Rural development in the 21st century: some issues.
Gill, Zulfiqar Ahmad ; Mustafa, Khalid ; Jehangir, Waqar Ahmad 等
The benefits of rural development efforts have not trickled down to
the rural masses due to centralised planning, limited participation of
the rural people in the programmes of rural uplift and the feudal nature
of the rural set up. Illiteracy and poor infrastructure of the rural
areas along with dynastic and centralised power structure have kept the
rural poor on the periphery. It is recommended that as a first priority
the emphasis should be given to human resource and infrastructure
development to ensure participation of the rural masses in the
development process. Developing local leadership through a process of
devolution of power can be helpful in generating long-ran sustainable
agricultural and rural development pattern in the 21st century.
INTRODUCTION
Rural development is essentially a part of the process of
structural transformation characterised by diversification of the
economy away from agriculture. This process is facilitated by rapid
agricultural growth, at least initially, but leads ultimately to
significant decline in the share of agriculture to total employment and
output and in the proportion of the rural population to total population
[Johnston (1970)]. Rural development, as such, is not an end in itself
but a means to an end and can provide the basis for a sustained and
equitable economic growth of all sectors of the economy.
The main theme of the paper is to contribute to the perception of
rural development in Pakistan by delineating the pros. and cons. of past
rural development efforts and the ensuing crisis in agriculture.
Possible strategies for sustainable agricultural growth and rural
development and the formal approach for their implementation are
described in subsequent sections. It is argued that the whole scenario
requires courage and political will of politicians to decentralise the
development process. Concluding comments and future options for research
appear at the end.
PAST EXPERIENCE: CRISIS IN AGRICULTURE AND DILEMMA OF RURAL
DEVELOPMENT
Past Experience
The annals of village development in Pakistan provide evidence that
a number of experiments were made eversince the early years of the 20th
century to reactivate the rural economy. These measures were scanty and
did not establish gross-roots for lack of drive, vitality and
participatory confidence of all the segments and sectors of the society.
"Dehat Sudhar" and "Panchayat" were the two
systems or concepts that were addressed before independence. The
literature reveals that these efforts could not be institutionalised
with some serious effort and were just used as tools of control of the
rural community by the colonial rulers. However, after independence in
1947, some concerted efforts were made in the field of rural
development. An over view of these development programmes is given.
The village Agricultural and Industrial Development (Village-Aid)
programme was initiated in 1953 to work through community development
centres. The achievement of the programme was, by and large, marginal.
Amongst others, major weaknesses of the programme were: lack of
cooperation between the village Aid organisations and the other nation
building departments and imposition of leadership from outside
[Pakistan, FAO/UNDP (1973)].
The institution of Basic Democracies was introduced in 1959 in
order to remove deficiencies that had characterised the Village-Aid
Programme and to utilise the concealed unemployment in the rural sector.
This effort was further substantiated in 1963 by the introduction of
Rural Works Programme (RWP). The scheme did not yield desired results as
it became excessively a political slogan rather than a programme of
rural uplift [Ibid (1973)].
The Academy for Rural Development was set up in East Pakistan (now
Bangladesh) during 1960s'. The Academy offered an
agriculture-oriented practical model for cooperatives, acceptable to
farmers, workable and manageable by them at village and thana level in
the Comilla Project Area. The magnitude of success of the project was
considered comparatively too small to justify the funds pumped into it
in the form of Dollars and advisory services. As such, replication of
Comilla model in other parts of the country (West Pakistan) was not
considered.
The integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP). alongwith the
Peoples Works Programme (PWP) emerged as a combination of the above
mentioned models with the induction of private sector during the first
half of 1970s. It was based on a two tier system, one at the Village
level and the other at the "Markaz", comprising 50 to 60
villages; involving the rural community in the process of development.
It did not make any notable contribution to the rural economy. The IRDP
officials did not cooperate with each other in planning and organising
the development programmes. One of the important component of IRDP--the
cooperatives in the Markaz failed in generating funds from within the
project area. Neither was success achieved in mobilising human resources nor these cooperatives were able to ensure peoples participation in this
programme. The local bodies established at the gross root level never
became a part of this programme [Gill (1976)].
The Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) and Peoples Works
Programme (PWP) were merged in 1979 and redesignated as Rural
Development (RD). The programme turned out to be a replica of Basic
Democracies System with the only difference that local bodies were not
required to serve as an electoral college. This set up, like the
previous ones, did not make any considerable dent in the perpetuating
problems of rural masses [Pakistan (1988) and Gill and Qamar (1988)].
The present rural development activities in Pakistan are completely
enveloped by the local councils, represented by the elected
representatives. Efforts undertaken have helped in bringing improvements
in establishing infrastructure such as roads. However, diversification
towards health, education and human resource development activities have
not ensured broad based participation of rural communities. In summary,
formulation, planning, organisation and implementation of rural uplift
or development activities in Pakistan have remained more man than
community-centred [Pakistan (1988); Gill and Qamar (1988) and Pakistan
(1998-99)].
Crisis in Agriculture
Pakistan is still predominantly an agricultural country even after
half a century of concerted efforts towards industrialisation. The
dominant production activity of the rural sector is agriculture.
Although migration from rural to urban areas has increased considerably
over the past two decades, nearly three-fourths of the population still
makes its living through farming and lives in villages. This makes
agriculture the largest employer in the economy, accounting for 54
percent of the country's total labour force and supporting,
directly or indirectly, 70 percent of its population [Pakistan
(1998-99)].
There is no denying the fact that agriculture has an important role
to play in overall economic growth, poverty reduction, resource
management and over all development. It has direct bearing on the
economic growth by having 1/5 share directly in the economy and further
indirectly through adjustments and expenditure patterns of rural
communities. As reported in a study undertaken by World Bank (1994) each
one-percent increase in per-capita agricultural growth leads to 1.5
percent increase in per capita in non agricultural growth. Increasing
incomes in agriculture are spent on locally produced goods and services and help to increase rural employment, reduce poverty and serve as a
pre-condition in enhancing rural development. Moreover, the contribution
of agriculture to manufacturing is substantial. Industries dependent on
agriculture have the highest value added and indirectly exert
significant influence on overall growth of the economy.
This dependence of the economy on agriculture has created a crisis
situation, Pakistan has been facing for some years now. The steady
growth rate of the yester years is a dream and uncertainty now surrounds
its performance. The growth rate of agriculture touched as low as 0.12
percent during 1990s. This has happened in a country where the rate of
agricultural growth, on an average stayed around 6.77 percent in the
1960s and about 6.14 percent in the 1980s [World Bank (1994); Pakistan
(1998-99)]. Non-diversification of the rural economy, an over
pressurised agriculture (particularly the crop production), intensive
cultivation of land without conservation of soil fertility and soil
structure have led to decline in production and productivity with the
attendant uncertainty [Ahmad and Gill (1998)]. Excessive dependence on
agriculture has created a culture of excessive and indiscriminate use of
fertilisers, pesticides, fungicides and herbicides combined with
unscientific tapping of underground water that has made the agricultural
economy vulnerable to all sorts of fluctuations [Pakistan (1988)]. The
growth rate of agriculture started declining during the 1990s. It was
0.12 percent in 1996-97, picked up again and stayed just at 0.35 percent
during 1998-99, even in the wake of ongoing agricultural and rural
development efforts. [Pakistan (1998-99)]. Policies to get short term
gains have only succeeded in putting at stake the long term objectives
such as self-Sufficiency in food etc.
RURAL DEVELOPMENT'S DILEMMA
As noted earlier, rural development is a total process of economic,
social and human development. Development programmes have different
connotations in different political and social systems, but common to
all is the need to reduce unemployment, poverty and inequality with the
participation of the masses.
Despite the rhetoric and insistence on local or popular
participation in decision making, all development models had the same
"up-down" relationship, but with full government support to
safeguard rural Pakistan from the clutches of stagnation and poverty.
The programmes were expected to raise agricultural productivity, improve
marketing infrastructure, provide welfare services, develop cottage
industry and other income/employment generating activities. These
development paradigms improved the rural scene somewhat, but the
available commentaries and statements on the performance of these
programmes are highly contradictory. However, the available information
reveals that each programme achieved a limited success with little
tangible benefits to the real clientele. The major beneficiaries were,
by and large the well-to-do farmers. Little was achieved in terms of
increased production, income and welfare of the prospective
beneficiaries. Majority of the rural poor could not derive much
benefits. The impact of these programmes on rural life has remained
quite marginal. [Pakisan, FAO/UNDP (1973); Pakistan (1988); Mustafa and
Gill (1998) and Pakistan (1998-99)].
