The impact of tariff reforms on income distribution in Pakistan: a CGE-based analysis.
Siddiqui, Rehana ; Siddiqui, Rizwana ; Iqbal, Zafar 等
The study examines the impact of reduction in tariff on industrial
goods across households and on other broad macroeconomic aggregates.
Using a CGE model framework, we analyse the impact of reduction in
tariff on industrial goods. The model has 215 equations explaining the
linkage among the variables. The basic data for estimating the model are
taken from Social Accounting Matrix for the year 1989-90. The simulation
exercise suggests that the negative impact of changes in relative prices
in response to reduction in tariff rate are disproportionately higher
for the lower income group. The gap between the rich and poor households
in widening. Decline in investment also has negative implications for
the economy as a whole. The paper suggests that income distribution is
worsening in rural and urban areas of Pakistan due to reduction in
tariff rate on industrial imports.
1. INTRODUCTION
Like most developing countries, Pakistan has undertaken drastic
economic policy reforms since the mid-1980s. Under these structural
reforms there is a general shift away from quantitative restrictions and
price controls towards liberalisation and privatisation. The empirical
studies (1) analysing the impact of the reforms report mixed results.
Economy wide framework like Computable General Equilibrium (CGE), based
on the social accounting matrix, is well suited to analysing the effect
of these structural reforms. The CGE models are developed to capture the
medium to long-run effects through which adjustment programmes affect
income distribution. These models are often used to evaluate the effects
of trade and tax policies on income distribution in developing
countries. There are three interacting channels through which these
adjustment policies affect income distribution, viz., the relative price
effect, the asset price effect and the shift in portfolio. However, in
this study, we are analysing the effect of changes in relative prices
only.
The first and more easily quantifiable channel is through analysis
of the impact of changes in production prices following changes in
tariff. For a given shock in the above mentioned policy variables, the
medium to long-run distributional impact of the resulting structural
adjustment is determined by the extent of relative price rigidities
(fixed real wages, or mark up pricing), the extent of factor mobility
(supply elasticity's) and difference in consumption pattern across
socio-economic groups. Difference in assumptions and closure rule play a
very important role in market adjustment mechanism in developing
countries. Simulation exercises show that assumptions about the macro
economic closure and behavioural parameters matter a great deal in
determining the productive and distributive effects of a shock and a
country's adjustment to the shock. These exercises also show the
channels through which a country can capture the effects of alternative
adjustment packages on income distribution. For example, resistance to
wage cut and profit cut has strong implications for the factoral
distribution of income. Poverty is likely to increase when there is
resistance because the economy is not functioning at full capacity.
Utilising the framework developed by Decaluwe et al. (1999) and Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999a), the study is extended in the following way.
Households are disaggregated by regions (i.e., by urban/rural) and by
income groups to see the impact of tariff rate reduction on imported
goods on income distribution. The order of the study is as follows:
Model is discussed in Section 2 and results are discussed in Section 3.
Conclusions are in the final section.
2. MODEL
The general structure of "Micro-Macro" economy-wide
simulation model is used to analyse the impact of tariff reduction on
distribution of income. Trade tax reforms (tariff reduction) affect the
pattern of sectoral demand and it can be well captured by the
disaggregation of production sector through the CGE model.
(a) Structure of SAM 1989-90 for Pakistan
Every economy-wide model, particularly the CGE model, requires a
consistent database. For this paper data arranged in Social Accounting
Matrix (SAM) framework provides the best consistent data set. For
Pakistan, the latest SAM for the year 1989-90 is given in Siddiqui and
Iqbal (1999) (see Table 1). It presents a comprehensive picture of the
whole economy. It disaggregates production activities into five sectors;
agriculture, industry, education, health and others. These commodities
are then transformed into traded goods, i.e., exportable, and non-traded
goods, i.e., goods for the domestic market. This disaggregation allows
us to capture the effects of policy changes on sectoral demands and
supplies. Factors of production are disaggregated into labour and
capital. Four types of institutions are identified as households, firms,
government and rest of the world. (2) In accordance with the orientation
of analytical interest and policy problems related with the field of
distribution of income and consumption, classifications in the
SAM-1989-90 (in the present form) highlights the income receipt pattern
of aggregate households from different sources and their uses on
different items and household sector is disaggregated by region, rural
and urban areas of Pakistan. In each region households are categorised by four income groups; upto Rs 2500, Rs 2501-4000, Rs 4001-7000, and Rs
7001 and above. The mechanism by which policy changes affect the
distribution of income are as follows:
(a) Changes in factor rewards directly affect household income
distribution.
(b) Changes in relative production prices affect real income of
households differently as baskets of Consumption goods differ by income
group.
The following issues determine the outcome of policy change:
(1) The selection of macroeconomic closure rule and institutional
characteristics (assumption about the working of markets) affect the
distributional outcome of policy change. The simulation exercise shows
how important closure rule and institutional settings are to the
distributive consequences of a shock. Since the outcome of policy change
varies with institutional characteristics, the selection of adjustment
policy is critical.
(2) Sector specific supply of capital stock is fixed. Increase
(decrease) in demand change the price of capital, not the allocation.
(3) Decline in prices due to reduction in tariff has important
implications for resource allocation, income distribution and poverty
alleviation.
