Impediments to social development in Pakistan.
Ismail, Zafar H.
The paper presents an analysis of some of the impediments that
exist in the development of the social sectors and in the delivery of
these services in Pakistan. It suggests that in essence these
impediments stem from malgovernance and can be attributed to a number of
causes, the most important of which have been included in the paper.
These causes lie within three broad areas: firstly, legislative
framework which sets the boundaries within which institutions, agencies
and agents can operate and therefore addresses issues related to
devolution, discretion and accountability; secondly, political
structures which determine the way in which we are governed; and lastly
the inter-twined trio of: institutional capacity which identifies the
ability of institutions, agencies and agents to make policies, ensure
coherence and coordination and ensure compliance; management which
addresses issues related to the proper use of systems and procedures and
the mechanisms used for the development of infrastructure and the
delivery of services by ensuring that there is an equitable and
transparent access to goods and services and protection of public
interest from private intrusion; and efficiency which addresses issues
of resource generation, expenditure planning, expenditure control,
regulation and overall public administration to ensure the most
effective use of resources. The paper suggests a number of remedial
actions which can remove these impediments, but most of these require
time and patience as institutional and societal reforms cannot be
accomplished overnight or in the short-run without revolution.
INTRODUCTION
The development of infrastructure and the provision of basic
services in Pakistan lie in the public domain. The quality of the built
infrastructure and the service offered reflect successive
governments' capability as a channel for public sector funds, their
role in overall financial and macro-economic planning and management,
and their administrative efficiency in implementation, operations and
management--in essence the extent to which they are able to adhere to the principles of good and humane governance. Good governance is
generally conceived of as the judicious exercise of economic, political
and administrative authority in the public and private spheres to manage
a country's affairs at all levels to improve the quality of life of
the people. It is a continuing process where divergent opinions and
desires are satisfied through compromise and tolerance in a spirit of
cooperative action for the mutual benefit of the larger whole. It has
three dimensions: one, the political regime; two, the systems and
procedures for exercising authority; and three, the capacity of
governments [World Bank (1994); UNDP (1997); OECD (1995); Commission on
Global Governance (1995)].
When Pakistan gained political freedom in August 1947, it inherited
an economic and social infrastructure unable to meet the demands of the
large influx of refugees from India. Five decades later, policies
emphasising public investment, subsidised credit and regulated private
sector development have generated strong economic growth, but failed to
implement successful social development. Over the last 50 years and more
Pakistan's economy, measured through its GDP, has grown by more
than 10 times, an average annual growth rate of 5.1 percent. Rapid
population growth, estimated to have averaged just under 3 percent
annually, has resulted in real per capita increases of only 2.1 percent
per year. Social development, measured through the Human Development
Index, has not been as impressive. Table 1 shows that this has increased
annually by about 1.7 percent, and by 1997 has only just more than
doubled over the last five decades.
To mitigate this imbalance, Pakistan in 1992 launched the Social
Action Programme (SAP) with the help of donor assistance. With rural
deprivation a major problem, it was decided that SAP should have a rural
focus. As well, SAP was to take an integrated approach to the four key
sectors--primary education, primary health, rural water supply and
population welfare. These were chosen both because they were the most
basic social services required by the population and because of the
obvious linkages and potential for synergy between them. In 1997-98 the
second phase of SAP was launched. With the large injection of funds into
the social sector was SAP able to achieve its objectives? All
stakeholders would agree that generally SAP's sole claim to
achievement is in enhancing the resources available to the social
sectors. It has had a mixed response in the realm of institutional
reform, which was to be its guiding principle. Reviews, appraisals and
evaluations (SPDC; WB; ADB; Auditor General; MSU) all suggest that the
programme is in jeopardy. The government itself agrees that economic and
social development has not been evenly distributed throughout the
country and the gap between the rich and poor has widened. The level of
social development remains extremely low, particularly in the rural
areas and especially among females. Unrelenting population growth has
impeded improvements in the quality of life for a large segment of the
population. This has, in turn, led to rising social tensions.
What has led to this dichotomy in development? This paper attempts
to identify the impediments to the development of the social sectors,
amplify on some of them, and in the final analysis suggest a series of
solutions most of which are not for the short-term.
UNDERLYING CAUSES FOR POOR DEVELOPMENT
Senior politicians and government officers are aware that the
machinery of government has contributed to the present state of affairs
and that the management of the resources available to Pakistan has not
been sufficiently strong to obtain the best value for money. Honest and
diligent officials are frustrated with systems and procedures which are
cost ineffective; the populace is faced with a political and
bureaucratic system which is unaccountable and is not responsive to
need; the entrepreneur is faced with a set of policies which contradict
each other, are counterproductive, are incoherent and designed to assist
in increasing corruption and are as constant as the changing winds; and
the poor are faced with a situation where their plight is not seen
sympathetically. The origins of these weaknesses can be traced to the
evolution of the government bureaucracy. Designed to serve the
coloniser's needs and the interest's of a ruling elite,
Pakistan's bureaucratic system has become increasingly corrupt and
incompetent over time. In addition, because it is trained and encouraged
to serve the interests of a ruling elite, rather than to respond to the
changing needs of the population, the provision of social services
remains seriously out of sync with the demand.