Even today nearly one-fourth of the country's population
subsists under extreme poverty conditions. Almost 50 percent of this
lives in rural areas, which include small farmers, and other non-farm
rural households [Pakistan (1988)]. This scenario is supported by a
number of studies. Naseem (1986) considered that 43 percent of the rural
population lived below poverty line. A world bank report (1991)
indicated that the highest 20 percent of the population share 40 percent
of income and consumption. Arena (1994) indicated that 30 percent of the
population in Pakistan lived in absolute poverty. It is thus evident
that benefits of development have not trickled down to the rural masses
as envisaged by the planners and policy makers, mainly due to mass scale
illiteracy and lack of technical know-how. This has kept the masses away
on the periphery from the core of development. It has been established
that agriculture income is the major source of income inequality in
rural Pakistan [Adams and Alderman (1993) and Richard and Jane (1995)].
Income inequality leading to poverty is attributed mainly to defects in
the mechanism of distribution which is subject to wide diversity in the
ownership, use and access to income generating resources between the
farming community in particular and the rural masses in general. It has
further been established that the farm area, cultivated area and
irrigated area inequalities between different farm size groups in
Pakistan have risen overtime [Gill and Mustafa (1997)]. Moreover,
Srinivasan (1993) has quoted from different studies on Pakistan that
agriculture has a strong interaction with rural poverty and it is quite
higher than urban poverty.
The dominant aspect of rural Pakistan's socio-economic scene
is its feudal nature, that makes it very difficult for the fruits of
overall growth and development to percolate downwards. It gives the
socially dominant class enormous economic benefits through unequal
exchanges and its access to income generating/assisting resources
[Mustafa and Zulfiqar (1998)]. The poorer sections, by and large, remain
passive and ill-organised, the result of mass scale illiteracy. They can
neither understand increasing sophistication of the urban areas nor the
complicated working of government organisations. The masses are neither
involved in planning nor in the implementation process [Pakistan
(1988)]. Any developmental programme, when it gets implemented,
therefore tends to deviate from the poor and illiterate and benefits the
richer and educated groups of the society. This is one of the major
structural problems which has made almost all attempts for rural
development ineffective in Pakistan.
THE STRATEGY AND THE FORMAL APPROACH TO RURAL DEVELOPMENT
The Strategy for Rural Development
The concept of rural development is conceived as an improvement in
the economic and social conditions of the rural people. All efforts
should be directed for uplifting the social and economic status of the
rural masses. Agriculture being the major activity of the rural
communities, nevertheless, as a first step efforts are needed to boost
agricultural production and productivity, and then to launch the process
of rural diversification. The increasing production and productivity
would facilitate the process of siphoning surplus labour from
agriculture to nonagriculture sectors.
The withdrawal of excess labour from agricultural production
activities does not mean that it is to be taken to urban centres, but to
be gainfully employed in and around villages through rural employment
opportunities by retaining and using rural resources, human or capital,
in rural areas, particularly in the production of wage goods from
activities like agro-based industry, horticulture-based industry,
industry related with dairy, fisheries, sericulture, cottage industries
of different types and style, agro-forestry and forest based industry.
Such activities fetch a better price for the farmer, and the value added
to the product is shared by the rural community. This paves the way for
the generation of new indigenous technologies giving rise to further
employment opportunities, and paving way for correction of distribution
patterns and alleviation of poverty. In the long run this can increase
incomes and would result in upgrading villages into towns, and serve as
a natural check on rural to urban migration. It can further enhance a
strong agriculture-industry link in the long-run. As an outcome the
creation of small towns and large villages and industrialisation based
around these centres will be easy to handle in terms of planning,
security and other related problems and provide an incentive for further
development.
