Supply, demand, and policy environment for pulses in Pakistan.
Ali, Mubarik ; Abedullah
This paper fills an information gap regarding factors affecting the
supply and demand of pulses in Pakistan. The short- and long-term supply
elasticities were estimated using the Nerlovian partial adjustment
process, while demand elasticities were estimated by applying the Deaton
and Muellbauer Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS). Generally lack of
technological innovation in pulses, except in mungbean, has reduced
their production and they are pushed to low intensive areas which are
marginal for cereal and cash crop production. Pulses did not benefit
from the investment in irrigation infrastructure. Increase in wage rates
has further affected the mungbean and lentil production. On the demand
side, contrary to normal belief, pulses have high own-price demand and
income elasticities. Thus decline in pulses consumption is not caused by
their being regarded as inferior goods, rather it can be attributed to
disproportionate increase in pulses price, as laxity in pulses research
left their production behind demand. The high-yielding, short-duration,
and pest-resistant pulses varieties with synchroniscd maturity can
revive their production trend as well as improve the dietary pattern,
especially of the poor.
**********
Black gram, mungbean, lentil, and mash are the major pulses grown
in Pakistan. Pulses production in the country declined from 836 thousand
t in 1973 to 614 thousand t in 1994-95 (Table 1). Laxity of
policy-makers for food legumes and introduction of high-yielding,
input-responsive varieties of cereals during the late 1960s and 1970s
not only reduced the pulses yield, but also pushed pulses cultivation to
marginal lands. For example, per ha yield of pulses declined from 514 kg
in 1973 to 419 kg in 1993, while wheat yield increased from 1248 kg to
1893 kg during the corresponding period (Table 1). The contribution of
the three major mungbean-growing districts in 1993-94--all relatively
marginal for cereals--in the total mungbean area in Pakistan was only 3
percent in 1970. This increased to 70 percent in 1992 (Fig. 1). Thus,
lack of modern technologies for pulses made their cultivation unsuitable
in intensive farming systems.
Combining the declining trends in pulse production with the
population explosion in the country, domestic annual pet" capita
production of the legumes decreased from 9.5 kg to 3.4 kg during the
period (Table 1). Prices of pulses jumped as compared to other food
items such as wheat (Fig. 2). This has serious implications for the
supply of protein to the poor population who do not have resources to
buy expensive livestock-based protein-rich food. In a failed attempt to
halt this decline, the government has to spend considerable foreign
exchange on the import of pulses, which has progressively increased from
nil in 1975 [Pakistan (1978)] to 254 thousand tin 1993 [Pakistan
(1995)]. (1)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Supply and demand of a commodity are determined by the policy
environment and consumers' preferences. Very little is known how
these factors affect the pulses production and consumption. The main
objective of this paper is to fill the information gap related to pulses
supply and demand. Understanding these factors will help policy-makers
in formulating appropriate policies and research agenda to boost pulses
production and encourage their consumption in the country. The next
section describes the theoretical framework to estimate the supply and
demand functions for pulses, while Section 3 declineates the empirical
models. Section 4 explains the data sources and Section 5 discusses the
results. The last section summarises the results and suggests the future
policy and research implications.
THEORETICAL MODELS
Supply Response
In general, the production response of a crop is assumed to be a
function of the expected own-price ([P.sup.*.sub.it]), expected prices
of other crops (P.sup.*.sub.jt), input prices ([W.sub.t]), and fixed
factors ([Z.sub.t],) at the time (t) the decision to produce a crop (i)
is made. This can be expressed as follows:
[Y.sup.*.sub.it] = f([P.sup.*.sub.it]., [P.sup.*.sub.jt],
[W.sub.t], [Z.sub.t]., [[alpha].sup.*], [[chi].sup.*] [[gamma].sup.*]
[[tau].sup.*] ... ... ... ... (1)
[Y.sup.*.sub.it], is the desired level of production of the i-th
crop farmers want to produce in response to the expected price regime at
time t; [[alpha].sup.*], [[chi].sup.*], [[gamma].sup.*], [[tau].sup.*]
are the long-term production response of the crop with respect to its
own-price, the prices of other crops, input prices, and fixed factors,
respectively.