Reviews of social sector projects [Auditor General (1997); MSU
(1997); WB (1998); ADB (1996, 1997); SPDC (1997, 1998, 1999)], conclude
that problems stem from bad governance, are sector-wide and hinder the
cost-effective delivery of services. These fall within three broad
areas: firstly, legislative framework which sets the boundaries within
which institutions, agencies and agents can operate and therefore
addresses issues related to devolution, discretion and accountability;
secondly, political structures which determine the way in which we are
governed; and lastly the intertwined trio of: institutional capacity
which identifies the ability of institutions, agencies and agents to
make policies, ensure coherence and coordination and ensure compliance;
management which addresses issues related to the proper use of systems
and procedures and the mechanisms used for the development of
infrastructure and the delivery of services by ensuring that there is an
equitable and transparent access to goods and services and protection of
public interest from private intrusion; and efficiency which addresses
issues of resource generation, expenditure planning, expenditure
control, regulation and overall public administration to ensure the most
effective use of resources.
LEGISLATIVE FRAMEWORK
The allocation of responsibilities between various tiers of
government are enunciated in the Constitution and in a large body of
legislation. However, except for a few areas no clear-cut allocation of
responsibilities is specified where more than one tier of government is
involved [AERC (1990); Inbucon (1991); Ismail (1996, 1998)]. While the
principle of such an overlap are implicit, that is, the highest tier is
responsible for overall policy formulation and coordination of the
activity across lower tiers and the lower tiers are responsible for
actual implementation, this is nowhere clearly stated. Thus a number of
functions are improperly addressed or are not undertaken by default. In
addition, a number of functions are best performed at the lower tiers of
government, because of the need to interact with beneficiaries, but have
been legislatively assigned to higher tiers. This dichotomy needs to be
removed.
In theory and legislatively, the provincial governments are
responsible for the development of the social sector (i.e., capital
investment), and are supposed to hand over the responsibility for the
operation, maintenance and delivery of services to the local councils or
beneficiary communities. In fact, the provincial governments are loath to transfer these responsibilities because they are a lucrative source
of patronage and rents. The complex character of this fragmentation of
structures and responsibility has been highlighted in a number of
studies and can be seen from the matrix of some of the responsibilities
for the planning, development, management, operations, maintenance, and
delivery of civic and social services in the metropolitan area of
Karachi shown in Appendix 1. As can be seen, all three tiers of
government and civil society organisations are involved. This dichotomy
of responsibility results in inappropriate procedures, poor planning,
improper budgeting, financial mismanagement, and flawed personnel
policies. This can to a large extent be overcome by a clearer definition
of the several tiers of government so that dichotomy, fragmentation and
duplication of responsibilities are removed and authority is clearly
defined and demarcated.
The link between maximising benefits from investment in
infrastructure and the provision of services on the one hand and the
involvement of the beneficiaries in the process from start to finish has
been demonstrated around the globe. This is the principal and basic
tenet for the implementation of the Social Action Programme with a view
to achieving the best value for money. While this is an explicit
statement of the government, legislation and mechanisms to ensure that
such participation is built into the process has not yet been devised
adequately. To ensure that this objective is attained, the required
mechanism needs to be designed and tested before the legislation needed
to ensure this is drafted and enacted. One such mechanism could be the
employment of Non-Governmental Organisations in the process. The
involvement of NGOs in the development process and making communities
aware of their rights, responsibilities and obligations has been
developed to some extent, but is largely manifest as case studies or in
isolated pockets with the help of bilateral donor agencies. However,
this needs to be studied in depth to draw lessons for replicability
generally using a mix of public sector funds and private sector
entrepreneurship.
A small but rapidly growing segment of the population's view
of legislation in Pakistan is that all legislation is passed without
adequate drafting skills resulting in lacunae which may be used for
access to pecuniary benefits by vested interests. Moreover, there are
built-in provisions for the executive to sub-legislate (make rules and
regulations), powers to set aside any mandatory requirement, waive any
mandatory prohibitive provisions either "for the public good"
or "in the public interest" (both euphemisms for my personal
pocket) without reference to any elected controlling body of individuals
and/or the ability to report on actions ex-post. While these have been
included to mitigate extreme cases of hardship, in reality, however,
these have tended to be used indiscriminately for personal gain. In
addition, discretionary quotas for access to infrastructure, services
and economic opportunity provide rents to the chosen few at the cost of
the exchequer. These lead to distortions and inefficiency in public
institutions and are seen to be a major avenue for corruption.
Lax legislation linked to poor governance leads to, may encourages
and breeds, corruption in a number of ways, for instance through bribery
and extortion, influence peddling and nepotism, and fraud and
embezzlement. It reduces the efficiency on which an economy depends, and
by increasing the cost of investment lowers the potential return. It
also reduces the government's resources and hence its capacity for
investment.
As in the rest of South Asia corruption in Pakistan is unique
because it occurs up-stream, it has wings which encourage flight of
capital rather than wheels which encourage re-investment and it often
rewards rather than punishes as the legal processes to fight corruption
are weak in themselves and the lower judiciary is amenable to letting
off the accused if the 'price is right'. As elsewhere,
corruption has had adverse effects on human development which
contributes to people's inability to fight corruption through an
improvement in governance as a result of deprivation of knowledge,
literacy and rights, and has also skewed public sector investment
priorities which favour large visible projects where the chances for
rent-seeking are substantial.
At the heart of the problem lies the corruption equation, first
devised by Robert Klitgaard in 1988:
Corruption = f (Monopoly power, discretion, accountability, low
government salaries).
The combination of monopoly power and discretion alone is a
disastrous combination. When linked to the absence of accountability and
low legal earnings they become more than just lethal. Studies in
Pakistan [AERC (1990); Inbucon (1993); Ismail (1996, 1998); ADB (1996)]
have concluded that most, if not all, laws, rules and regulations exist
only to create an environment for corruption. Some have even suggested
that they actually encourage corruption both implicitly and explicitly
because of the built in inconsistencies and contradictions. They create
monopolies because power is centralised and they provide immense
discretion to set aside any law regulation and rule in the public
interest.