Any developmental programme would not be effective in developing
rural areas or helpful in achieving the desired goals of prosperity
without optimal utilisation of available resources and effective
participation of the people. Participation and involvement of the people
is something which cannot be achieved by mere asking but has to be
voluntary and reciprocal. It requires molding opinion and nurturing
qualities of imagination, initiative and spirit of dedication among the
villagers. As such, leadership from within the rural folk should be
drawn if sustainable agricultural growth and a comprehensive but lasting
rural development pattern in the long-run has to be achieved. Keeping in
view this long-term aspect of rural development, we now turn our
discussion on human resource and infrastructure development.
Human Resource Development
The present rural scene in the country is marred by the appalling
illiteracy and ignorance alongwith disease and poverty [Pakistan
(1998-99); World Bank (1994); Srinivasan (1993); Richard and Jane
(1995)]. This weakens the power of decision, causes frustration and
depresses the potentialities of human resources. The development of
human resources is thus vital to the uplift of rural society. Without
developing human resources, the society will be compromising on a
declining structure of political and social life, creating strife in
place of welfare.
In a wider sense, the development of human, resources means a
process enabling the society to build capacities and abilities (both
material and spiritual) of individuals in such a manner that these are
of some use both to the society and the individual.
The advent of the 21st century invites us to build a self-reliant
society with a scientific bent, through an education system that trains
our manpower for specific requirements in technology, engineering,
management, administration and teaching.
A number of studies on Pakistan reported by the World Bank (1994),
have emphazised the need for education and human resource development.
It is noted that a 10 percent increase in literacy increased total
factor productivity by 2.7 percent, area under irrigation by 2.4 percent
and share of area under high yield varieties by 1.3 percent
respectively, indicating the dominant role of literacy. Moreover it is
established that there is a strong complementarity between education and
the provision of extension services. It is further noted that the
quality of education is a major concern in determining the productivity
of farmers and the share of the common man in total rural income.
A properly monitored system of education is the need of the time
and may be developed both at the primary and higher levels. Manpower
should be trained according to the desired needs of the community and
the curricula so tailored that students, on completion of their studies,
automatically find jobs. The imparted education should be functionally
useful and also relevant to the present and future needs of the
communities.
NEED FOR RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE
The World Bank Report (1994) contends that improved infrastructure
not only facilitates agricultural production, but also generates
non-farm income opportunities, which are crucial to poverty reduction.
Moreover, human resource development and the knitting of various rural
development activities into an integrated whole is almost impossible
without proper infrastructural development.
Investments in infrastructure and the provision of related services
are integral to the process of development [Wanmali and Yassir (1995)].
Infrastructural investments (roads, electrification, irrigation,
telecommunication) in agriculture play a key role in improving
agricultural production [Wanmali (1992); Ahmad and Donovan (1992)]. It
has been established that investment in infrastructure helps in
increasing accessibility of people to services, and in the dissemination
of new technologies [Wanmali and Yassir (1995); Cites Ahmad and Hussain
(1990) and Hazall and Ramasary (1991)]. Moreover, investment in soft
infrastructure (services such as those related to transport, finance,
input distribution, animal husbandry and marketing etc.) is equally
important. In the absence of these structures the very outcome would be
unsound planning and execution of development programmes.
The importance of infrastructure cannot be denied but insufficient
attention has been given in the past to the development of
infrastructural facilities in the rural areas [Pakistan (1988) and World
Bank (1994)]. One major reason responsible for slow pace of rural
development is the poor capital formation in rural areas, an outcome of
limited access of people to the services offered by rural financial
institutions [Pakistan (1988); Mustafa and Zulfiqar (1998)]. There is
dire need for the provision of infrastructural facilities, i.e.
education, transport, communication, health and banking etc. to the
rural communities. In the absence of these services the human resource
development and the objective of transforming rural communities from
poverty to prosperity will remain a dream.
FORMAL APPROACH TO RURAL DEVELOPMENT
Mindless urbanisation of rural areas may not be conceived as rural
development. Neither the creation of consumerism can be judged as rural
development, nor the provision of goods and services enjoyed by urban
folk to the rural masses can serve the desired purpose. Moreover
centralised macro-perspectives will also not generate the desired
results, since every village/region is a different entity and it is
impossible to implement centrally planned and even well conceived
programmes uniformly in all the areas while ignoring their micro level
variations. The bureaucratic and impersonal process of implementation of
rural programmes should therefore be discarded. Any development
programme aiming at the transformation of rural societies should take
into account the socio-economic aspects and the behavioral pattern of
rural society.