Assuming the profit-maximising behaviour of farmers,
[[alpha].sup.*] will be positive, and [[gamma].sup.*] will be negative.
However, [[chi].sup.*] will be positive if the i-th and the j-th crops
are complementary, negative if they are substitute, and zero if
independent. [[tau].sup.*] may be positive or zero depending upon the
role of the fixed factors in production.
Farmers can not fulfil their plan to produce a desired level of
output because of difficulties in making necessary arrangements
instantly. Therefore, Nerlovian adjustment process is used to replace
unobservable values of desired production ([Y.sup.*.sub.t]) with the
observable one ([Y.sub.t]) as follows [Nerlove (1958)]: (2)
[Y.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t-1] = [([Y.sup.*.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t-1]).sup.[beta]]
... ... ... ... ... (2)
where [Y.sub.t-1] is the production of the crop in the preceding
year, and [beta] is the adjustment coefficient. Substituting the values
of [Y.sup.*.sub.t] from Equation (2) into Equation (1), and shifting the
denominator to the right-hand side will give:
[Y.sub.it] = f([Y.sup.1-[beta].sub.i(t-1)], [P.sup.*.sub.it],
[P.sup.*.sub.jt], [W.sub.t], [Z.sub.t], [alpha], [chi], [tau] ... ...
... (3)
The adjustment coefficient ([beta]) can be estimated from the
coefficient of the lagged production variable. It should be noted that
inclusion of [Y.sub.(t-1)] in the right-hand side of the equation has
changed [[alpha].sup.*], [[chi].sup.*], [[gamma].sup.*], [[delta].sup.*]
(the long-term response paramters) to [alpha]=[[alpha].sup.*] (1 -
[beta]), [chi]=[[chi].sup.*] (1 - [beta]), [gamma]= [[gamma].sup.*] (1 -
[beta]), [tau]=[[tau].sup.*] (1 - [beta]) (the short- term response
parameters). The former can be estimated by dividing the latter with one
minus the adjustment coefficient [Nerlove (1958)].
Still Equation (3) is unobservable because it includes the expected
rather than observed output prices. There are many ways to estimate the
expected prices [Pindyck and Rubinfeld (1978)]. This study utilises the
previous year's (or lagged by one year) prices as the expected
prices for this year. Using one year's lag operator on output
prices, Equation (3) can be written as:
[Y.sub.it] = f([Y.sup.1-[beta].sub.i(t-1)], [P.sup.*.sub.i(t-1)],
[P.sup.*.sub.j(t-1)], [W.sub.t], [Z.sub.t], [alpha], [chi], [delta],
[tau]) ... ... ... (4)
All the variables in Equation (4) are now observable. Thus it can
be estimated using normal estimation procedures.
Demand Function
The Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) due to Deaton and Muellbauer
(1980) was applied to estimate the demand function for all food items
including pulses. (3) The specification not only helps to estimate the
own-price, but also cross-price and income elasticities of demand. The
model is specified as follows:
[[omega].sub.i]=[[PSI].sub.i] +
[[summation].sub.j][[eta].sub.ij][lnp.sub.ij] +
[[phi].sub.i]ln(X/[P.sup.*]) + [[upsilon].sub.i] for all i ... ... (5)
where i represents the i-th commodity (i=1,2, ... m), j is the j-th
price in each equation (j=i= 1,2, ... m), [omega] is the expenditure
share defined as expenditure on the i-th commodity divided by the total
expenditure on all food items, p is the commodity price, X is the total
expenditure on all food items, In is the natural logarithm, and
[upsilon] is the error term. The ln[P.sup.*] is defined as:
ln[P.sup.*] = [[PHI].sub.0] +
[[summation].sub.i][[eta].sub.i][lnp.sub.i] + 0.5 [[summation].sub.i]
[[summation].sub.j] [[kappa].sub.i], [lnp.sub.i][lnp.sub.j] ... ... ...