(b) Computable General Equilibrium Model for Pakistan
The CGE Model is, basically neoclassical in nature, in line with
the framework given in Decaluwe et al. (1996). The model contains six
blocks with more than 200 equations. The exchange rate acts as
numeraire. Its value is set equal to one. The mathematical equations of
the model are given in Appendix. The theoretical background of the
equations in each block of the CGE model are discussed below:
1. Production Sector: Domestic production is disaggregated into
five sectors, viz., agriculture, industry, others, health and education.
Like other empirical studies, we adopted technology in which gross
output has separable production function. We assume the Cobb-Douglas production functions for value added and the Leontief technology between
intermediate and value added and also within intermediates. Equations
for gross output, value added (specified as a function of labour(L) and
capital(K)) and intermediate demand (aggregate as well as disaggregated)
are specified in Equations 1 to 4.
2. Factors' Demand: Assuming perfect competition and market
clearing, labour demand function for the ith sector is derived from
respective Cobb-Douglas production function. Labour demand is specified
in Equation 5. Capital is sector specific and it is assumed to be given
in the short run. The price of capital is determined by Equation 30 in
the price block. Changes in factor prices play important role in
explaining the issue of functional income distribution.
3. Foreign Trade Sector: We assume that domestic sales and exports
with the same sectoral classification represent goods of different
qualities. The CET function describes the possible shift of sectoral
production between the domestic and external markets. For import
function, we assume that domestically produced goods sold in the
domestic market are an imperfect substitute of imports (Armington assumption). Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) import
aggregation function presents demand for composite goods (imported and
domestically produced goods). In addition to Equation 6 for export
transformation and Equation 7 for import aggregation, profit
maximisation/cost minimisation gives desired exports and imports ratios
as a function of relative prices (domestic to foreign prices). (see
Equations 8 and 9, respectively.)
4. Income, Saving and Consumption: Institutions; households, firms,
government, and rest of the world, receive income from five sources.
Each institution has various sources of income. The endowment of primary
factors and their rental values determine the institutions' income.
All income and saving of institutions are used for consumption and
investment purposes. Relevant equations are given in the income and
saving block of the model.
(i) Household: All wage income accrues to households. Similarly
households receive share of capital income (lambda) from total capital
income from different activities. They also receive income from firms as
dividends, transfers from government as social security benefits, and
transfers from the rest of the world. Equation 12 represents total
income of hth households from the above mentioned sources. Dividends for
the hth households are determined by Equation 14. Transfers from the
government and from the rest of the world are assumed to be exogenous.
Households pay taxes to government. Subtracting taxes from the total
income we get the disposable income of households. The consumption of
ith commodity by hth households is defined by Equation 24, while total
consumption of households is presented by Equation 25. These equations
describe how households' income is allocated among different goods.
It is defined with fixed value share of ith good [[beta]ij].sup.c]. The
sum of [[beta]ij].sup.c] is equal to 1. In addition, savings of the hth
households is defined in Equation 15.
(ii) Firms: Firms receive income from capital and transfers from
government. Equation 17 presents their total income. Income from capital
(retained profit) is presented in Equation 16. Transfers from the
government are given exogenously. Their expenditure includes tax
payments to the government, dividends to jth households, and transfers
to the rest of the world, while the residual is saved by the firms.
(iii) Government: The third institution, government, receives
income from the following sources, i.e., direct taxes (income tax from
households, corporate taxes from firms), indirect taxes (from production
sector), import duties, export duties, and transfers from the rest of
the world. Total government revenue is given by Equation 22. Equations
for indirect taxes, taxes from imports and from exports are presented in
Equations 19, 20, and 21, respectively. Government's total current
expenditure is given in value. Government's total expenditure on
commodity 'i' is the fixed share calculated through Equation
27. Government saving is calculated as a residual after subtracting
consumption expenditure from total revenue.
The total consumption expenditure on goods i is the sum of
expenditure on goods 'i' by different household groups and by
government. In addition to consumption expenditure, there is a demand
for goods i for the investment purposes. Equation 29 converts aggregate
investment into demands for investment goods by sector of origin. I is
gross capital formation in commodity i, [[beta].sup.I]ij is fixed value
share where the sum of shares is equal to one. Gross saving from
different households groups, firms, government and rest of the world
serve as a source of funding for gross investment.
5. Prices: Block 5 of the model presents prices. There are seven
different prices associated with each tradable good, as price of
aggregate output, price of composite goods, price of domestic sale,
domestic price of imports, domestic price of exports, world price of
imports, and world price of exports. World prices of exports and imports
are exogenously determined. All prices are defined in Equations 30
through 36. The price index i.e., GDP deflator, is presented in Equation
37.
6. Equilibrium: The final block presents saving investment
equilibrium, goods market equilibrium, and labour market equilibrium by
Equations 38, 39, and 40, respectively.
7. Model Closure: The model is closed in the Current Account
Balance equation and the exchange rate acts as numerair.
3. RESULTS
(a)(i) Income Distribution by Sources of Income in Pakistan
(3)--Baseline Scenario
In this paper households income from labour (wages and salaries),
capital (operating surplus) and dividends (transfers from firms) are
endogenously determined. Transfers from government and transfers from
the rest of the world are exogenous. The results show how the income
from different sources changes in response to policy change. (4)
The present study differs from Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999a) as
households are distinguished by four income groups; (1) up to Rs 2500
per month (lowest), (2) Rs 2501-4000 (low), (3) Rs 4001-7000 (medium),
and (4) Rs 7000 and above (high), for rural and urban areas of Pakistan.
