units, whilst KESC's
are mostly thermal. A limited amount of electricity is also generated at
the Karachi nuclear power plant. Both WAPDA and KESC are vertically
integrated in the generation, transmission and distribution of power and
although they are not subject to rate of return regulation, price
increases must be approved by the government.
Growth
Growth in power generation has been very substantial with an
increase in aggregate supplies of approximately 12 percent annually from
1960 to 1995. Over the same period per capita power availability
increased from 28 KWh to 444 KWh. (1) However, the demand is growing at
a higher rate and power shortage has become a serious problem which has
forced the rationing of power supply. Therefore, load-shedding by the
two companies has been seen as a major problem over this period and
several studies have suggested that power bottlenecks have imposed
serious costs on the economy. For example, Pasha and Gellerson (1988)
and Ali (1990) calculated the loss in industrial output from factory
closures due to power cuts. The former suggested that it might be 9
percent of annual industrial output. The latter puts the annual cost in
lost GDP at 1 billion dollars. Using the production function approach,
USAID (1988) estimated the cost of load-shedding at nearly 2 percent of
GDP and a fall in manufactured exports of 4 percent.
Technical Performance
System losses in the power sector of Pakistan at 24 percent in
1990, were relatively higher than in the UK and the USA [World Bank
(1994)]. Ghafoor (1998) argues that higher system losses may be due to
unreliable and old-age generation plants, low-voltage transmission and
distribution lines and inappropriate location of grid stations, as well
as some non-technical factors such as inaccurate metering and billing,
default payments, un-metered supplies, and theft from illegal
connections. However, the average generation capacity factors (2) for
the sector are as good as for other developing countries [Ghafoor
(1998)]. Therefore, shortage of electricity cannot be attributed solely
to inefficient use of available installed capacity.
Financial Performance
Although both WAPDA and KESC have shown a substantial annual
average net profit on sales after interest (13 percent and 9 percent
respectively averaged over 1960-95), this has been found to flow from
financing their development programmes through grants, low interest
loans and subsidies on foreign loans, so that the full cost incurred to
supply electricity was not reflected in their financial costs. When a
proxy of 10 percent capital charge element is included in total cost,
the average net profit on sales becomes -55 percent for WAPDA and -46
percent for KESC during 1960-95 [Ghafoor (1998)]. This clearly indicates
that power tariff without capital cost gives a misleading signal for
pricing. Therefore, price was set at a level lower than long-run
marginal cost. Comparative tariff data suggests that in dollar terms
tariff in Pakistan, at least in the 1980s, were well below those in
comparable economies in the Asian region [Malhotra et al. (1994);
Ghafoor and Weiss (1998)].
Economic Performance
Ghafoor (1998) noted that not only average labour productivity (3)
in the case of WAPDA and KESC was very low, it decreased over time in
the case of KESC. Although, the growth in total factor productivity
(TFP) was positive in the case of WAPDA, it was negative in the case of
KESC, which gave a very low TFP growth (0.41 percent for 1960-95) for
the overall power sector compared to that found in other similar
studies. (4)
Economies of Scale
The empirical work by Ghafoor (1998) also indicates that there are
economies of scale in the case of electric power sector. A
generation-level analysis of cost per KW of installed capacity and size
of plant indicates that steam and hydel power plants have increasing
return to scale, whilst gas turbine and combine cycle power plants do
not exhibit any economies of scale. Since the share of hydel and steam
thermal power is higher in total electricity for WAPDA, it has a higher
level of economies of scale, which helped it to lower its unit cost of
production.
Capital Requirement
The under-pricing coupled with substantial system losses, produced
a net profit which was never large enough to finance a substantial part
of future investment, and consequently electric power remained in short
supply.
3. DIAGNOSTIC ANALYSIS
Since electric power is supplied through a unique networked
delivery system, investments in the delivery system are mostly
irrecoverable and are sunk costs. Then, there are economies of scale.
With these characteristics the power sector is usually considered to be
a natural monopoly. Although, recent technological and market
developments have made the unbundling of power sector possible (i.e.,
the breaking up of the generation, transmission and distribution
activities), there is a broad agreement that the transmission function
in most circumstances is a natural monopoly [Tenenbaum et al. (1992);
World Bank (1994); Ghafoor and Weiss (1997)].