Any change aimed at improving efficiency and income of rural people
should not attempt to sever their relationship from their social and
cultural heritage. At the same time the development model or programme
should have the essence of horizontal movement and not vertical
linearity in order to maintain the balance between economic and social
aspects on the one hand and encourage participatory enthusiasm, in
planning, implementation and execution of developmental efforts on the
other. Thus any developmental effort has to be slow and gradual but
persistent, so as to allow the rural people to absorb the spirit of
change in the perspective of social harmony. The process of human
resource development and the investments in infrastructure should move
along these lines.
For achieving the forestated goals and purposes, a well thought out
and carefully designed local institutional/organisational structure
needs to be established. Under this set-up the institutions should think
and plan locally and at the same time have an understanding of the
outside world. This alone can promote both economic and non-economic
factors (i.e. nutrition, health, education etc.) alike.
THE POLITICAL WILL AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT
Pakistan is not poor in manpower, talent, planning expertise and
institutions of research and development. However, sustained and
directed research and a strong political will are some of the essential
pre-requisites for achieving the desired goals. The development process
that started with the birth of the country, has had much success, but
has been limited in scope. Almost all efforts have failed in achieving
distributive justice for the lowest rungs of the society. As noted
earlier, envisaged benefits of planned changes through different rural
development efforts have not percolated downwards to the poor. The basic
reasons are vertical linearity in planning and in the execution of rural
development efforts. Moreover, attention has not been given to
horizontal spread of programmes through active and concerted
participation of rural masses, who are at the lowest rung of illiteracy
and poverty. Amongst others, these are some important factors which make
all schemes of rural uplift efforts in the country ineffective.
What is required is the redirection of priorities by mobilising
institutional and human resources towards political, economic and civic
dimensions. While the government should provide social, legal and
economic safety nets, the real focus should be on empowering the people
who should organise, plan and execute the programmes at the base level.
Success in the 21st century would essentially rest upon successful
blending of centralisation and localisation. Rural folk must be involved
in the political system by devoluting power in an appropriate manner at
the local levels. The fate of the masses should not be left at the mercy
of dynastic political leaders and an administration of narrowly selected
civil service. It would be rather impossible to create and sustain
powerful constituencies/institutions for change without the courageous
leadership from within the masses. The political leadership and elite of
the society should seriously think and plan for introducing desired
reforms for social and economic changes at the local level.
CONCLUSIONS/FUTURE CONSIDERATIONS
The fruits of rural development efforts have failed to trickle down
to the rural masses. The main reasons are: lack of diversification in
the rural economy which is a consequence of centralised planning and
implementation of development programmes without participation of the
common man. This failure can further be attributed to the low pace of
human resource and infrastructural development. The process of
decentralisation and devolution of power should be carried to the
village level if rural developments efforts are to succeed.
The most important task to be undertaken is to change the rural
patterns of thought and behaviour, particularly of young men, rather
than over-emphasising physical and material dimensions of the rural
economy. It may be done by evolving a human resource development plan
capable of redirecting the present elitist education towards value/moral
building, technical and operation-based education. There is need to
study the distribution pattern of land and income generating resources
of rural areas in order to formulate policies helpful in mitigating
existing inequalities in their ownership and use. It would be useful to
document past performance and the present potential of the rural economy
to develop a mutually strengthening working environment for agriculture
and non-agriculture sectors in different regions and sub-regions of the
country. This would pave the way for further diversification and
generation of employment opportunities in the rural areas.
Last, but not the least, appropriate methods of power
decentralisation, tax collection and its expenditure pattern may be
developed at national, provincial and village levels to ensure
continuous development process in the country.
Comments
The authors have written an interesting article on an extremely
important topic. They introduced the paper with discussion of the past
rural development programmes (RDPs) of Pakistan. They argued that the
formulating, planning and implementing (FPI) of RDPs with no input from
the rural masses offended the norms of appropriateness, efficiency and
effectiveness and thus was the principal cause of their awfully poor
performance. Using certain RDPs by politician/privileged groups as means
to maneuver political gains, social power and financial benefits is also
said to have influenced their FPI. Similarly, ignoring human resource
development in the FPI of RDPs has also resulted in continued
backwardness of the rural areas. The current crisis of the fall in the
productivity of the farm sector has been attributed to the ignorance and
illiteracy of farmers and non-development of adequate rural
infrastructure to the mode of centralised planning and to the low saving
of farmers. The authors ended their article with a plethora of
prescriptions for rural development in the country during the :21st
century.