(6)
This leads to non-linearity in parameter of the demand model, and
can be estimated by maximum likelihood (ML). However, as Buse (1994)
noted, the ML estimation is usually avoided in favour of the
computationally attractive linearised model such as the ordinary least
square (OLS) or seemingly unrelated regression (SUR). To convert the
model in (6) into linear in parameters, Deaton and Muellbauer (1980)
suggested to replace [lnp.sup.*] with the stone's geometric price
index as follows.
ln[P.sup.*] = [[summation].sub.i][[omega].sub.i][lnp.sub.i]
The adding up, homogeneity, and symmetry restrictions can be
expressed in terms of the model's coefficient [Moschini and Meilke
(1989)]:
[[summation].sub.i][[PHI].sub.i] = 1,
[[summation].sub.i][[eta].sub.ij] = 0, [[summation].sub.i][[phi].sub.i]
= 0 (adding up) ... ... (7)
[[summation].sub.i][[eta].sub.ij] = 0 (homogeneity) ... ... (8)
[[eta].sub.ij] = [[eta].sub.ji] (symmetry) ... ... (9)
These restrictions can be imposed in the normal way, except the
adding up restriction, which is imposed by deleting one of the equations
and estimating the parameters of the deleted equation through the
residual method.
Under the assumption that the error term [upsilon] in (5) has
multivariate normal distribution, uncorrelated over time, but
contemporaneously correlated such as:
E([[upsilon].sub.it]) = 0
E([[upsilon].sub.it], [[upsilon].sub.jt]) = [[OMEGA].sub.it]
E([[upsilon].sub.it], [[upsilon].sub.jt]) = 0 for t [not equal to]
q,
the parameters in (5) with [DELTA]ln[P.sup.*] as in (6) and
restrictions in (7-9) can be estimated using the Iterated Seemingly
Unrelated Regression (ITSUR) method of the SYSLIN procedure in SAS. The
parameters obtained by ITSUR converage to their maximum likelihood
values if the error term follows a multivariate normal distribution
[Judge et al. (1985)] and they are invariant to the choice of the
deleted equation.
Following Green and Alston (1990), the price and expenditure
elasticities are estimated as follows:
Price elasticities (uncompensated) = [[epsilon].sub.ij] =
-[[delta].sub.ij] + [([[eta].sub.ij])-[[omega].sub.ij]
([phi])]/[[omega].sub.t] for all i and j
Price elasticities (compensated) = [[epsilon].sub.ij.sup.*] =
[[epsilon].sub.ij] + [[omega].sub.j][[epsilon].sub.i]
Expenditure or scale elasticities = [[epsilon].sub.i] = 1 + [phi] /
[[omega].sub.i] ... ... (10)
where [[delta].sub.ij] is the Kronecker data (its value is one for
i-j and zero for i [not equal to] j [Green and Alson (1990)]
[[epsilon].sub.ij] (i.e., own price elasticities) are expected to be
negative. For normal goods, [[epsilon].sub.i] is positive, and negative
for inferior goods. The [[epsilon].sub.ij] (i.e., cross-price
elasticities) may be positive if the two commodities are substitutes,
negative if they are complimentary, and zero if independent. The
statistical significance of the elasticities was tested using the F-test
at the mean values of factor share.
EMPIRICAL MODELS
The following empirical supply model was estimated separately
['or the four major pulses, i.e., mungbean, gram, mash, and lentil,
which is an elaborated form of Equation (4).
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
where [Y.sub.it] is as defined before; [P.sub.m], [P.sub.g],
[P.sub.h], [P.sub.l], [P.sub.w], [P.sub.r], [P.sub.c], [P.sub.s],
[P.sub.a], are, respectively, mungbean, gram, mash, lentil, wheat, rice,
cotton, sugarcane, and maize prices in Rupees per 100 kg; W is wage rate
in Rupees per day; I, C, and T are the fixed factors in pulses supply.
The C is cropping intensity (defined as total cropped area divided by
net sown area) indicating the pressure on land to produce food and raw
materials; I is the proportion of irrigated area in the total cropped
area representing public and private investment on the development of
irrigation infrastructure; T is a trend variable to capture the effect
of relative technological change in pulses, having the values 0, 1,2,
... for 1970, 1971, 1972, ......; D is dummy variable for district
having a value of one for the d-th district and zero otherwise; (4) t
denotes the t-th year; (t-l) is a difference operator indicating the
variable is lagged by one year; e is a random error term assumed to be
randomly and normally distributed; and [Y.sub.0] is the intercept of the
supply equation. The function was estimated in logarithm form by taking
the natural log or all the dependent and independent variables, except
the trend and dummy variables. (5) The Ordinary Least Squares method was
used to estimate Equation (11). Assuming the homogeneity of degree one
(i.e., no change in production if the prices of all outputs and inputs
are changed proportionately), one price variable can be omitted from the
equation, and it can be used to normalise all other prices [Ali (1990)].