Since electricity is recognised as a prerequisite for many economic
and social activities, the development of the electric power sector has
enjoyed a prominent place in national development. Because of its
special characteristics like capital intensiveness, technological
complexity, long project life, long gestation period and comparatively
small and a spatially dispersed electricity market, it was unlikely to
attract private investors in its initial stages. Therefore, public
ownership alone could ensure the desired level of production and
distribution needed to accelerate and strengthen agricultural and
industrial development and its potential benefits to flow towards
general economic and social development. Geographical difficulties in
some areas also scared away private investors. Lack of infrastructure
facilities was another discouraging factor. The development of
undeveloped areas was (and still is) a concern for policy-makers as well
as public concern for equity and income distribution in which cheap and
continuous supply of electricity for all citizens figure prominently.
The vertically integrated and publicly owned utilities are therefore
seen as ideally suited to deal with these social goals. Therefore, like
many other developing countries, a monopolistic, vertically integrated,
public electric power sector was developed in Pakistan, which was
favoured by the donor agencies (the World Bank and the IMF) because of
its relatively large absorptive capacity and government guarantees for
credit [Barnett (1992)].
Does this market structure of public ownership contribute to poor
performance? Some think yes. They argue that with public ownership,
property rights are diffused between large number of shareholders and no
individual has an incentive to incur the substantial information costs needed to monitor and control management. Therefore, Tenenbaum et al.
(1992) argue that "when the state owns, nobody owns; and when
nobody owns, nobody cares".
The alternative view is that ownership per se is much less critical
than institutional and organisational constraints faced by an
enterprise.- By organisational constraints, we refer to the managerial
and operational constraints internal to an organisation (in our case,
electric power utilities) for a given market structure. Similarly,
institutional constraints include government and regulatory bodies.
Table 1 represents the factors affecting the performance of electric
power sector.
Table 1 indicates that the poor technical performance of electric
power sector in Pakistan may be due to organisational constraints. For
instance, higher system losses may be due to inappropriate location of
generation plants and the national grid station, voltage of transmission
lines and age of plants. However, there are some non-technical problems
such as undeveloped anti-theft laws, poor metering system, inefficient
measures of security and inadequate maintenance. At the same time poor
financial performance may also be due to price setting and very low
adjustment o1' electricity tariffs to reflect higher costs. Poor
managerial performance may be due to lack of autonomy in investment and
capacity expansion decisions. Furthermore, despite repeated efforts,
both WAPDA and KESC have failed to recover defaulted payments from their
respective defaulters. All of the above mentioned factors can be linked
to institutional constraints. Thus, institutional constraints coupled
with organisational constraints are responsible for poor financial
performance, which in turn is responsible for inadequate capacity
expansion. It can be concluded that public ownership may lead to
political interference and centralisation, excessive size may lead to
the problem of inflexibility and limited skills, poor capabilities of
regulators and management may lead to lack of professionalism, and
unclear objectives may lead to proliferation of bureaucratic regulations
and controls on managerial freedoms. Moreover, as the power sector is
not capable of financing its future investment, capacity expansion
depends on government resources, which are shrinking overtime, so new
sources of financing need to be found. This analysis does not
necessarily support a strictly privatisation-based reform.
4. SALIENT FEATURE OF PRIVATISATION POLICY OF ELECTRIC POWER IN
PAKISTAN
Pakistan has adopted a partial privatisation policy in the case of
electric power, where generation and distribution have been opened to
the private sector while transmission remains under state control.
Moreover, hydroelectric power plants in the case of WAPDA would also
remain in the public domain while thermal power plants and the
distribution sector would be divided into eight districts to be
privatised. As for, KESC is concerned, its structure would not be
divided into districts but parts of its stock (26 percent of total)
would be sold to the private sector. The transmission sector of the KESC
would be connected to the national grid of WAPDA to separate it from
generation and distribution sectors.
The privatisation of the electric power sector was started by
announcing an incentive packages for private power generators in 1994.
The main points of this package are as follows:
* Decision on construction sites and technology are at the private
sector's discretion.
* Government will provide guarantees for selling prices and for
electric power sale contracts between private power plants and WAPDA and
KESC.
* Government will provide guarantees for fuel procurement from
state-owned enterprises, for foreign exchange risk and for overseas
remittance risks.
* Private projects will mainly be financed through the World Bank.
Conditions of loans are a 14 percent interest rate, with a repayment
period of 23 years, including an average grace period of 8 years.