One obvious mechanism to eliminate corruption would be to review
legislation which helps breed corruption, such as through creating
monopoly power, permitting discretion without checks and balances,
exercising authority without responsibility. Parallel to this should be
an effort to reform the judicial system generally. Another mechanism
would be to introduce legislation which is effectively implemented
through an impartial and independent authority (with substantial
representation from civil society and the senior members of the
judiciary) with exemplary punishment. Corresponding changes in the laws
of evidence and trial should allow for flexibility in procedures and
rigour of evidence. The double standards prevalent in the developed
world, particularly the safe havens of Switzerland, Liechtenstein, the
Cayman Islands and the Bahamas, and now also the United States of
America and the United Kingdom impose stiff legal challenges to the
laundering of money generated from drugs, but a similar treatment to
bribes, extortion, embezzlement and fraud is conspicuous by its absence.
This needs to be rectified urgently.
The lack of transparency in the system is typified by the budgeting
and planning process itself. The budgeting and financial management
procedures are obscurantist. For instance, detailed budget breakdowns
are invariably not presented, expenditure decisions outside the budget
framework through executive orders are normal, the failure to disclose
or even to discuss military spending is the rule, the limited data on
revenue collection, and the absence of detailed information on new
amendments and ordinances. In the planning and development management
arena, there is no civil society representation in the selection of
projects, ex-ante executive approval outside the normal minimal approval
processes are becoming the order of the day, and variations from
approved or designed specifications are condoned by 'amenable'
officials. What is required is legislated free access to information,
even military spending, the inclusion of civil society in planning and
development management and independent monitoring, particularly by a
free and investigative media.
Pakistan requires disclosure of wealth by officials and elected
representatives. Follow-up action is missing. Legislation should be
enacted which provides for a mandatory cross-verification of
declarations for a minimum sample of returns. Delayed and no-returns
should be penalised severely. In the event that investigation reveals
concealment or mis-declaration, then an independent tribunal of the
senior most judges and civil society representatives drawn from
professional accountants (who should be elected for three year terms)
should order punishment after due process. Punishments should include,
confiscation of property, jail and severance from service without
benefits.
In summary, the action needed to eliminate corruption should
include the following elements nationally:
* Begin accountability from the top.
* Set up national anti-corruption commissions and appoint an
independent watchdog.
* Set up exclusive corruption courts.
* End unnecessary or archaic discretionary laws.
* Enact legislation to improve accountability, ensure transparency,
punish the corrupt severely and ensure time bound action.
* Require public officials to declare their assets.
* Provide immunity to informers.
* Pass a Right to Information Bill.
* Use independent private-sector auditors.
* Involve people in diagnosing corrupt systems.
* Implement core institutional reforms and repair corrupt systems.
* Ensure an active and free press.
It is also necessary that parallel action at the international
level should also be undertaken so that the double standards which exist
are removed. Such actions, should include:
* Making all bribes given in industrialised countries illegal.
* Ensuring that all 'illegal' money and property
transactions in industrialised countries is treated at par with drug
money.
* Linking aid to humane governance through a programme funding
mechanism "such as under IMF's ESAF/EFF, and the World
Bank's Structural Adjustment Loans or Programme Loans are
structured such that circumventing any conditionality becomes nearly
impossible. These provide initial bridge financing to start the process
of change and specify benchmarks which are quantifiable and verifiable
exogenously by third parties. They must be achieved before any
subsequent tranche is released. Disbursement is either withheld or
delayed pending compliance, thereby providing both the carrot and the
stick to encourage the implementation of change" [SPDC (1999)].
Indeed, all stakeholders in the social sectors acknowledge that
there are major deficiencies in the coverage and performance of the
basic social sector infrastructure and services in both urban and rural
areas resulting from the built-in weaknesses in the legislative
framework stemming from the Constitution of Pakistan itself and also
from the body of legislation. They further acknowledge that an enormous
and complex effort is required to remedy these deficiencies. This limits
the institutional changes feasible at the provincial and local levels in
the short- to medium-term. Further, the centralisation of authority and
the need to wield patronage has intentionally left communities out of
the decision-making process and the accompanying operations and
maintenance effort. In essence, the political structure also contributes
to the lack of social development in Pakistan.
POLITICAL STRUCTURES
Politics is about the creation and distribution of power and
governance is the mechanism which controls the relationship between the
two extremes--the governed and the governors. The political process lies
at the core of governance. This can be efficient only if elections are
free and fair; the elected are accountable; authority is divided between
the legislature, the bureaucracy and the judiciary; and, power is
decentralised.
Unfortunately, Pakistan does not meet all of these criteria. The
lethal combination of powerful personalities or families linked together
by familial and economic interests, on the one hand, and weak
institutions, on the other, has resulted in the subversion of law which
lacks accountability, creates processes which are largely personal and
informal and allow rulers to operate outside established institutional
frameworks. Democracy in Pakistan is confined largely to the ballot
(purchased or coerced) box--and that too for the legislatures only.
Political parties do not hold elections for office. Decision-making is
controlled by the powerful elite. Sovereignty is equated to powerful
governments, not free citizens. Democracy has not been translated into
visible benefits for the poor. Pakistan's people continue to
remain, perhaps, the least well endowed amongst Asians generally with
respect to literacy, health, incomes, and freedom. HDC (1999) postulates
that legitimate governments are, therefore, not necessarily good
governments and queries "Can people be truly free when they have no
control over their destinies?" The moral foundation of Governments
in Pakistan has been eroded through electoral fraud, money politics,
criminalisation of the political system and increasing corruption in
public life.