We use fertiliser price ([P.sub.t]) to normalise all the output prices
and wage rate.
In the demand analysis, our main interest was to estimate the
demand elasticities of pulses. Therefore, other individual food items
were aggregated into the following ten food groups: (i) wheat; (ii)
gram, (iii) mash, (iv) mungbean, (v) lentil, (vi) milk (fresh and
bioled, milk packed, dry and condensed, butter, ghee, yougart, all
converted into liquid milk equivalent), (vii) meat (mutton, beef, fish
fresh, and chicken), (viii) fruit (citrus fruits, mango, apple, melon,
and grapes), (ix) vegetables (tomato, onion, and other vegetables), and
(x) other cereals (rice and potato). The Equation (5) was elaborated for
all the food groups, expect for "other cereals", which was
deleted for estimation purposes, but its parameters were recovered by
invoking the adding-up restriction.
DATA
In the supply-response analysis, district-level data on production
and harvest prices of the major pulses, harvest prices of major crops
(wheat, rice, cotton, sugarcane, and maize), wage rate, fertiliser
prices, proportion of irrigated area, and total cropped area in Punjab
(6) for 1970-93 were used. Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan [Pakistan
(1975), (1978), (1980), (1982), (1984), (1987), (1990), (1993) issues]
and Punjab Agricultural Statistics [Agricultural Department of Punjab
(1977), (1977a), (1978), (1982), (1983), (1991) issues] regularly
publish district-level area under major crops. The harvest prices of
agricultural commodities until 1980 are also published in the latter
source. The prices for 1980-93 were obtained from the official files of
Crop Reporting Services, Directorate of Agriculture, Lahore. Where
district-level prices were missing, these were taken from a neighbouring
district. Fertiliser prices at the retail-level were obtained from the
Economic Survey of Pakistan [Pakistan (1994)]. District-wise cropped and
irrigated areas were taken from the Punjab Agricultural Statistics, and
in case missing, these were obtained from the official files of Crop
Reporting Services, Directorate of Agriculture, Lahore. Wage rate was
obtained from the Wage Census Reports published by the Land Record
office in Lahore for 1966, 1973, 1978, and 1988 [West Pakistan (1969);
Punjab (1978); Punjab (1987); Punjab (1993)]. The wage rate for the
in-between years was extrapolated using a constant growth rate between
the census years [see Ali (1996) for more details on how these data
series were assembled and generated].
To estimate the demand function as specified in Equation (5), one
needs prices and expenditure share on various consumption items.
Household income and expenditure surveys, known as HIES for short,
report consumption and expenditure on different food items by income,
province, and rural and urban group. The HIES data for 1986-87, 1987-88,
and 1988-89 [Pakistan (undated); Pakistan (1987); (1988a)] were used in
this analysis. The latest household survey (changed from Household
Income and Expenditure Survey to Integrated Economic Survey) did not
publish data on consumption by province and rural and urban group
[Pakistan (1993)], and were thus excluded from the analysis. The prices
of different food items were estimated by dividing expenditure with the
respective consumption quantities.
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
Pulses Supply
The exercise to estimate the supply response aims to understand the
role of input and output prices, investment on irrigation
infrastructure, technology generation, and population pressure in the
production of pulses in Pakistan.
The estimated supply response model explained a 84-93 percent
variation in the production of different pulses, as indicated by the
value of [R.sup.2]. The F-values ranged from 72-177; each is significant
at the 1 percent level. The Durbon-Watson statistics is around two,
indicating no serious auto-correlation problem. The lag coefficients, as
expected, are positive in all cases, and highly significant (Table 2).
This implies that farmers failed to achieve their desired production in
the same year because of the structural problems.