* There is an initial exemption from corporate tax and the removal
of indirect taxes on machinery and equipment.
* Investment procedures are to be simplified.
These measures have been taken to introduce and Independent Power
Producer (IPP) system so that private entities can construct and operate
power generation plants and then sell produced electricity to the state
transmission sector.
Since 1994, 19 private power plants have been under construction
and 16 of them were expected to start operations in 1997-98 (Table 2).
As mentioned earlier, the electric power sector will be divided
into generation, transmission and distribution sectors. The electric
power demand and supply through the public and private power plants will
be co-ordinated by the National Electric Power Regulatory Authority (NEPRA). The NEPRA will also be responsible for the establishment of
electric tariffs and the co-ordination of future investment programmes.
However, WAPDA will manage the hydro power generation and rural
electrification.
As yet Pakistan has achieved privatisation only in the case of the
Kot Addu Thermal Power Plant through sale of 36 percent of total stock
to the private sector along with the management rights. The remaining 64
percent is scheduled to be sold gradually. With management rights,
private companies will have all powers from electric power generation to
price setting. Labour shedding is, however, based on the employment
agreement between All Pakistan State Enterprises Workers Action
Committee (APSEWAC) anti the government [OECF (1997)].
5. ANALYSIS OF CURRENT PRIVATISATION POLICY
It is clear from the above discussion that the power sector has
certain characteristics including existence of a natural monopoly,
economies of scale, capital intensiveness, long project life, and the
need for long term security for the producers. Thus, a model for reform
should take these characteristics into account. According to Tenenbaum
et al. (1992) and Bhattacharyya (1995), the following are the possible
models of power sector reform.
* Transfer of ownership without disintegration (where
disintegration means splitting the power sector into generation,
transmission and distribution sectors).
* Partial disintegration (separating generation sectors from
transmission anti distribution with competition by contracting at the
generation level).
* Complete disintegration with competition between producers and
distributors.
* No disintegration, but contracting the whole operation and
management to private sector.
Like many other developing countries, Pakistan at present is
following the partial disintegration policy (the second model above). As
a result, privatisation of the electric power sector has been limited to
the generation level only. The question is whether this type of
privatisation is capable of creating the competition required for
efficient resource allocation, of generating the capital needed for new
investment, of providing access to modern technology, of improving
managerial efficiency and of avoiding undue political interference.
Competition Arguments
Although, a number of private power projects are under
construction, only one plant has started operation during 1997 (Hub
River thermal plant) which contributes a total of 969MW, about 1 percent
of total capacity. Even if all the proposed private power projects start
operation successfully by 2000, the total private sector contribution
will not increase to more than 10 percent. Under this situation
privatisation does not guarantee a competition for several reasons.
First introduction of one or two new generators does not spontaneously
lead to competition. The market power of two new generators obviously
remains substantial, and their capacity to collude, rather than compete,
is considerable and is probably the most likely outcome. Second, all
private power generation plants are either gas turbine or combined
cycle, which are based on fossil fuels. These plants cannot compete with
the large public sector's hydro and steam power plants which are
not only economical due to economies of scale but also environmental
friendly.
Moreover, the government has to induce private investors by
offering considerable concessions including tax holidays and
repatriation of earning in foreign currencies. Therefore, theoretically
speaking competitive bidding for a particular BOOT project may be
possible but in reality it is unclear whether this will be the case. In
the absence of such competition, there is always a possibility of rent
seeking behaviour from contracting firms by equating higher prices with
capital invested. A similar situation has developed in Pakistan. Private
power producers have taken the advantage of Pakistan's
privatisation policy and have agreed to supply electricity at a price
which is higher than the long-run marginal cost. An effort is now there
to correct this situation by resetting the price according to long-run
marginal cost by rescheduling all these contracts.
Privatisation and Politics
The question of political interference with public enterprises
cannot be eliminated particularly in the case of infrastructure.