The same powerful families appear to be the leaders of any
government in power because each branch of a family is a member of
another political party and most families are related to each other
through marriage. They also constitute a fair portion of the senior
bureaucracy, the higher judiciary and the military as the youngest are
"encouraged" to seek a career, implicitly to protect their
elders from the ravages of law. Thus they control the economy, deny
access to social services to the disadvantaged segments of society, and
the benefits of growth have accrued to them disproportionately.
The elite power structure consists of landlords (who have a
disproportionate share of seats in the legislatures and policy-making
agencies in government and thereby frustrate reform), a handful of large
industrialists (who cumulatively control resources which are equal to or
greater than the national budget), bureaucrats (who have gained power as
a consequence of weak political structures) and the military (who have
overtly ruled for half or more of the time and covertly for considerably
longer). The last of the quartet justify their rule as a consequence of
a breakdown in civil rule and political governments failing to
legitimise themselves.
There is a growing realisation that decentralising, or ensuring
local level participation in development and service delivery is the
best method of ensuring equitable growth, human development and
pro-people governance. The desire for decentralisation is also fuelled
by ethnic diversity. There is demand for the institution of effective
local government systems, not the watered down versions which exist
today. In Pakistan local government elections have been held (other than
in Sindh), but have been replaced by nominated bodies ostensibly on the
plea that they are corrupt. A case of the pot calling the kettle black?
The power structures and power nexus formed in the higher tiers of
government are replicated at the lower levels. In Pakistan, which has
a federal structure, the local councillors are the younger brethren or
sons of the Members of Assemblies and the contractors are their kith and
kin. Thus the benefits to be derived from decentralisation are lost.
Thus decentralisation is only in form and not spirit.
Further, Pakistan portrays a confused form of federalism. It has
never accepted the basic principles of federalism--the exercise of
independent authority within their assigned (separated) areas. The
constitution itself enshrines this situation through the overlapping of
functions and authority contained in what is called the combined
legislative list without specifying the bifurcation between the federal
and provincial governments. The federal government has tended to usurp the authority of the lower tier and the predominance of Punjab, the
largest province, in both the elected and bureaucratic institutions is a
peculiar feature. There is also legislative authority to set aside
state/provincial governments under exceptional circumstances.
The lower tiers of government are dependent financially on the
higher tiers. In Pakistan the provinces account for 25 percent and 6
percent respectively of public expenditure and revenue. The dependence
of local governments, particularly in the small towns and rural areas is
even severer. The smallest local governments are totally dependent for
resources on the state/provincial governments. Moreover, both inter- and
intra-tier sharing of revenues is a source of acrimony. This disparity
in resource generation results from the allocation of tax bases, the
more buoyant (trade and income) being apportioned to the federal level.
This is further exacerbated by the lack of political will to collect
resources.
Efficiency is a cardinal principle for good governance and only the
right responsive political structures can ensure this. Thus, this will
accrue from assigning functional responsibility to that governmental
organisation which is closest to the people. However, such assignment
must be consistent with the efficient delivery of that service. This
non-hierarchical assignment permits a more constructive and dynamic
relationship. For instance, the delivery of primary health care, primary
education, water supply and sanitation, targeted distribution of social
safety benefits are best delivered through local governmental
institutions.
Effective local governance can be assured only through the active
participation of a representative body of elected officials which has a
constitutionally assured permanence, has participatory representation
(say through proportional representation and quotas for women,
minorities and marginalised people), has constitutionally legislated
responsibilities and authority (regulation and provision of the full
range of services that can equitably meet the needs of the community),
and has an assured financial resource base which is not encroached on by
higher tiers of government, either directly or indirectly. Fiscal policy
should clearly assign which taxes may be levied by whom, and if shared,
assure a mechanism which ensures automatic credit by the Central
Bank/Treasury without reference to any governmental body.
The principle that the spending agency should also be the
collecting agency should govern all tax assignment between tiers of
government. For instance, all property and property related taxes are
normally considered to lie in the realm of local governments. Worldwide
these form the base through which resources are generated for
maintaining basic infrastructure and finance some of the development and
operations cost of primary services. In most of South Asia these have
been encroached upon by the higher tiers of government and assessing and
collecting responsibilities have been usurped by these higher spheres.
These responsibilities should be shifted down to ensure an assured,
stable and buoyant revenue source and also prudent expenditure
management.
To ensure adequate funding for capital works, the larger local
governmental organisations should also be assured access to capital
markets. In Pakistan particularly, local governments should not be
dependent on a system of erratic grants for development purposes. These
must be provided for routinely.
Accountability of both the elected and the administrative hierarchy
ensures adherence to standards and goals. This should be ensured,
firstly through audit by non-governmental professional audit
organisations, and secondly by prosecution through an independent
tribunal under a legal framework which mandates a time-bound process.
Accountability also requires that there should be greater transparency
and openness (accessibility) in the system. This can be assured through
a number of actions, such as:
* Beneficiary participation in planning (through a system of
committees with beneficiary representation in addition to councillors,
and backed by mandatory public hearings and advertising in the media
inviting public objections).
* Participatory budgeting (involvement of councillors in the
preparation of budgets in preference to the preparation by officials in
isolation).
* Involvement of the non-profit and for-profit
non-governmental/private sector institutions.
* Increasing public awareness.
* Simplification of processes.
* Public participation and audit of council debates and access to
information.
Operational management must conform also to standards and goals.
Beneficiary participation in the setting of goals and standards should
be assured through a mandatory process of public hearings by elected
representatives and nominees of citizens' rights groups.