The study shows that 43.1 percent households are in the lowest income
group. The second, third and fourth income groups, respectively, consist
of 29.1 percent, 19.2 percent and 8.3 percent of total urban households
of Pakistan. The study reports that the highest income group receives
the highest percentage of total income, 31 percent and the lowest income
group receives only 18 percent of total income. But on average one
percentage of the lowest household receives only 0.42 percent while one
percentage of households from high income group receives, on average,
3.7 percent of total income. This shows that the income of households
from high income groups receive nine times higher than the income of
lowest income group.
Labour supply is the main source of income of the poor in Pakistan,
while the rich class earns the largest share of their income from
capital and dividends. The study shows that 43.1 percent (lowest income
households) receive 24.4 percent of total wages and salaries and 8.3
percent high income households receive 21.9 percent of total wages and
salaries. As many as 48.4 percent of total households (both low and
middle income groups) receive about 53.8 percent of total wages and
salaries. The high income group receives the highest share of income
from all other sources-but wages, i.e., capital income (28.6 percent)
and dividends from firms (56.2 percent). On the. other hand, the lowest
income group (but the highest percentage of households) receives the
lowest share from the other sources of income, i.e. 17.6 percent as
capital income and 3.2 percent as dividends from firms. Thus, it
presents a clear picture of skewed income distribution by source in the
urban areas of Pakistan.
The study shows that the main source of income of the poorest
households is wages and salaries i.e. 54.2 percent of their total income
comes from wages and salaries and 42.2 percent of their total income
comes from capital and 1.1 percent as dividends from firms. The richest
group of households earns 28.5 percent from wages and salaries and 40.1
percent from capital income. It is worth noting that in contrast to the
lowest income group, the high income group receives the largest share
from capital. The incomes of this group from other sources are also
higher than the income of the lowest income group. It receives 11.6
percent of their total income from firms as dividends.
The study presents the percentage distribution of total income from
different sources across the rural income groups and percentage of
households' income from different sources. It shows that 59.8
percent of aggregate households in rural areas are in the lowest income
group and only 4.5 percent households are in the high income group. This
study also shows that in the poorest class, 60 percent of households
receive 29.4 percent of total income and the rich, 4.5 percent of rural
households receive 23.4 percent of total income. On average 1 percent
rural poor households receive 0.49 percent of total income and one
percent of high income groups receives 5.2 percent of total income. This
shows that the income ratio between rich and poor in rural areas is
10:1. The study also reveals that 51.2 percent of the total wages and
salaries in rural areas is earned by households in the lowest income
group. On the other hand, the high income group receives only 8.3
percent of total wages and salaries. Furthermore, we see that 25.9
percent of capital income accrues to the lowest income group (60 percent
households) while 22.4 percent to the high income households (4.5
percent rural households). Similarly, the largest shares of dividend,
i.e., 51.7 percent, from firms go to households in the high income
group. The lowest income group receives only 9.9 percent of the total
dividends from firms.
This study also shows that all income groups in rural areas earn
the highest share of their income from capital. The lowest, low, middle
and highest income groups receive 56.6 percent, 68.3 percent, 72
percent, and 61.5 percent of their income from capital respectively. It
also shows that the lowest income group receives 37.4 percent of its
total income and the highest income group 7.6 percent of its total
income from wages and salaries. It is worth noting that as rural
households' monthly income level increases, their percentage shares
in dividends from firms also increases. These groups from the lowest to
the highest income groups receive 2.6 percent, 5.2 percent, 7.4 percent
and 17.1 percent of their respective income as dividends from firms,
respectively. It is worth noting that shares of wages and salaries in
households income fall as income rises and shares of income from capital
and dividends increase as monthly incomes of rural households increase.
(ii) Expenditure by Different Income Groups--Baseline Scenario
In this model we endogenise household expenditure on individual
commodities, total consumption and saving. But taxes paid by the
households are exogenous. The consumption of agriculture products is
basically food consumption, while consumption of manufacturing products
is consumption of durable and nondurables like processed food items. As
mentioned earlier, this baseline solution is discussed in Siddiqui and
Iqbal (1999). The study shows that the share of each income gap in total
expenditure on agriculture is 27.3 percent by the lowest income group
and 17.0 percent by the highest income group in urban areas.' The
shares in total expenditures on manufacturing products are 18.2 percent
and 26.3 percent for the high and the lowest income groups,
respectively. The results shows expenditure on education is positively
correlated with income. It is about 40.6 percent of total expenditure on
education for the high income group and only 12.1 percent of total
expenditure for the lowest income group. The order is reverse for
expenditure on health as the lowest income group spends 26.2 percent and
high income group spends only 15.4 percent of total expenditure on
health, In Pakistan the tax system is progressive, so the highest share
in total taxes (37.2 percent) is paid by the high income group. The
lowest income group pays 7.3 percent of total taxes in urban areas.
Similarly, households with high income contribute the lions' share
to total households' saving and the low income group reports
negative savings. The expenditure pattern of rural households reveals
almost a similar expenditure pattern.