Political interference affects pricing and investment decisions. For
instance, it was argued during the earlier period of establishment (and
still is) that since both rural and urban poor have very few
infrastructure facilities compared to the rich, the utility tariff
should be subsidised to lower the financial burden of the poor. (6) Like
many other developing countries, subsidising charges coupled with rapid
growing demand increased future investment at a level which was out of
the reach of Pakistan. Bhattacharyya (1995) asserts that in general,
developing countries required a capital investment of about $110 billion
per year including about $40 billion in foreign exchange to cope with
their future demand for electricity. Since these requirements are
commonly met from foreign borrowing, the result is a serious debt
crisis. Moreover, the private electric power sector has to be regulated
through a regulatory body which would be under political influence
directly. Although, privatisation may decrease political intervention in
managerial decision making to some extent, it will not lead to
improvements without regulatory or institutional reforms. It is often
argued that the main reason for government intervention in public
enterprises is financial. If the power sector can become financially
independent, intervention can be reduced, without resorting to private
ownership.
Privatisation and Labour Policy
Issues like labour policy and employment are closely related to
privatisation. It is argued that privatisation will lead to shedding of
the labour force to raise productivity of the sector. Such action
however requires identification of areas where labour is either abundant
or in shortage. By analysing the situation, it may be easy to plan for
better utilisation of labour force (e.g., shifting labour from one area
to another). For instance, technological advancements at generation
level demand labour shedding, the extensions of transmission and
distribution systems may require more labour. What is needed is a
restructuring of the whole system.
Privatisation and Development Policies
The risk with privatisation is that as the private sector prefers
quick returns, private investors may set up plants of short gestation
period (like gas turbine and combined cycle plants). This behaviour may
lead to a lack of diversity and adversely affect long-term planning.
Further, these plants have a higher capital cost per unit of output and
since they use fossil fuel, their establishment may lead to more
dependence on imported fuels.
Privatisation and Environment
There is a need to look at the environmental costs and benefits of
privatisation in the case of electricity. In the past, the public
electric power plants were one of the major sources of environmental
pollution because of old technology (coal based plants) and limited
environmental controls. It is argued that with privatisation new
technologies are expected to be utilised which will lead to less
pollution. However, better utilisation of plants and extensive use of
fossil fuel may increase the total emission of S[O.sub.2] and N[O.sub.4]
which will not only deteriorate the air quality but also contribute to
global warming. Moreover, it may be difficult to regulate private
companies on informational grounds. Thus a change of ownership is not
necessarily a safeguard.
6. ALTERNATIVE POLICY REFORMS
As argued earlier, the problems of electric power sector are linked
with institutional and organisational constraints which may not require
a change in ownership. However, there are four main steps involved in
the performance of a public enterprise;
* Explicitly defined goals and objectives.
* Identifying required changes in organisational culture.
* Identifying required changes in institutional culture.
* Implementing the changes.
Let us examine each step in more detail.
Enterprise's Goal and Objectives
Often government objectives for state owned enterprises (SOE) are
multiple, unclear and ambiguous. Where stated explicitly, they may be
inconsistent and can frequently be altered in response to political
circumstances. The purpose of this exercise is to identify as explicitly
as possible the goals and objectives that the enterprise should pursue.
Ideally, an enterprise should have a single set of compatible goals
and objectives. However, it is possible for an enterprise to pursue
multiple goals and objectives, if they are explicitly defined and clear.
For instance, public electricity enterprises can have both commercial
(such as self-financing, price equal to long-run marginal cost etc.) and
non-commercial (such as income distribution, development of remote area
etc.) objectives. However, they need to be clearly separated. A
subsidised rate should be targeted at those who needed it, not at all
consumers who can pay the actual price of utility. The targeted approach
may be possible in rural areas where poor people can easily be spotted.
In the case of urban area, it could be possible by designing a two part
tariff where minimum basic amount could be provided at a subsidised rate
but beyond that limit every one has to contribute to compensate for the
subsidy. In all cases, it should be clear in a financial statement how
much subsidies are being provided and how much are being compensated
through other means. Similarly, all projects revolved in developing a
remote area would also be dealt with separately. This process will
provide an opportunity to keep an eye on incoming and outgoing financial
resources which would help to develop future strategy more clearly.
Identifying Required Changes in Organisational Culture
Schein (1983) mentioned five elements that help in identifying
required changes in organisational culture. They include goals and
objectives, strategy to achieve them, means of accomplishing the
strategy, performance measures and correction mechanism. The first
element has already been discussed in the previous section. By strategy,
we mean how people plan their task. It will have to address questions
such as:
* Is there any division of labour, or function groups which are
responsible for a specific task?
* What means do they use to accomplish each task and what is the
organisational structure?
* How is performance measured?
* Is there any incentive system for good and any penalty for bad
performance?