The short-term own-price supply elasticities of mungbean and lentil
are positive and significant at least at the 15 percent level. Grain and
mash productions are not responsive to their own respective prices,
perhaps because of the subsistence nature of these crops. The respective
values of the own-price supply elasticities of mungbean and lentil are
0.223 and 0.138. Singh and Singh (1988) estimated the supply elasticity
of mungbean in India (probably in the medium-term) as 0.5.
Pulses production, especially of mungbean, is affected by other
crop prices. The important competing crop for mungbean is mash. A 1
percent increase in price of the former will decrease the production of
the latter by 0.4 percent in the short term. This is because both crops
are grown in the same season [Ahmad et al. (1993)], and regional
distribution of these crops overlapped on a good proportion of the area.
Maize, cotton, gram, and lentil are complementary crops to mungbean. In
the case of maize, the use of spring mungbean as a catch crop in between
maize-wheat rotation can explain this relationship. In the case of
cotton, mungbean cultivation after its harvest, when farmers get
lucrative cotton prices which induce them for an extra picking and
discourage wheat cultivation [Byerlee et al. (1987)], explains this
relationship.
The productions of lentil and gram are also complementary with
mungbean, probably because both the crops are grown in different seasons
(i.e., lentil in September-March, gram in December-May, and mungbean
mainly in July-September), and some farmers might be growing them in
sequence. So a good harvest from gram and lentil could provide the cash
necessary to arrange the inputs for the mungbean crop. Mungbean
production seems to be independent of the prices of wheat, rice, and
sugarcane.
Lentil competes with cotton and mungbean, mainly because of their
overlapping growing season. High mungbean prices discourage lentil, as
mungbean can delay lentil cultivation if grown on the same piece of
land. (It should be noted that high prices of lentil encourage mungbean
production, as enough time is available to prepare mungbean field after
the harvest of lentil crop). Lentil production is independent of the
prices of wheat, rice, sugarcane, maize, gram, and mash.
Gram production competes with wheat and mash, because of their
overlapping period. Similarly, mash and sugarcane are competing crops.
Gram is complementary with mungbean as explained earlier.
Mungbean and lentil productions are negatively affected by the
increasing wage rate, as these crops need high labour input, especially
in harvesting their pods, which occurs 3-4 times in case of traditional
varieties as these do not mature uniformly. Moreover, the demand for
harvesting labour in these pulses may compete with the planting labour
of cash crops such as rice and cotton. A 1 percent increase in the wage
rate would reduce their production by about 0.3 percent in each case.
The effect of cropping intensity on production is negative in all
pulses, except in gram, although insignificant in the cases of mungbean
and mash. This implies that pulses are mainly concentrated in areas with
low cropping intensities. Although gram is concentrated in more
intensive areas, this does not imply that it is a preferred crop in the
intensified cropping regions. Actually, it is used as a fall-back crop,
i.e., cultivated when the main wheat crop is not successful both in
terms of productivity and return. Its association with wheat as an
inter-crop also explains this result.
The coefficient for the proportion of irrigated area is
insignificant in all cases. This implies that pulses production has not
benefitted from the public and private investment on irrigation
infrastructure. The trend coefficient is positive and significant only
in mungbean, and its production increased at the rate of 1.2 percent
during 1970-93 after controlling the effect of relative prices. The
production declined in gram, mash, and lentil, although the trend was
not statistically significant in the case of mash.
The long-term elasticities are derived from the short-term
elasticities of production (Table 3) in case the latter are significant
at the 15 percent level. Although the short-term elasticities of
mungbean supply are small, its long-term elasticities are more than 1.0.
The own-price long-term supply elasticity of mungbean is comparable to
those of rice and cotton (commercial crops) at 1.9 and 1.3, respectively
[Ali (1990)]. The big difference in the short- and long-term
elasticities is an indication of the difficulties in adjusting mungbean
production in response to its prices in the short-term, as limited area
is available for its cultivation and it is mainly concentrated in the
mungbean-growing region on the fallow land alter wheat, while its
expansion in new areas competes with cereals and other cash crops. Mash
and wheat productions pose even stronger competition for gram in the
long term. The elasticities of mungbean and lentil production with
respect to the wage rate are relatively high in the long term.