The study also discusses the pattern of expenditure within the
rural income groups. It reveals that the lowest income group spends 45.9
percent of total expenditure on agriculture and 57.3 percent on
manufactured commodities. As income rises the percentage expenditure of
total expenditure on these commodities declines. The expenditures on
agriculture commodities are 34.1 percent, 26.2 percent, and 12.8 percent
of the total expenditure by the low, middle and high income groups,
respectively. Similarly, expenditures on manufactured commodities are
42.2 percent, 33.4 percent, and 16 percent of total expenditure by the
low, middle, and high income groups. Expenditure on education by all
these income groups is less than 0.5 percent of their respective income.
The same is the case for health expenditure by all income groups. The
high income group pays 1.3 percent of its income as taxes to the
government while the low, middle and high income groups pay less than
0.5 percent of their respective incomes as taxes to government. The
lowest rural income group is a dissaver as 28.6 percent dissaving is
reported by this group. The other three rural income groups save,
respectively, 2.9 percent, 21.7 percent and 57.7 percent of their
incomes. It is also worth noting that the high income group in rural
areas saves 57.7 percent of its income as compared to the urban high
income group, who saves 35.4 percent of its income.
(b) Simulation Exercise: 80 Percent Reduction in Tariff Rate on
Industrial Imports
The impact of tariff rate reduction depends on the interaction
between the domestic economy and the foreign trade sector. The first
impact of reduction in tariff rate is lower import prices of industrial
imports by 16.37. This decline in the imported price leads to increase
in demand of imported goods and people substitute imports for
domestically produced goods resulting in imports by 9.80 percent. As the
demand for imported industrial goods increase and demand for
domestically produced goods decline, domestic price of industrial goods
also declines. Due to this decline in domestic price, producers reduces
the supply of industrial goods by 0.76 percent. This reduction in
production reduces the demand for factors of production. The demand for
labour in this sector is reduced by 2.56 percent leading to decline in
wages by 4.18 percent. Due to decline in wages the demand for labour in
other sectors increases by 2.60 percent, 5.61 percent, and 3.93 percent
in agriculture, health and education sectors, respectively. This leads
to increase in production in these sectors. The prices of all these
products also decline. The results show that returns to capital also
decline. The decline in returns to factors of production leads to
decline in income of institutions.
The results also show that the income of each households group
declines. The reduction in the income of the lowest income group is the
largest. While the reduction in the income of the highest income groups
is smallest in rural and urban areas of Pakistan. In short, the gap
between the rich and poor is expected to increase after the shock.
Decline in prices leads to increase in demand of goods and
services. The results show that the demand for industrial goods by each
groups of households was the largest as compared to increase in demand
for all other goods. The results also show that the increase in demand
increases with the increase in income. This shows that the rich are
benefiting more than the poor. The distributional impact of tariff
reduction does not seem to be working in the right direction as the
negative impact on household consumption is disproportionately high for
lower income groups. As expected, the reduction in tariff results in
significant loss of government revenue resulting in increase in public
deficit and ultimate negative effect on capital formation.
4. CONCLUSIONS
The study examines the impact of reduction in tariff on industrial
goods across households and on other broad macro aggregates. The
simulation exercise suggests that the negative impact of changes in
relative prices is disproportionately higher for the lower income
groups. Thus, tariff reduction increases the gap between the rich and
poor. Decline in investment also has negative implications for the
economy as a whole. This paper suggest that income distribution is
worsening in rural and urban areas of Pakistan due to reduction in
tariff rate on industrial imports. We intend to extend this analysis by
using more recent input-output table (whenever it becomes available). We
will also compute 'gini' coefficient to complete the analysis.
Comments
The subject study uses economy-wide framework Computable General
Equilibrium (CGE) based on Social Accounting Matrix to analyse the
effects of Structural Adjustment Policies on income distribution in
Pakistan. There being three channels through which these adjustment
policies affect income distribution namely relative price effect, asset
price effect and portfolio shift effect, the study incorporates the
relative price effect only bypassing the other equally important
channels.
The focus of the study is on measuring the impact of 80 percent
reduction in tariffs on industrial products which is analysed using
Social Accounting Matrix of 1989-90 which is the latest available in
Pakistan. The CGE Model is of a neoclassical nature which contains 6
blocks and about two hundred equations. The value of exchange rate which
serves as numeraire is set equal to one. The economic blocks are the
production sector, labour demand, foreign trade sector, income, saving
and consumption sector, household sector, firm sector and the government
sector, which are 7 in number and not 6 as is claimed in the beginning
of the study.
The study, when examined critically in terms of its basic
structure, approach, methodology and conclusions, turns out to be of a
far lesser use as a tool for policy formulation, as compared to the
claims of the authors.
The basic problem with the study relates to its failure to identify
the different parameters of the study in precise terms e.g. it focuses
on 80 percent tariff reduction on industrial products. However, it does
not identify what are the benchmark tariffs and what are the final
levels of tariffs after 80 percent reduction. The study also does not
identify the composition of industrial products such as raw materials
for consumer goods, raw materials for capital goods or final industrial
products like machinery etc. It was desirable for proper understanding
of the subject that the classification of industrial products according
to STIC System or itemwise specifications in line with Pakistan's
tariff schedule were given.
The study is based on Social Accounting Matrix for the year 1989-90
which is fairly outdated and does not reflect some of the basic
transformations in the economy of Pakistan experienced during the last
one decade. However, SAM 1989-90 could be upgraded by using plausible
assumptions about the real growth rate of the major sectors of
Pakistan's economy and the inflation rates and that could serve as
a better data base for analysing the effects of tariff changes on the
income distribution. Such an upgradation of the SAM was undertaken in
1999-2000 by the Tax Policy Unit of the Central Board of Revenues (CBR)
and was quite useful for studying the impact of tax policy changes on
revenues, prices, etc.