* What institutional changes are required to improve enterprise
performance as a whole? * What correction measures should be taken if
the enterprise's performance goes wrong?
For example, in the case of the electric power sector in Pakistan,
generation, transmission and distribution functions need to be
separated. Every function should have its own independent management and
financial system: whether under public or private ownership, joint
ventures or under contractual arrangements with the private sector
whilst retaining public ownership, the transmission sector should buy
electricity from the generation sector. This process will lead to
transparent business relations between these sectors and management
(public or private) can clearly understand the flow of financial
resources from one sector to another. Moreover, it will also help in
identifying where in the system as a whole there is excess labour and
low productivity. However, the question of economies of scale needs to
be considered. As earlier, discussed, there are economies of scale at
generation level and under the disintegration of the power sector, the
benefit of economies of scale will be reaped at this level. Similarly,
there might be economies of scale at the transmission level in the
purchase of transmission, which will again remain after disintegration.
The distribution level is more complex however, and appropriate regions
have to be set up to take advantages of any scale effects. It may also
be useful to break the transmission monopoly by providing electricity
for larger users directly from generation companies.
Since institutional factors are a function of ideological belief
and external factors, like changes in international environment, they
are dynamic. Even if the change in an ownership is not required in the
short term, the government needs to be determined to improve the
efficiency. This requires greater managerial autonomy. For instance,
management should be allowed to adjust prices with inflation and
increased fuel charges and to decide about future investment and
technology.
Implementing Changes
Productive cultures are those where an enterprise's goals and
objectives are further supported by external as well as internal
motivation and control mechanisms. There are four elements in external
control mechanism: (i) market control, (ii) legislation, (iii)
subcontracting, performance contracting and asset leasing and (iv)
direction by ownership. Where strong market control is possible,
arguably ownership does not matter. Where market control is not
feasible, legislation, subcontracting in terms of performance contract
and asset leasing are alternatives. Legislation is an alternative for
indivisible natural monopolies such as transmission. It may be helpful
to regulate both charges for and availability of services. Divisible monopolies such as generation and distribution are amenable to private
participation through subcontracting, performance contracting or asset
leasing. For instance, in the case of electricity, the government can
use performance contracts, or asset leases rather than transfer of
ownership for individual generation plants. This will help to create a
healthy competitive environment and will also provide an opportunity for
more information on cost and benefits needed to develop a better
regulatory system. Similarly, in distribution, performance contracts
would be useful as a means of understanding the market mechanism at the
early stage of reform. Transfer of ownership can occur later when the
state is in a better position to regulate a utility.
7. CONCLUSIONS
Pakistan electric power sector is characterised by higher system
losses, low financial profitability and very low total factor
productivity growth. This below standard performance may be due to a
variety of reasons. Apart from technical problems, underpricing and
subsidising are found to be more critical. Although WAPDA was supposed
to set a price according to long run marginal cost, this objective could
not be achieved. Thus, subsidised electric power tariff were continued
on the ground of poverty alleviation and industrial development
arguments. Further, default payments also played a significant role in
the financial crises of electric power sector. These problems led to
search for alternative policy options such as privatisation.
Since Pakistan is following a partial divestiture policy in the
case of electric power, the question of competition, political
interference and other development policies will remain unanswered. It
is, therefore, likely that the present privatisation exercise may ease
short-term financial constraints but it will certainly not lead to any
miracles. Even short-run financial benefits would be at a substantial
cost if the sector is not properly regulated and supervised. For
instance, incentive package for independent power producer system under
the privatisation policy was so attractive that a large number of
private investors came forward and Pakistan is now facing the fear of a
power glut. This situation led to search for an international market to
export surplus electric power such as India. Moreover, since the IPPs
are using only gas turbines and combine cycle power plants, Pakistan may
lose the benefits of economies of scale. Therefore, such a privatisation
strategy may not generate competitive environment needed to have an
efficient electric power sector which can lead to a cheap and high
quality service. Since the importance of electric power sector in social
and economic development process of a country is well recognised, it is
necessary to improve the performance and the environmental culture of
the power sector. However, over-emphasis on privatisation has somewhat
over-shadowed other possible alternatives.