It is agreed that the rural sector has been subjected to many RDPs
in quick succession. Neither the introduction nor the discontinuation of
any programme was determined scientifically. Since the FPI of all the
RDPs have been influenced by political expediency, they could not
achieve intended alleviation of poverty, ill-health, disease,
illiteracy, unemployment, income inequalities, hunger and infrastructure
in the country.
Both the political expediency in launching RDPs and their poor
performance has been documented in the relevant literature. However, the
authors have attributed the current crisis of low farm productivity to
non-diversification of farming enterprises leading to intensive crop
cultivation and to heavy irrigation which is arguable. The authors held
that "the non-diversification of rural economy over-pressurised the
agriculture particularly the crop production and as a consequence the
intensive cultivation of land without conservation of soil fertility and
soil structure led to the declining and uncertain production and
productivity pattern. It is further aggravated by heavy irrigation
without proper drainage mechanism in soils getting alkaline and
saline". The current cropping intensity in whole of Pakistan is
estimated at best at 100 percent and at 150 percent at the maximum in
areas where use of tubewell water with canal supplies and tractor
cultivation is on the increase. In fact, the current irrigation canal
system permits only 75 percent cropping intensity and enables farmers to
meet half of the optimal consumptive water requirements of crops. To
argue that land is being cultivated too intensively in Pakistan and has
led to a decline in its productivity and that irrigation has aggravated
it further is hard to support empirically.
The authors have remarked that "the excessive dependence on
agriculture has created a culture of excessive and indiscriminate use of
fertilisers and pesticides and made agriculture economy vulnerable to
all sorts of fluctuations". This again reflects the lack of true
knowledge of real facts. Exceptions notwithstanding, use of fertiliser
is like cropping intensity and irrigation water significantly lower than
the desirable level. The use of pesticides also cannot be regarded
indiscriminate.
To the authors, the remedy for the rural development dilemma lies
in the involvement of the masses in the FPI of the RDPs and in
encouraging rural diversification. However, the style of diversification
suggested is only partially consistent with the weather conditions,
resource endowments, technical know how and infrastructure obtaining in
the rural areas. While the authors seem to be aware of the occurrence of
surplus labour as a consequence of agricultural/rural development and
the desirability of retaining it in rural areas, they do not seem to
know how to achieve it. In fact, they have failed to appreciate how
increased irrigation can create employment opportunities in rural areas
by enabling farmers to increase cropping intensity and cultivated area,
and adopt input-intensive cropping patterns.
The human resource development (HRD) needs to be accorded top
priority in FPI of the RDPs. However, the author's view of HRD seem
to be extremely limited. According to them, increased access to a job
oriented education system constitutes HRD. This is only one requirement
of it. The efforts at enhancing literacy need to be dovetailed with
increased access to better nutrition, modern health services, on-the-job
training and growing opportunities of advancement and freedom for
promotion of HRD. Further, the role of increased component of vocational
and technical education also needs to be appreciated for improving the
prospects of employability of manpower.
While wanting to highlight the supreme importance of proper
planning for HRD, the authors have contended that Pakistan is not poor
in manpower, talents, planning expertise and institutions of R&D. I
have my reservations. Scientifically and technically trained manpower is
not in abundant supply; highly educated individuals do not constitute
more than 3 percent of the population; planning expertise has miserably
eroded and institutions of R& D are virtually in shambles. There is
no justification for such a complacency. Rather, there is a need to be
realistic.
The provision of adequate infrastructure as the next strategy
suggested for rural development in the next century is inevitable. Yet
it is strange that the authors hold that "one major reason for slow
pace of rural development is the poor capital formation in rural areas
as a consequence of limited access to financial institutions". To
advocate such a link is highly unjust, if not preposturous on their
part. Such a wholesale superimposition of borrowed alien ideas on the
indigenous rural setting will be dangerous. Rural savings have all along
been invested in urban areas. Additional rural banks and other financial
institutions can increase rural savings. But rural infrastructure cannot
develop if rural savings continue to be invested somewhere else. The
need is to legislate measures to ensure equitable investment in rural
areas. The rural sector must get additional investment in its own right.