The relevance of the neo-classical nature of the CGE Model can be
questioned one the premise that economies of the most of the developing
countries including Pakistan suffer from basic distortions and
imperfections which reflect major departure from the basic structure and
assumptions of CGE Neo-classical Models.
The results of the study are counter-intuitive and contradictory.
For example, one of the conclusions of the study is that low growth in
domestic output and decline in consumption has resulted in a sharp
increase in the exportable surplus but the very next conclusion states
that the decline in import price has increased the demand for industrial
goods which is related in a positive effect on consumption and composite
demand. Obviously the two conclusions are contradictory in nature.
Another contradictory result of the study relates to the behaviour
of investment and income growth. According to the study, 80 percent
reduction in tariffs on industrial products increases investment in all
the sectors, but, the income declines at the same time. This result
contradicts the basic principles of production and growth theory which
establishes a positive co-relation between investment and real growth in
an economy.
The study correctly concludes that reduction in tariffs brings
about significant losses in government revenues but the study fails to
provide any quantitative estimates of such losses. The estimation of
revenue losses in relatively precise terms should not be difficult once
a CGE Model is deployed for analytical purposes.
The study establishes positive directions in the distribution
effects of tariff reduction, as the negative impact on household
consumption is shown to be disproportionately high for higher income
groups coming from a higher income decline as compared to the income
decline of lower income groups. This conclusion is not convincing
because the linkages between tariff reduction and household consumption,
income distribution are not clearly established. Once investment
increases as the study observes, it is natural to expect that this will
be adding to the income of high income group households and is likely to
improve their share in the distribution as well.
The study fails to analyse the impact of tariffs on the level of
protection specially the changes in Effective Protection Rates (EPRs)
and Domestic Resource Cost (DRC) of the different industrial sector on
account of tariff reduction. The CGE Model could be modified to diagnose this aspect of industrial growth in Pakistan.
One of the major problems currently faced by the industrial sector
of Pakistan relates to its increasing non-competitiveness in the world
economy resulting from lower protection following the policy of reducing
tariffs on regular intervals under IMF (ESAF/EFF), World Bank and WTO commitments and pressures. In other words, lower tariffs are one of the
important factors leading to growing number of sick units as well as the
industrial stagnation being experienced in Pakistan. The study fails to
incorporate the protection effect of tariff reduction on industrial
output and income distribution.
Aqdas Ali Kazmi
Central Board of Revenue, Islamabad.
Appendices
Appendix 1
I. CGE MODEL FOR PAKISTAN Appendices
Production:
(1) [X.sub.i.sup.s] = (L, K, [IC.sub.i] io,
Vi) Production 5
(2) [VA.sub.i] = CD ([K.sub.i], [L.sub.i.sup.D];
A, [[alpha].sub.i];) Value Added 5
(3) [IC.sub.i] = [LF.sup.*]([X.sup.S.sub.i])
Intermediate Consumption of goods I 5
(4) [IC.sub.ij] = [a.sub.ij]([IC.sub.j])
Intermediate Consumption of goods I
in jth sector 25
(5) [L.sub.i.sup.D]; = [CD.sup.*] ([P.sub.i.sup.VA]
/W, [VA.sub.i]) Labour Demand. 5
Foreign Trade:
(6) [X.sub.n.sup.S] = CET([Ex.sub.n],
[D.sub.n]) Export transformation 4
(7) [Q.sub.n] = CES([D.sub.n], [M.sub.n])
Import aggregation (Armington) 4
(8) [Ex.sub.n] = [CET.sup.*] ([Pn.sup.E],
[P.sub.n.sup.D], [D.sub.n]) Export Supply 4
(9) [M.sub.n] = [CES.sup.*] ([P.sub.n.sup.M],
[P.sub.n.sup.D], [D.sub.n]) Import Demand
(10) QNT = [X.sub.NT] Demand for non-traded Goods 1
(11) [SIGMA][P.sub.n.sup.WM] * [M.sub.n] + (1/e)
[T.sub.FR] - [SIGMA][P.sub.n.sup.WE] *
[EX.sub.n] - [TR.sub.H] - [TR.sub.G] = CAB
Current Account Balance 1
Income and Saving:
(12) [Y.sub.H] (h)= W[SIGMA][L.sub.i.sup.D] +
[lambda][SIGMA][R.sub.n][K.sub.n] + DIV + e
* [TR.sub.H] + PINDEX * [TR.sub.G]
Household Income 8
(13) [YD.sub.H](h) = (1-[t.sub.y]) *