Participatory planning should be seen as an opportunity and not a
threat.
Weak political structures have resulted in the creation of weak
institutions, the lack of efficiency from planning to delivering
services, particularly in the social sectors, and poor management of
resources, man, material and financial.
INSTITUTIONAL CAPACITY, EFFICIENCY AND MANAGEMENT
The full set of institutions (legislative, administrative and
judicial) are transplants by the raj and, therefore, do not serve the
needs and aspirations of the populace. Society in Pakistan is largely
informal and based on kinship where patronage plays a major role. The
general perception of the common man is: his elected representative is
available only when he wants his vote; the bureaucracy and the judiciary
is there to serve the rich and powerful. The judiciary has been
subverted by executive power, the bureaucracy is politicised and
demoralised in all of South Asia and the executive is accountable in
name only. The systems are fragile, unresponsive to people's needs
and corrupt. Therefore, discretion, arbitrariness and political
expediency rule all decision-making. Institutions are thus weakened,
transaction costs are high and misgovernance increases.
At the root of the institutional decay lie the legislatures
themselves. Legislators are by their very nature expected to be
watchdogs, regulators, and law-makers. They are supposed to be
representatives of civil society. Legislatures, by and large, are
expected to be composed of individuals of merit and integrity. However,
in Pakistan legislators generally are seen to have bought their position
to power, are poorly educated (as opposed to schooled). Attendance in
Parliament is poor and women representation is minimal. Debates in
parliaments are endless and restricted to constituency politics only and
policy and decision-making is left in the hands of an overpowering
executive. This weakness in the legislatures is also due to a blurring
of the separation of powers between the three pillars of state.
Law-making is the responsibility of the Supreme Court also, largely
through its rulings which set precedents. The bureaucracy, in parallel
with the executive, continues to wield immense power over policy
formulation and implementation, for instance, by legislation through
'Presidential' ordinances initiated by the bureaucracy (as
many as 125 in 1996). The judiciary has also played a role in weakening
the legislature. As an example, the Supreme Court of Pakistan has
permitted the dissolution of Parliament on a number of occasions.
The executive is made of the head of government, the cabinet and
civil servants. While the former have tenure and are not necessarily of
the highest calibre, the latter are permanent and should be of the
highest calibre and above politics. The former is responsible for policy
and supervising implementation, the latter is required to administer and
advise. To the public it is this latter which is government. It has been
argued that the most powerful civil institution of Pakistan is the
bureaucracy. But they have forgotten that they are public servants and
not the rulers. By their very permanence, politicians have had to
influence them through patronage which has led to the erosion of them as
an institution. They are an all pervasive anachronism left from the days
of the raj. Their major functions continue to be economic and law and
order, in both of which they have failed. The provision of social
services remain neglected.
The highly layered hierarchy adds significantly to the cost of
service delivery, impedes the smooth functioning of departments, and is
a siphon for leakages and delays in implementation. The initial
rationale may have been to either decentralise authority as much as
possible, or to create a barrier between the beneficiary and the
authority responsible for providing the service. Over the years,
however, the concept of decentralised management and control has been
seriously eroded. The creation of administrative units, latch on
organisations for foreign aided projects and political patronage have
all meant that today the civil service is bloated and its size is
increasing. This is diametrically opposite to world trends where the
size of government is shrinking. Recent studies [Pakistan (1996, 1997);
WB (1999)] have indicated that a substantial part of the civil service
employees are redundant. As growth has slackened public sector
employment has risen, largely because this is seen to be the best avenue
for employment. The composition of the civil services is also skewed in
comparison to the rest of the world. In Pakistan there is one officer
for 15 other staff. In Bangladesh (which only three decades ago was the
eastern half of Pakistan) the ratio is 1:7. The norm of 1:3 is
recommended by all agencies.
Further the quality of civil servants has been eroded because of
quota-based employment. This in turn has made it easier for the
politicisation of the services. Only 10 percent of intake is based on
merit compared to 40 percent in Bangladesh. The sheer size of the
bureaucracy makes it inefficient and wasteful. Even though real wages
are lower than in the private sector and are declining, the total wage
bill consumes 56 percent of the non-defence, non-interest current
expenditures [WB (1999a)]. The decline in real wages has led to a
consequential increase in corruption, at times in collusion with
politicians. The differential in public and private sector wages has
compounded this problem. Some estimates suggest that the most
remunerated public sector jobs are 60 percent lower than comparable
positions in the domestic (non-multinational) private sector. The
differential increases with seniority. Thus talent is not attracted.
HDC (1999) concludes that "the institution has had to face
intense political interference in the form of both coercion and
patronage". Those who are loyal receive better (more
"lucrative") postings and more rapid promotions. Demotion,
political appointment, lateral entry, ad hoc transfers, and bureaucratic
reshuffle are only a few of the mechanisms used to ensure loyalty. Large
scale arbitrary termination and transfers have resulted in a further
lowering of morale and neutrality. On the flip side, they exert
considerable influence over politicians largely owing to the immature
nature of political parties and institutions.
Even though legislation may exist which allows for an efficient
allocation of responsibilities and ensuring transparency and
accountability in public administration, unless institutions have the
corresponding capacity and capability, no change may be forthcoming to
ensure efficiency in development process and delivery of services. The
public institutions in Pakistan are today faced with a multitude of
shortages and shortcomings. There is a skill shortage for identifying
and enunciating coherent and coordinated policies; the prevailing work
ethos discourages officials from ensuring compliance; systems and
procedures are cumbersome and outdated; mechanisms to ensure
coordination exist but are not implemented--meetings of the
secretaries' committees have not been held for years on end; there
is continuous interference in day-to-day management by vested interests;
staff is inadequately trained both ab initio and subsequently on-job
because of the very short-term assignment to posts; staff selection,
posting and promotions are not merit related; and the incentive
structure is designed to penalise the performers.