Over the years, not more than 3.4 percent of the entire public sector
development allocations have been made in rural areas. The authors point
to the desirability of developing rural infrastructure but they are
unable to order the priority.
I would conclude my comments by arguing that the article has not
been attempted on lines of a rigid scientific method of research. No
precise identification of an empirically verifiable statement of the
researchable problem has been made. There is no analytical method or
framework given to estimate any policy-relevant variables to establish
their relationship with outcomes. The paper is a narration of events
followed by a range of prescription excessively loaded with value
judgements and normative assertions. I only wish the authors had
utilised their energy and time in undertaking research on lines of
scientific research method. Further, there was the need not to loose
sight of realities on the ground. Knowledge of recent numerical data and
research is inevitable for one to be on a safe wicket.
Muhammad Ali Chaudhary
Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Adams, R. H. Jr., and H. Alderman (1993) Sources of Income
Inequality in Pakistan. In A. S. Haider et al. (ed.) Association of
Agricultural Social Sciences. Islamabad, Pakistan.
Ahmad, B., Munir Ahmed, and Zulfiqar A. Gill (1998) Restoration of
Soil Health for Achieving Sustainable Growth in Agriculture. The
Pakistan Development Review 37:4.
Ahmad, R., and C. Donovan (1992) Issues of Infrastructural
Development a Synthesis of the Literature. Washington, D.C.: IFPRI.
Ahmad, R., and M. Hossain (1990) Development Impact of Rural
Infrastructure in Bangladesh. IFPRI, Washington, D. C. (Report 83.)
Arema (1994) State, Markets and Inequalities 10:1 61.
Gill, Z. A. (1976) Organisation Functioning and Performance of
Cooperatives in Rajana Markaz of Integrated Rural Development Programme.
Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis, University of Agriculture, Faisalabad.
Gill, Z. A., and Khalid Mustafa (1997) Farm-area, Cultivated Area
and Irrigated Area Distribution in Pakistan, 1972-90. Pakistan Journal
of Agricultural Science 34:1-4.
Gill, Z. A., and Qamar Mohy-ud-Din (1988) Rural Development the
Pakistan Perspective. Journal of Rural Development and Administration
20:4.
Hazell, P. B. R., and C. Ramasamy (1991) Green Revolution
Reconsidered. The Impact of High-Yielding Rice Varieties in South India.
Washington, D. C.: IFPRI.
Johnston, B. F. (1970) Agriculture and Structural Transformation in
Developing Countries: A Survey of Research. Journal of Economic
Literature 8.
Mustafa, K., and Zulfiqar Ahmad Gill (1998) Cooperatives and
Development: Lessons from the Punjab Experience. The Pakistan
Development Review 37:4.
Naseem, S. M. (1986) Underdevelopment, Poverty and Inequality in
Pakistan. Lahore: Vanguard Publications, Ltd.
Pakistan, Government of (1988) Report of the National Commission on
Agriculture. Islamabad.
Pakistan, Government of (1998-99) Economic Survey (1998-99).
Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.
Pakistan, Government of/FAO/UNDP (1973) Report of the International
Seminar on Integrated Rural Development. Islamabad.
Richard, H. A. Jr., and He Jame (1995) Sources of Income Inequality
and Poverty in Pakistan. IFPRI, Washington, D. C. (Report 102.)
Srinivasan, T. N. (1993) Poverty Alleviation in South Asia. Yale
University, U.S.A.
Wanmali, S. (1992) Rural Infrastructure, the Settlement System and
Development of the Regional Economy in Southern India. IFPRI,
Washington, D. C. (Research Report 91.)
Wanmali, S., and Yassir Islam (1995) Rural Services, Rural
Infrastructure and Regional Development in India. Washington, D.C.:
IFPRI.
World Bank (1994) Pakistan: A Strategy for Sustainable Agricultural
Growth. Washington, D. C.: World Bank.
Zulfiqar Ahmad Gill and Khalid Mustafa are associated with the
Faculty of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, University of
Agriculture, Faisalabad Waqar Ahmad Jehangir is associated with the
International Irrigation Management Institute, Lahore.