YH Household Disposable Income 8
(14) DIV (h)= dvr * [YF.sub.K] Dividends 8
(15) [S.sub.H] (h)= mps(h) * [YD.sub.H] (h)
Household Saving 8
(16) [Y.sub.FK] = (1-[lambda]) [SIGMA]([R.sub.i]
[K.sub.i]) Capital Income of Firms 1
(17) [Y.sub.F] = [Y.sub.FK] + PINDEX *
[T.sub.GF] Firms Total Income 1
(18) [S.sub.F] = [Y.sub.F] - tk * [Y.sub.FK] -
DIV - [TF.sub.R] Firms Saving 1
(19) [TXS.sub.i] = [tx.sub.i] * [P.sub.i] *
[X.sub.i.sup.S] Indirect Taxes 5
(20) [TXM.sub.n] = [tm.sub.n] * e * [P.sub.n.sup.WM]
[M.sub.n] Taxes on Imports
(21) [TXE.sub.n] = [te.sub.n] * e * [P.sub.n.sup.E]
[EX.sub.n] Taxes on Exports 4
(22) [Y.sub.G] = ty * [Y.sub.H] + tk * [Y.sub.FK] +
[SIGMA][TXS.sub.i] + e * [T.sub.RG] +
[SIGMA][TXM.sub.n] + [SIGMA]TXE.sub.n]
Government Revenue 1
(23) [S.sub.G] = [Y.sub.G] - Pindex * T - Pindex *
T-CT Government Saving 1
Demand:
(24) [C.sub.Hi] = [[beta].sub.i.sup.c] * [CT.sub.H]/
[P.sub.i.sup.c] Household Consumption
for good i 40
(25) [CT.sub.H] = [YD.sub.H] - [S.sub.H] Total
Household Consumption 8
(26) [INTD.sub.i] = [SIGMA] [a.sub.ij] [IC.sub.j]
Intermediate Demand 5
(27) [CG.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.i] [CT.sub.G]/
[P.sub.i.sup.c] Government Consumption 5
(28) [C.sub.i] = [CH.sub.i] + [CG.sub.i]
Total Consumption of Good i 5
(29) [I.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.i.sup.I] * IT/
[P.sub.i.sup.c] Investment
Prices:
(30) [R.sub.i] = ([P.sub.i.sup.VA] * [VA.sub.1] -
W * [L.sub.i.sup.D])/[K.sub.i] Returns
to Capital 5
(31) [P.sub.n](1 + [tx.sub.i]) * [x.sub.n.sup.s] =
[D.sub.n.sup.s] * [P.sub.n.sup.D] +
([EX.sub.n]) * [P.sub.n.sup.E] Value of Output 4
(32) [P.sub.n.sup.VA] * VA = ([P.sub.n] * [X.sub.n.
sup.s] - [SIGMA]([P.sub.j.sup.C]) [IC.sub.ji]
Value of Value Added 4
(33) [P.sub.n.sup.M] = (1 + [tm.sub.n]) * - e *
[P.sub.n.sup.WM] Import Price 4
(34) [P.sub.n.sup.E] = (e * [P.sub.n.sup.WE] / 1 +
[te.sub.n]) Export Price 4
(35) [P.sub.n.sup.C] = ([P.sub.n]/[Q.sub.n]) *
[P.sub.n.sup.D] + ([M.sub.n]/[Q.sub.n])
[P.sub.n] Composite Price for Composite Goods 4
(36) [P.sub.nt.sup.C] = [P.sub.nt]
Price for Non Traded Goods 1
(37) Pindex = [SIGMA]([[beta].sub.i.sup.x * Pi)
Price Index 1
Equilibrium:
(38) IT = sum([S.sub.H](h) + [S.sub.F] + [S.sub.G]
+ - e * - CAB) Saving Investment Equilibrium 1
(39) [Q.sub.i] = [C.sub.i] + [INTD.sub.i] +
[INV.sub.i] Goods Market Equilibrium 5
(40) Ls = [SIGMA]([L.sub.i.sup.D])
Labour Market Equilibrium 1
Total Equations 215
II. VARIABLES
Endogenous Number of
Variables Definition Variable
(1) [C.sub.i] Total Consumption of Goods 5
(2) C[G.sub.i] Public final Consumption of
Goods i 5
(3) [CH.sub.i]; (h) Household h's Consumption of
Goods i 40
(4) [CT.sub.H] (h) Total Consumption of household h 8
(5) [D.sub.n] Domestic Demand for domestically
produced goods 4
(6) DIV (h) Dividends distributed to
Households from firms 8
(7) [EX.sub.n] Exports of nth goods (FOB) 4
(8) [M.sub.n] Imports of nth goods (CAF) 4
(9) [IC.sub.i] Total Intermediate Consumption
of Goods by ith sector 5
(10) [ICJ.sub.i] Intermediate Consumption of 25
Goods J by ith sector
(11) [INTD.sub.I] Intermediate Demand of Good I 5
(12) [INV.sub.i] Consumption of Goods by I for
investment in sector i 5
(13) IT Total Investment 1
(14) [L.sub.i.sub.D] labour Demand in sector i 5
(15) [P.sub.n] Producer price 4
(16) [P.sub.i.sub.C] Price of Composite goods 5
(17) [P.sub.n.sub.D] Price of domestically produced
and consumed goods 4
(18) [P.sub.n.sub.E] Domestic price of Exports 4
(19) [P.sub.n.sub.M] Domestic Price of Imports 4
(20) [P.sub.n.sub.VA] Value Added Price 5
(21) PINDEX Producer price Index 1
(22) [Q.sub.i] Domestic Demand for Composite
Goods i 5
(23) [R.sub.n] Rate of Return on capital
in branch n 5
(24) [S.sub.F] Firms Saving 1
(25) [S.sub.G] Government Saving
(Fiscal Deficit) 1
(26) [S.sub.H] (h) Saving of Household h 8
(27) [TXE.sub.I] Taxes on Imports of nth sector 4
(28) [TXM.sub.i] Taxes on Exports of nth sector 4
(29) [TXS.sub.I] Indirect taxes on ith sector
production 5
(30) [VA.sub.I] Value Added of sector i 5
(31) [X.sub.i.sub.s] Production of ith sector 5
(32) [Y.sub.H] (h) Total Income Household h 8
(33) [YD.sub.H] (h) Disposable income of h
Households 8
(34) [Y.sub.F] Firms total income 1
(35) [Y.sub.G] Government Revenue 1
(36) [YK.sub.F] Firms Capital Income 1
(37) W Wage rate 1
Total Endogenous Variables 214
18*5+8*1+10*8+9*4=90+8+80+36=214.