Some fundamentally sound administrative rules and regulations have
been allowed to fall into decay or have been regularly circumvented.
There is a need to return, in many cases, to the formal procedures as
originally defined, but, in other cases, an opportunity should now be
taken to re-draw them to reduce, if not totally remove, the opportunity
and hence the temptation to by-pass them. It must be realised at the
outset that any process of change affecting policies and the practices
that have become entrenched over the years will be viewed with
apprehension by some of those directly involved and the changes will
require sensitive handling.
Central to the creation of institutional capacity is the effective
decentralisation of functions. This means that financial powers,
administrative authority and commensurate responsibility must be given
to lower echelons but within a tight regulatory framework. The current
practice of requests for supplementary grants would, therefore, have to
be done away with and the current powers to authorise expenditures in
excess of budget allocation would need to be exercised in the same
manner as the budget allocation itself, that is by the legislature in
assembly through a process of dialogue "ex-ante".
Civil service reforms need to be introduced to make the public
official answerable for his actions. The current status of
"permanent non-terminable" employment must be replaced by a
system where the inefficient or the corrupt can be weeded out within a
short time frame. Staff skills need to be developed to use modem
management techniques. Mere attendance at courses operated by civil
service training institutions does not constitute training. Civil
servants must be required to show absorption of training skills by
results in tests and examination (as is done in the defence forces).
This should help in weeding out the incompetent. With greater reliance
on the private sector for the development of infrastructure and the
provision of services large public sector employment is unjustified. The
objective would be to, at least, reduce overall public sector employment
to a third of its current size.
Efficiency can be achieved in a number of ways. One may be the use
of appropriate mechanisms which ensure the greatest value for money.
Other ways may include pro-active legislation (rather than retro-active)
ensuring target based management, or through the use of information to
analyse shortcomings and suggest ways to improve. Yet others may be the
use of regulatory mechanisms which ensure that private sector provision
of services and development of infrastructure does not create rents for
the vested segments of society.
While private sector participation can to a large extent overcome a
number of shortcomings in the development of infrastructure and in the
provision of services, unless controlled and regulated it could lead to
situations of monopoly and oligopoly. This would result in excessive
rents accruing only to the few agents involved in the process to the
detriment of the disadvantaged. The legislative framework establishes
the boundaries within which the public-private partnership can take
place. However, these laws will need to be translated into a workable
and transparent regulatory framework. While some regulatory agencies
exist, they deal largely with matters related to the corporate sectors
and are only now beginning to address issues related to the environment.
The existing institutions are manned largely by staff without the skills
needed to ensure compliance, the knowledge and understanding needed to
adapt to a rapidly changing operating environment and the systems and
procedures which could generate the mutual trust between the two
agents--the regulators and the entrepreneurs.
The constant interference in day-to-day management by vested
interest groups also impedes the maintenance of infrastructure and
delivery of services in the social sectors. The fact that elected
officials are given a quota of jobs to hand out as they see fit ensures
that merit plays no role in the appointment of low-level staff. There
are countless examples of teachers being appointed who have neither the
qualifications nor experience required. Postings and transfers are made
to suit the convenience of politicians. The mandated tenure of 3 years
stipulated in the Rules of Business has not been applied now for the
last two decades or more. In fact, the trend in the length of service in
post has been asymptotic (tending to zero) in character.
In the past, many approaches have been tried to coordinate the
actions of all parties with an interest in social development, but these
have failed, and the administrative arrangements have withered away. One
such example is the Secretary's Committee in each province. It was
intended to be a forum to coordinate interests and plans and to review
improper demands being placed by the politicians within a framework of
set criteria. These committees were expected to meet at least quarterly,
however the last known meetings took place in early 1988. The committees
had little authority; some secretaries did not feel bound by their
conclusions and ignored them.
The absence of cost-effectiveness in the whole range of actions
from planning to delivery is a major impediment to the effective
delivery of social services in Pakistan. Over-design, low quality
construction, inappropriate technology, improper site selection, opaque
tendering procedures, and asynchronous release of funds have all reduced
the cost-effectiveness of infrastructure development in the social
sectors. The procedures used have been developed in such a way as to
serve the vested interests of those seeking rents from the system. This
results in an excessive need for repairs and maintenance, which cannot
be done for lack of funds. This scarcity of resources, measured as the
share of non-salary expenditure of total expenditure, has been worsening
over the years. It has been caused by a substantial increase in wages
caused by both an increase in the numbers employed and the wage rate.
The general practice of the finance department has been to reduce
expenditures on operations and maintenance (O&M), and not question
the wage bill. In the light of the resource constraints facing the
public sector at all levels, increasing the cost-effectiveness of
expenditures will not only help achieve social indicator targets, but
also strengthen the case for allocating more funds to the social
sectors. Increased cost-effectiveness can be attained in two ways:
either by achieving greater output from given resources or by reducing
the cost of achieving a given output.