We have argued that current problems stem primarily from the
institutional and organisational constraints faced by public sector
power enterprises. Properly restructuring the sector, and using a
variety of mechanisms to encourage greater private involvement will be
necessary. The issue should not be the ownership, either public or
private, as implied by privatisation-based reform, but rather to find an
appropriate reform package based on either a public or private or mixed
ownership structure that will function well in the specific environment
of Pakistan.
REFERENCES
Ali, S. (1990) Energy: Plugging in Pakistan. Far Eastern Economic
Review 148:18.
Bagdadioglu, N., C. M. W. Price, and T. G. Weymanjones (1996)
Efficiency and Ownership in Electricity Distribution--A Non-parametric
Model of the Turkish Experience. Energy Economics 18:1&2 1-23.
Barnett, A. (1992) The Financing of Electric Power Projects in
Developing Countries. Energy Policy 20:4 326-334.
Bhattacharyya, S. C. (1995) Power Sector Privatisation in
Developing Countries: Will it Solve All Problems? Energy Sources 17:3
373-389.
Claggett, E. T., D. R. Hollas, and S. R. Stansell (1995) The
Effects Ownership from on Profit Maximisation and Cost Minimisation
Behaviour within Municipal and Cooperative Electrical Distribution
Utilities. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 35: 533-550.
Deboer, D. P., and L. Evans (1996) The Economic Efficiency of
Telecommunications in a Deregulated Market--The Case of New Zealand.
Economic Record 72:216 24-35.
Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, and J. Logan (1985) The Relative
Performance of Publicly Owned and Privately Owned Electric Utilities.
Journal of Public Economics 26: 1 89-106.
Ghafoor, A. (1998) Evaluating the Performance of Public
Infrastructure: The Case of Electric Power and Telecommunications in
Pakistan. Ph D Thesis, Development and Project Planning Centre,
Bradford. University of Bradford.
Ghafoor, A., and J. Weiss (1997) Taxonomic Advancement in the
Classification of Public and Private Goods and Services. Development and
Project Planning Centre, Bradford. (Discussion Paper Series 2, No. 2.)
Ghafoor, A., and J. Weiss (1998) Performance of Public Sector
Infrastructure Enterprises: Evidence from Pakistan. Development and
Project Planning Centre, Bradford. (Discussion Paper Series 2, No. 11.)
Humplick, F. (1993) Does Multiplicity Matter Than Ownership in the
Efficiency of Infrastructure Services? Paper prepared for Conference on:
Infrastructure, Economic Growth and Regional Development: The Case of
Industrialised High-Income Countries. Jonkoping, Sweden, June 10-12.
Koh, D. S., S. Y. Berg, and L. W. Kenny (1996) A Comparison on
Costs in Privately Owned and Publicly Owned Electric Utilities--The Role
of Scale. Land Economics 72:1 56-65.
Malhotra, A. K., O. Koenig, and P. Sinsukprasert (1994) A Survey of
Asia's Energy Prices. The World Bank, Washington, D. C. (Technical
Paper No. 248.)
Molyneux, R., and D. Thompson (1987) National Industry Performance:
Still Third-Rate. Fiscal Studies 8:1 48-82.
Newbery, D. M., and M. G. Pollitt (1997) The Restructuring and
Privatisation of Britain's CEGD--Wast it Worth It? Journal of
Industrial Economics 45:3 269-303.
OECF (1997) The Privatisation Policies in Pakistan: Current
Situation and Future Challenges. The Overseas Economic Co-operation
Fund, Japan. (Research Paper No. 19.)
Pasha, H., and M. Gellerson (1988) Study of Financial Aid and
Economic Impact of Power Interruption and Load-shedding. University of
Karachi, Karachi.
Pescatrice, D. R., and J. M. Trapani (1980) The Performance and
Objectives of Public and Private Utilities Operating in the US. Journal
of Public Economics 13: 259-275.
Pryke, R. (1981) The Nationalised Industries: Policies and
Performance since 1968. Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Schein, E. H. (1983) The Role of the Founder in Creating
Organisational Culture. Organisational Dynamics 12:1 21-36.
Tenenbaum, B., R. Lock, and J. Barker (1992) Electricity
Privatisation--Structural, Competitive and Regulatory Options. Energy
Policy 20:12 1134-1160.
USAID (1988) Power Shortage in Developing Countries; Magnitude,
Impacts, Solutions and the Role of Private Sector. USAID Report to
Congress.
World Bank (1994) World Development Report: Infrastructure for
Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
World Bank (1995) Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and
Policies of Government Ownership. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
(1) Data cited here come primarily the published reports of the
companies. For information sources. see Ghafoor (1998).