Exogenous Variables
CAB Current Account Balance 1
[CT.sub.G] Government final consumption 1
e Exchange Rate 1
[K.sub.n] Branch I's Capital Stock 3
[L.sup.S] Total Labour Supply 3
[P.sub.n.sub.WE] World Price of Exports 4
[P.sub.n.sub.WM] World Price of Imports 4
[T.sub.FR] Firms transfers to the rest of
world 1
[T.sub.GF] Government transfers to Finns 1
[T.sub.GH] (h) Government Transfers to
Households 8
[T.sub.RG] Foreign transfer payments to
the Government 1
[T.sub.RH] (h) Foreign transfers to Households 8
Total Exogenous Variables 36
III. SYMBOLS
[A.sub.i]: Cobb-Douglas Scale Coefficients.
[a.sub.ij]: Input Output Coefficients.
[[alpha].sub.I]: Cobb Douglas elasticities.
[[beta].sub.i.sup.c]: Percentage share of goods i in household
consumption.
[[beta].sub.i.sup.G]: Percentage share of goods i in Public
consumption.
[[beta].sub.i.sup.I]: Percentage share of goods i consumed for
investment purposes.
[[beta].sub.i.sup.x]: Percentage share of goods i in total
Production.
[lambda]: Household Share of Capital Income.
dvr(h): Dividend rate for Households h from firms.
[io.sub.i]: Leontief technical coefficients (Intermediate
Consumption of goods i).
mps(h): Households h marginal propensity to save.
ty(h): Income tax rate of households.
tk: Capital Income tax rate of firms.
[tx.sub.i]: Indirect tax rate on branch ith Production.
[v.sub.i]: Leontief technical coefficients(value added).
REFERENCES
Amjad, R., and A. R. Kemal (1997) Macroeconomic Policies and their
Impact on Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development
Review 36:1.
Decaluwe, B., M. C. Martin, and M. Souissi (1996) Ecole PARADI de
modelisation de politiques economiques de development. Quebec:
Universite Laval.
Iqbal, Z., and R. Siddiqui (1999) The Impact of Structural
Adjustment on Income Distribution in Pakistan: A SAM Based Analysis.
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. (MIMAP Technical
Report No. 2.)
Mahmood, Zafar (1999) Pakistan Conditions Necessary for the
Liberalisation of Trade and Investment to Reduce Poverty. Unpublished
Research Paper.
Nasir, Z. M. (1999) Poverty and Labour Market Linkages. Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. (MIMAP Technical Report).
Siddiqui, Rizwana, and Zafar Iqbal (1999) Social Accounting Matrix
of Pakistan for 1989-90. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics,
Islamabad. (Research Report No. 171.)
Siddiqui, Rizwana, and Zafar Iqbal (1999a) The Impact of Tariff
Reduction on Functional Income Distribution of Households: A CGE Model
for Pakistan. Presented in Regional Workshop on Modeling Structural
Adjustment and Income Distribution: CGE Framework, May 16-17.
Thorbecke, E. (1991) Adjustment, Growth and Income Distribution in
Indonesia. World Development 19:11 1595-1614.
Tilat, A. (1996) Structural Adjustment and Poverty: The Case of
Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 35:4 911-926.
White, H. (1997) The Economic and Social Impact of Adjustment in
Africa: Further Empirical Analysis. Unpublished Paper.
(1) See Amjad and Kemal (1997); White (1997); Tilat (1996); Mahmood
(1999); Iqbal and Siddiqui (1999); Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999a) and
Thorbeck (1991).
(2) We distinguished household group in our earlier study [Siddiqui
and Iqbal (1999)] into four income groups for rural and urban areas of
Pakistan separately. This disaggregation is carded out to make an
example how the SAM framework and the related CGE model can combine the
macro economic features with microeconomic issues. Although
disaggregatiou of the household sector is of much importance to see the
impact on income distribution, but in this paper we just keep the
household sector aggregate.
(3) This part of the paper is taken from Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999).
(4) For details see Siddiqui and Iqbal (1999 a).
Rehana Siddiqui and Rizwana Siddiqui are Senior Research Economist
and Staff Economist at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics,
Islamabad. Zafar Iqbal is working as Economist at the Office of the
Senior Resident Representative, International Monetary Fund, Islamabad.