One of the most serious problems in social service delivery is the
high level of wastage, particularly when resources are scarce. Examples
can best be seen in education. The net continuation ratio by year and
gender at the primary level since the mid-1970s shows (Graph 1) that the
continuation ratios have decreased since the beginning of the Social
Action Programme in 1992-93. A plausible reason for this apparent
decline may be due to one factor--the shift to private schools data for
which is conspicuous by its absence. The high dropout rate can be
attributed also to other factors such as poverty, the high opportunity
cost of education, teacher absenteeism, poor teaching skills,
inappropriate teaching methods, and the low motivation among parents to
educate their children, particularly in rural areas. This suggests a
need to improve the environment in schools by providing better
facilities, enhancing the number of qualified teachers and making the
curriculum more relevant and job-related.
[GRAPHICS OMITTED]
Another major weakness in the systems and procedures used to manage
social sector development and delivery is in the financial management
arena. There appears to be no mechanism to ensure value for money or
that funds are released to match demands. This is due not only to
shortfalls and uncertain revenue flows, but also to the outdated
systems, procedures and technology used. Budgets are prepared on the
basis of historical trends rather than actual or estimated needs. The
Finance Department then applies an across-the-board cut in these demands
ensuring that these cuts do not impact on critical items of expenditure,
such as travelling and daily allowances, the utility bills of senior
staff, fuel charges and work charged staff. Because little attention is
paid to routine maintenance, it usually ends up being charged to the
development budget. Invariably, funds covering the purchase of supplies
(e.g., books, surgical supplies, drugs, medicines, etc.) are deferred,
and are released in one tranche towards the end of the year (in late May
or early June). As a result, these are often purchased without using
good buying practices. In any case, the amount released is not enough to
meet requirements and is frequently less than the amount sanctioned.
This leads to the purchase of non-standard materials and inequitable
geographic distribution.
The carry forward (continuing) costs of ongoing schemes which have
remained incomplete at the close of one fiscal year are carried forward
to the following year(s). In 1991-92, these costs accounted for
approximately 75 percent of available funds. This amount has increased
to over 80 percent in 1998-99.
A REFORM AGENDA
Pakistan's impressive economic growth has not been accompanied
by healthy social development. The country's progress in improving
its social sectors has been slow. Over its fifty-odd years as an
independent nation social development has fallen behind population
growth at times. By 1991, not only was it clear that Pakistan was
lagging behind its neighbours in social development, but serious
internal imbalances had become evident--imbalances that cut across
rural-urban lines, across genders and across provinces.
It was against this backdrop that SAP was launched. With rural
deprivation a major problem, it was decided that SAP should have a rural
focus. As well, SAP was to take an integrated approach to the four key
sectors--primary education, primary health, rural water supply and
population welfare. These were chosen both because they were the most
basic social services required by the population and because of the
obvious linkages and potential for synergy between them. It would appear
that this has had little or no impact on the social sectors. In fact,
all reviews and the government's own statistics would tend to
indicate that there has been an adverse impact on primary education, and
little or no impact on water and sanitation. The health sector would
appear to have fared the best.
Impediments to social development fall within several broad areas:
legislative framework, political structures, institutional capacity,
management and efficiency.
Some of the mechanisms which can be used to overcome these
impediments follow. Most, however, require time. One must, however,
realise that changing institutions and societal norms cannot be achieved
at the wave of a wand. Reforms, without revolution, require time and
patience.
In the legislative arena one of the major tasks that should be
undertaken immediately should be a clearer definition of the several
tiers of government so that dichotomy, fragmentation and duplication of
responsibilities are removed and authority is clearly defined and
demarcated. To contain corruption, an obvious mechanism would be to
review legislation which helps breed corruption, such as through
creating monopoly power, permitting discretion without checks and
balances, exercises authority without responsibility. Another mechanism
would be to introduce legislation which is effectively implemented
through an impartial and independent authority (with substantial
representation from civil society and the senior members of the
judiciary). Corresponding changes in the laws of evidence and trial
should allow for flexibility in procedures and rigour of evidence.
Institutional reforms should be directed to achieve effective local
governance. Effective local governance can be assured only through the
active participation of a representative body of elected officials which
has a constitutionally assured permanence, has participatory
representation (say through proportional representation and quotas for
women, minorities and marginalised people), has constitutionally
legislated responsibilities and authority (regulation and provision of
the full range of services that can equitably meet the needs of the
community), and has an assured financial resource base which is not
encroached on by higher tiers of government, either directly or
indirectly. Necessary constitutional changes should be undertaken. The
recent change in governance structures in Pakistan may perhaps be the
ideal occasion for this reform. Fiscal policy should clearly assign
which taxes may be levied by whom, and if shared, assure a mechanism
which ensures automatic credit by the Central Bank/Treasury without
reference to any governmental body.
Accountability of both the elected and the administrative hierarchy
ensures adherence to standards and goals. This should be ensured,
firstly through audit by non-governmental professional audit
organisations, and secondly by prosecution through an independent
tribunal under a legal framework which mandates a time-bound process.
Accountability also requires that there should be greater transparency
and openness (accessibility) in the system. This can be assured through
a number of actions, such as: beneficiary participation in planning;
participatory budgeting; involvement of civil sector organisations;
simplification of processes; public participation and audit of council
debates; and access to information
Civil service reforms need to be introduced to make the public
official answerable for his actions. The current status of
"permanent non-terminable" employment must be replaced by a
system where the inefficient or the corrupt can be weeded out within a
short time frame. Staff skills need to be developed to use modern
management techniques. Mere attendance at courses operated by civil
service training institutions does not constitute training. Civil
servants must be required to show absorption of training skills by
results in tests and examination (as is done in the defence forces).
This should help in weeding out the incompetent. With greater reliance
on the private sector for the development of infrastructure and the
provision of services large public sector employment is unjustified. The
objective would be to, at least, reduce overall public sector employment
to a third of its current size.