(2) Generation capacity factor is an indicator of capacity
utilisation for electric power industry. It is expressed as follows
[Humplick (1993)].
Generation Capacity Factor = Annual Gross Output (MWh)/Annual
Installed Capacity (MW) x 8760 x 100
Where, 8760 are total number of hours in a year of 365 days.
(3) The labour productivity was measured as a ratio of value added to the total number of persons employed.
(4) For the UK for example TFP growth was 8.7 percent during
1968-73 Pryke (1981), and 1.4 percent during 1978-85 [Molyneux and
Thompson (1987)].
(5) Recent literature on the issue of comparing performance in
private and public electric power sectors includes: Pescatrice and
Trapani (1980): Fare et al. (1985): Claggett et al. (1995): Koh et al.
(1996); Bagdadioglu et al. (1996); Deboer and Evans (1996); Newbery and
Pollin (1997).
(6) For example, in Bangladesh subsidies for the non-poor are six
time larger than for the poor and in Ecuador, a subsidy of $36 a year
goes to the 37 percent residential consumers with the lowest use, but
$500 a year goes to richer households with a higher use [World Bank
(1994)].
Abdul Ghafoor is Assistant Professor, Department of Economics,
Faculty of Business and Economics, Eastern Mediterranean University,
Turkish Republic of Northern Cyprus and John Weiss is Professor of
Development Economics, Development and Project Planning Centre,
University of Bradford, Bradford, UK.
Table 1
Identification of Factors Affecting the Performance of Electric
Power Sector
Explanatory Institutional Organisational
Indicators Factors Constraints Constraints
Financial * Pricing Policy * Price control * Lack of
Performance * Employment to achieve the autonomy
Policy equity and
welfare
objectives of
government
* Increased
employment to
alleviate
poverty
* Investment * Government * Lack of
Decision political resources
* Access to decisions for future
Finance * Hurdles from investment due
bureaucratic to price lower
process than long run
* Budgetary marginal cost
constraints * Depends on
* Government government
guarantees budget
* Foreign debts
* Managerial * Political
Decision interference
in day to day
operation
* Financial
condition of
organisation
Technical * Operating * Lack of
Performance * Performance resources
* System Losses * Poor design and
* Suboptimal inappropriate
Expansion location due
to lack of
technical
expertise
* Lack of
anti-theft law
* Inadequate
replacement of
old plants
* Other
non-commercial
factors
Source: Derived from Bhattacharyya (1995).
Table 2
On Going Private Power Projects in Pakistan
PPAs Scheduled
S. Plant Signing Operation
No. Power Plant Capacity Date Date
1 Huh Power Project Unit 4 323 24.11.1994 04.1997
2 AES Lalpir Ltd. 362 03.11.1994 11.1997
3 AES Pak Gen (Pvt) Ltd. 365 05.09.1995 12.1997
4 Kohnoor Energy Power Co. 131 08.11.1994 04.1997
Ltd.
5 Southern Electric Power Co. 117 17.11.1994 09.1997
Ltd.
6 Japan Power Generation Ltd. 120 21.03.1995 10.1997
7 Davis EnerLgen (Pvt) Ltd. 10 18.01.1995 07.1997
8 Power Generation System Ltd. 113 25.09.1995 07.1997
9 Habibullah Coastal Energy 140 25.03.1996 12.1997
Ltd.
10 Saba Power Company Ltd. 114 26.12.1994 02.1998
11 Rousch (Pakistan) Power Ltd. 412 25.02.1995 03.1998
12 Uch Power Project Ltd. 586 23.11.1995 11.1997
13 Fauji Kahirwala Power Co. 157 21.03.1996 11.1998
Ltd.
14 Altern Energy Ltd. 14 18.09.1995 07.1997
15 Liberty Power Project 235 26.11.1995 08.1997
16 Eeshtech Ltd. 20 19.03.1996 04.1998
17 Northern Electric Company 6 17.01.1995 11.1998
18 Consolidated Electric Power 1426 27.10.1995 09.1999
Asia Ltd.
19 KESC Gul Ahmed Energy Ltd. 136 04.1997
Sabah Shipyard Pakistan Ltd. 288 10.1997
Tapal Energy Ltd. 126 11.1997
Total 5204
Source: OECF (1997).