Table 1
Simulation Results with 10 % Reduction in Tariff
Rate on Industrial Imports
Percentage
Variables Base Year Change Variables
[VA.sub.ag] 212693 0.55 [XS.sub.ag]
[VA.sub.ind] 150037 -0.76 [XS.sub.ind]
[VA.sub.he] 5963 2.63 [XS.sub.he]
[VA.sub.o] 361752 -0.20 [XS.sub.o]
[VA.sub.ed] 17332 3.13 [XS.sub.ed]
Percentage
Variables Base Year Change
[VA.sub.ag] 355811 0.55
[VA.sub.ind] 630627 -0.76
[VA.sub.he] 8919 2.63
[VA.sub.o] 620705 -0.20
[VA.sub.ed] 19044 3.13
Percentage Change in
Household Demand for Goods
Agriculture Industry Health
Base %-age Base %-age Base
value change value change value
[CH.sub.u1] 25837 0.50 33485 8.57 556
[CH.sub.u2] 27784 0.71 36436 8.79 606
[CH.sub.u3] 24995 0.93 34039 9.02 637
[CH.sub.u4] 16085 1.32 23174 9.45 327
[CH.sub.r1] 47929 0.82 59768 8.90 1004
[CH.sub.r2] 28600 1.13 35334 9.21 594
[CH.sub.r3] 22050 1.22 28120 9.35 549
[CH.sub.r4] 10618 1.33 13805 9.46 276
INV 1458 -22.34 96225 -16.11 14
Percentage Change in
Household Demand for Goods
Health Others Education
%-age Base %-age Base %-age
change value change value change
[CH.sub.u1] 0.60 17820 3.29 406 0.31
[CH.sub.u2] 0.81 21677 3.50 742 0.52
[CH.sub.u3] 1.03 22181 3.73 851 0.74
[CH.sub.u4] 1.42 24415 4.13 1363 1.13
[CH.sub.r1] 0.92 24758 3.61 404 0.62
[CH.sub.r2] 1.23 16347 3.93 366 0.94
[CH.sub.r3] 1.32 14642 4.03 337 1.03
[CH.sub.r4] 1.43 9166 4.14 204 1.14
INV -22.26 65348 -20.18 7.00 -22.48
Labour Demand
[L.sub.D] 45681 -4.76 45415 1.07 2839
Labour Demand
[L.sub.D] 1.03 101471 1.38 13883 1.90
Percentage Change In Prices
Base %-age Base %-age Base
value change value change value
[W.sup.*] 209289 -4.81
[P.sub.D] 1.00 -4.15 1.00 -9.10 1.00
P 1.00 -4.1 1.00 -7.64 1.00
[P.sub.VA] 1.00 -2.24 1.00 -5.93 1.00
[P.sub.c] 1.00 -4.00 1.00 -11.16 1.00
[P.sub.M] 1.00 0.00 1.00 -16.37 1.00
[P.sub.E] 1.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00
[P.sup.*.sub
.index] 1.00 -6.39
R 1.00 -1.70 1.00 -2.41 1.00
Percentage Change In Prices
%-age Base %-age Base %-age
change value change value change
[W.sup.*]
[P.sub.D] -4.15 1.00 -6.9 1.00 0.00
P -4.15 1.00 -6.53 1.00 -3.82
[P.sub.VA] -1.41 1.00 -4.68 1.00 -3.45
[P.sub.c] -4.1 1.00 -0.59 1.00 -3.82
[P.sub.M] 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 0.00
[P.sub.E] 0.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 0.00
[P.sup.*.sub
.index]
R 1.19 1.00 -3.58 1.00 -0.36
Foreign Trade
M 12378 -5.67 166554 9.80 122
EX 3867 3.98 102210 11.80 9
Q 364322 0.29 694971 0.24 9032
Foreign Trade
M -3.70 18153 -8.56 0.0 0.0
EX 9.37 22386 8.23 0.0 0.0
Q 2.54 616472 -0.76 19044 0.0
Income of Institutions
[Y.sub.Hu1] [Y.sub.Hu2]
Base %-age Base %-age
value change value change
[Y.sub.H] 64297 -3.52 85908 -3.32
[S.sub.H] -13933 -3.52 -1666 -3.32
DIV 680 -2.72 3403 -2.72
Base Value %-age change
[Y.sub.G] 135174 -28.36
[Y.sub.F] 146954 22.61
Income of Institutions
[Y.sub.Hu3] [Y.sub.Hu4]
Base %-age Base %-age
value change value change
[Y.sub.H] 95955 -3.11 109497 -2.73
[S.sub.H] 12612 -3.11 152405 -2.73
DIV 5150 -2.72 11842 -2.72
Income of Institutions
[Y.sub.Hr1] [Y.sub.Hr2]
Base %-age Base %-age
value change value change
[Y.sub.H] 11473 -3.22 93921 -2.92
[S.sub.H] -19335 -3.22 12553 -2.92
DIV 2719 -2.72 4325 -2.72
Income of Institutions
[Y.sub.Hr31] [Y.sub.Hr41]
Base %-age Base %-age
value change value change
[Y.sub.H] 94854 -2.83 92109 -2.73
[S.sub.H] 28952 -2.83 56961 -2.37
DIV 6231 -2.72 14209 -2.72
Agriculture Industry
Base %-age Base %-age
Value change Value change
[TX.sub.s] 1557 -3.57 40103 -8.34
[TX.sub.M] 857 -5.67 42844 -78.04
Health Others
Base %-age Base %-age
Value change Value change
[TX.sub.s] 4 -1.63 10265 -6.72
[TX.sub.M] 0.0 0.0 3.0 -8.56
* Wage rat is same in each industry as labour is mobile.