Efficiency can be achieved in a number of ways. One may be the use
of appropriate mechanisms which ensure the greatest value for money.
Other ways may include pro-active legislation (rather than retro-active)
ensuring target based management, or through the use of information to
analyse shortcomings and suggest ways to improve. Yet others may be the
use of regulatory mechanisms which ensure that private sector provision
of services and development of infrastructure does not create rents for
the vested segments of society. All or a combination of these need to be
implemented.
Author's Note: The views expressed here are solely those of
the author as are all errors and omissions.
REFERENCES
Applied Economics Research Centre (1990) Local Government Finance
and Administration in Pakistan. Karachi: Applied Economics Research
Centre.
Asian Development Bank (1996) RRP:PAK 28330 Report and
Recommendation of the President to the Board of Directors on a Proposed
Loan to the Islamic Republic of Pakistan for the Social Action Program
(Sector) Project II. Manila.
Asian Development Bank (1997) Social Sector Issues in Pakistan: An
Overview. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Auditor General of Pakistan (1998) Social Action Programme Third
Party Validation : Governance Issues. Islamabad.
Auditor General of Pakistan (1998) Social Action Programme Third
Party Validation : Report on Site Validation. Islamabad.
Commission on Global Governance (1995) Our Global Neighbourhood.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Human Development Centre (1999) Human Development in South Asia
1999: The Crisis of Governance. Islamabad: Oxford University Press.
Ismail, Zafar H. (1996) Impediments to Improvements in Social
Sectors in Pakistan. Karachi: Social Policy and Development Centre.
Ismail, Zafar H. (1998) The City of Karachi: Planning and Managing
for Urban Development. Karachi: Social Policy and Development Centre.
Multi-Donor Support Units (1997) Report of the Workshop on Third
Party Validation by the Office of the Auditor General of Pakistan,
Islamabad.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (1995)
Participatory Development and Good Governance. Paris: Development
Cooperation Guideline Series.
Pakistan, Government of (1997) Pakistan Integrated Household
Survey, Round 1: 1995-96. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (1998) Access and Usage of Basic Health
Services in Pakistan. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (1998) Pakistan 2010: A Vision for
Knowledge-led, Just, Tolerant, Enterprising and Prosperous Society.
Pakistan 2010 Programme. Islamabad: Ministry of Planning and
Development.
Pakistan, Government of (1998) Pakistan Economic Outlook: Past
Present and Future; Pakistan 2010 Programme. Islamabad: Ministry of
Planning and Development.
Pakistan, Government of (1998) Pakistan Integrated Household
Survey, Round 2: 1996-97. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (1998) Participatory Development Programme:
Information and Project Proposal Form. Islamabad: Federal SAP
Secretariat and Multi-Donor Suppourt Unit.
Pakistan, Government of (1996) Planning Document: Social Action
Programme Project-II (1996-2000). Federal SAP Secretariat, Planning
Commission; Islamabad. November 21.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Economic Adviser's Wing.
PE Inbucon (1993) Metropolitan Management and Budgeting Study.
Egham, Surrey and Karachi.
Punjab, Government of (1998) Survey of School Management Committees
in Districts D.G. Khan and Gujranwala (Punjab). Islamabad: Department of
Education and the Multi-Donor Support Unit. May.
Social Policy and Development Centre (1997) Review of the Social
Action Programme. Karachi: SPDC.
Social Policy and Development Centre (1998) Social Development in
Pakistan--Annual Review 1998. Karachi: SPDC.
Social Policy and Development Centre (1999) Social Development in
Pakistan--Annual Review 1999: Social Development in Economic Crisis.
Karachi: Oxford University Press.
United Nations Development Programme (1997) Governance for
Sustainable Human Development. New York: Management Development and
Governance Division.
United Nations Development Programme (Various Issues) Human
Development Report. New York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank (1994) Governance: The World Bank's Experience.
Washington, D. C.
World Bank (1998) Implementation Completion Report:
Pakistan--Social Action Programme Project. Poverty Reduction and
Economic Management Division, South East Asian Region, Washington, D. C.
World Bank (1999) Pakistan: Civil Service Reforms. Washington, D.
C.
World Bank (1999a) Pakistan: Public Expenditure Review. Washington,
D. C.
Zafar H. Ismail is Principal Specialist/Company Secretary and Head
of the Governance, Training, Monitoring and Evaluation Unit of the
Social Policy and Development Centre.
Table 1
Trends in Economic and Human Development in Pakistan Since
Independence
Real Per Capita Human Development
Year Real GDP Index GDP Index Index
1949-50 74 93 89
1959-60 100 100 100
1969-70 192 135 120
1979-80 308 160 131
1989-90 538 217 159
1994-95 714 245 172
1998-99 835 260 193
Average Annual
Growth Rate 5.07% 2.12% 1.66%
Sources: (1) Pakistan (Various Issues).
(2) United Nations Development Programme (Various Issues).
Note: 1 for 1997.
Primary--Boys
Punjab Sindh NWFP Balochistan
1981-82 57.1 48.2 34.4 27.9
1991-92 68.5 41.2 31.3 19.8
1992-93 60.4 40.5 29.2 16.4
1993-94 49.6 45.1 25.7 17
1994-95 55.5 43.2 21.9
1995-96 13.9 30.4 22.3
Note: Table made from line graph.
Primary--Girls
NWFP Punjab Balochistan Sindh
1981-82 55.8 31.7 36.5 29.8
1991-92 59.8 44.7 30.4 20.4
1992-93 57.8 38.2 28.2 1.7
1993-94 77.5 36 30.3
1994-95 61.5 40.1 29
Note: Table made from line graph.