Pulses Demand
Pulses are consumed as daal cooked separately or, sometime, with
other pulses, meat, and egg. Daal is a base food eaten with chapati prepared from wheat flour. Sometimes they are used in snacks called
haleem and pakora, and also in sweets. But the use of pulses as a
vegetable, in the form of sprouts, is unknown. Very little is known
about consumers' relative preference for pulses in the food basket.
To fill this knowledge gap, the own- and cross-price demand and income
elasticities are estimated, and the results are discussed in the
following section.
Compensated and uncompensated demand elasticities are very similar
to each other (Tables 4 and 5), although the latter is slightly higher
than the former. Therefore, only uncompensated elasticities are
discussed below.
Individual pulses have higher own-price demand elasticity than
wheat, a staple food in Pakistan. For example, a 1 percent increase in
gram, mash, mungbean, and lentil prices will decrease their consumption
by 0.74 percent, 0.73 percent, 0.67 percent, and 0.83 percent,
respectively, while the own-price elasticity of wheat is only 0.27
percent. The high own-price demand elasticity of pulses is comparable
with other high-quality food items such as milk, meat, and other cereals
(mainly rice), where a 1 percent increase would bring a decrease in
their consumption by 0.94 percent, 0.76 percent, and 0.61 percent,
respectively. However, fruit and vegetables have relatively low
own-price elasticities of demand than meat, milk, and pulses, but they
have higher elasticities than wheat (Table 4).
The own-price demand elasticities of pulses estimated in this
analysis are comparable with those in other countries in the region. For
example, Singh and Singh (1988) estimated the elasticity of pulses in
India as -1.0 for the low-income group, and -0.2 for the high-income
group.
Mungbean is a complementary food with mash, because as mash
consumption decreases with the increases in its price, so does the
consumption of mungbean. However, it is a substitute for lentil, milk,
and fruit, because as the consumption of these items decreases with the
increase in their respective prices, the consumption of mungbean
increases. The mungbean and other pulses are independent (of wheat and
other cereals) food items, except gram, which is a substitute for wheat
(Table 4). These results partly contradict those reported by Chopra and
Swami (1988), who report pulses as strong substitutes for cereals.
Lentil is a substitute and mash is complementary with vegetables, and
gram is complementary with meat. Mungbean, mash, and lentil consumption
are insensitive to the changes in the prices of gram and meat, as
cross-price elasticities with respect to these food items are
insignificant.
Pulses are believed to be inferior commodities, such that their
consumption is expected to decline with an increase in income. Contrary
to this belief, our estimate gave positive income elasticities for all
individual pulses (Table 6). Mungbean turned out to be a less preferred
pulse, as its income elasticity is the lowest. However, the elasticity
is non-negative. Therefore, we reject the hypothesis that pulses
including mungbean are the inferior good as defined in economic jargon.
The income elasticities of other food items are as expected and
comparable with other studies [Alderman (1988)].
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The neglect of food legumes by policy-makers caused a serious
decline in their availability on the one hand, and created a knowledge
gap on the other. For example, the supply and demand elasticities, which
are so critical in understanding the production and consumption
patterns, making plans, and analysing the impact of technological
change, are rarely available for all pulses in general, and for
individual pulses in particular. The current analysis fills this
information gap.
The general perception is that pulses are subsistence crops, and
they do not respond to the changes in the policy environment, especially
relative prices. This may actually be an effect of the neglect of pulses
by policy-makers. For example, the introduction of technological
innovations in the art of their cultivation [Ali et al. (1996)] has made
them a commercial crop, and farmers have started weighing their
profitability with other crops rather than just meeting the family
requirements irrespective of the market demand. Their short-term
own-price demand elasticity is comparable with wheat, while long-term
elasticity matches with other commercial crops, such as rice and cotton,
in the country.
Pulses production is mainly concentrated in areas with low cropping
intensity. This suggests that their production is normally pushed to low
fertile lands, which are marginal to main cereal and cash crop
production. The negative effect of cropping intensity on the supply of
pulses also reflects farmers' low preference for using pulses in
averting the pressure to produce more food and raw materials from land.
Pulses production has not benefitted from the public and private
investment in irrigation infrastructure, as unlike cereals,
water-responsive pulses varieties are not available. Similarly, the
negative trend coefficient, except in mungbean, reflects a paucity of
research innovations in pulses in general. The positive trend in
mungbean production is mainly due to the belated Green Revolution
process begun during the mid 1980s.
Increasing wage rate negatively affects mungbean and lentil
production. Therefore, varieties with synchronised maturity which can
significantly reduce the harvesting labour demand, as well as mechanical
technologies, will help to boost the production of these pulses.
Pulses generally have high demand elasticity, and low but positive
income elasticities. This is contrary to what is believed--that pulses
are inferior food items, and their consumption declines as income
increases. The decline in food legume consumption during the 1970s and
1980s, therefore, can be attributed to disproportional increase in
pulses prices combined with high demand elasticity, rather than due to
income increase. Actually, income and population increase will continue
to put demand pressure on pulses in the future. Unless this pressure is
relieved by creating additional supplies, it will simply push pulses
prices up, reduce consumption, and thus create more imbalance in diet,
especially of the poor people. High-yielding, short-duration, and
pest-resistant pulses varieties having synchronised maturity and
mechanical technologies for their production will greatly benefit
consumers and producers, as well as bring long-term sustainability to
the production system.
REFERENCES
Agricultural Department of Punjab (1977) Punjab Agricultural
Statistics. 1972-73. 1973-74, and 1974-75. Lahore: United Printers.
Agricultural Department of Punjab (1977a) Punjab Agricultural
Statistics. 1975-76. Lahore: United Printers.
Agricultural Department of Punjab (1978) Punjab Agricultural
Statistics, 1976-77. Lahore: United Printers.
Agricultural Department of Punjab (1983) Punjab Agricultural
Statistics. 1977-80. Vols. I & II. Lahore: Youth Printers.
Agricultural Department of Punjab (1991) Punjab Agricultural
Statistics, 1980-81 to 1989-90. Lahore: Directorate of Agriculture Crop
Reporting Services.
Ahmed, B., Z. Hussain, and J. Longmire (1993) Farm Management
Handbook, Economics and Policy Analysis Project (Chemonics International
Consulting Division), Agricultural Services Sector Project (ASSP) and
United States Agency for International Development (USAID), Islamabad.
Alderman, H. (1988) Estimates of Consumer Price Response in
Pakistan Using Market Prices as Data. The Pakistan Development Review
17:2 89-107.
Ali, M. (1990) The Price Response of Major Crops in Pakistan: An
Application of the Simultaneous Equation Model. The Pakistan Development
Review 29:3&4 305-325.
Ali, M. (1996) Total Factor Productivity Dam Set: Definition,
Source, and Transformation. AVRDC, Tainan, Taiwan.
Ali, M., H. M. Sabir, B. Ahmed, and I. A. Malik (1997) Green
Revolution in Mungbean for Sustainability and Human Nutrition:
Understanding the Interface of Technology, Farmers, and Environment in
Pakistan. AVRDC Technical Paper (in press).
Batten, A. P. (1969) Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Complete
System of Demand Equation. European Economic Review 1: 7-73.
Buse, A. (1994) Evaluating the Linearised Almost Ideal Demand
System. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76:781-793.
Byerlee, D., M. R. Akhtar, and P. R. Hobbs (1987) Reconciling
Conflicts in Sequential Cropping Patterns Through Plant Breeding: The
Example of Cotton and Wheat in Pakistan's Punjab. Agriculture
System 24:291-304.
Chopra, K., and G. Swami (1988) Pulses: An Analysis of Demand and
Supply in India 1951-71. New Delhi: Sterling Publishers.
Christensen, L. R., D. W. Jorgenson, and L. J. Lau (1975)
Transcedental Logrithmic Utility Functions. American Journal of Economic
Review 65: 367-83.
Deaton, A., and J. Muellbauer (1980) An Almost Ideal Demand System.
The American Economic Review 70:3 312-326.
Green, R., and J. M. Alston (1990) Elasticities ill AIDS Models.
America, Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 442-445.
Judge, G. C., W. E. Griffiths, R. C. Hill, H. Lutkepohl, and T. C.
Lee (1985) The Theory and Practice of Econometrics, 2nd Edition. New
York: John Wiley & Sons.
Koutsoyiannis, A. (1977) Theory of Econometrics, 2nd Edition.
London: Macmillan.
Moschini, G., and K. D. Meilke (1989) Modelling the Pattern of
Structural Change in U. S. Meat Demand. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 71: 253-261.
Nerlove, M. (1958) Distributed Lag and Estimation of Long-run
Supply and Demand Elasticities: Theoretical Consideration. Journal of
Farm Economics 40: 301-310.
Pakistan, Government of (1973) 25 Years of Pakistan in Statistics,
1947-72. Karachi: Central Statistical Office, Economic Affairs Division,
Ministry of Finance, Planning and Development.
Pakistan, Government of (1975) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1975. Vol. II. District-wise Area and Production of Important Crops.
Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Under
Developed Areas and Land Reforms, Agriculture Wing (Planning Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1978) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1977. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Food
and Agriculture Division (Planing Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1980) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1979. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Food
and Agriculture Division (Planning Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1982) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1981. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Food
and Agriculture Division (Planning Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1983) 10 Years of Pakistan in Statistics.
Karachi: Central Statistical Office, Economic Affair Division, Ministry
of Finance, Planning and Development.
Pakistan, Government of (1984) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1983. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Food
and Agriculture Division (Planning Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1987) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1986. Vol. II, District-wise Area and Production of Important Crops.
Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Food and
Agriculture Division (Planning Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1988) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1987-88. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Cooperatives, Food
and Agriculture Division (Planning Unit).
Pakistan, Government of (1988a) Household Income and Expenditure
Survey, 1985-86. Karachi: Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics
Division.
Pakistan, Government of (1989) Household Income and Expenditure
Survey, 1986-87. Karachi: Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics
Division.
Pakistan, Government of (1990) Crop Area and Production (By
District), 1986-87 to 1988-89. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture
and Cooperatives, Food and Agriculture Division, Economic Wing.
Pakistan, Government of (1993) Crop Area and Production (By
District), 1989-90 to 1991-92. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture
and Cooperatives, Food and Agriculture Division, Economic Wing.
Pakistan, Government of (1993a) Household Integrated Economic
Survey. 1990-91. Karachi: Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics
Division.
Pakistan, Government of (1994) Economic Survey 1993-94. Karachi:
Finance Division, Economic Advisor's Wing.
Pakistan, Government of (1995) Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan
1993-94, Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Livestock, Food
and Agriculture Division, Economic Wing.
Pakistan, Government of (1995a) Pakistan Statistical Year Book
1994. Federal Bureau of Statistics, Economic and Statistics Division.
Pakistan, Government of (undated) Household Income and Expenditure
Survey, 1986-87. Karachi: Federal Bureau of Statistics, Statistics
Division.
Pindyck, R. S., and D. Rubinfeld (1978) Econometric Models and
Economic Forecasts, Second Edition. New York: McGraw Hill Inc.
Punjab, Government of (1978) Report on the Eleventh Regular Wage
Survey of the Punjab Taken in June 1973. Lahore: Government Printing
Press.
Punjab, Government of (1987) Report on the Twelfth Regular Wage
Survey of the Punjab taken in June 1978. Lahore: Government Printing
Press.
Punjab, Government of (1993) Report on the Fourteenth Regular Wage
Survey of the Punjab Taken in December 1988. Lahore: Government Printing
Press.
Singh, R. K., and R. I. Singh (1988) Recent Trends in Marketing
Mungbean in Uttar Pradesh, India. In Mungbean: Proceedings of the Second
International Symposium. AVRDC, Tainan, Taiwan, 463-469.
Swamy, G., and H. P. Binswanger (1983) Flexible Consumer Demand
Systems and Linear Estimation: Food in India. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 675-684.
West Pakistan, Government of (1969) Report on the Tergh Regular
Wage Survey of the West Pakistan (Northern Zone) Taken in December 1966.
Peshawar: West Pakistan Government Press.
(1) Similar trends were observed in other countries where the Green
Revolution in cereals was pushed hard. For example, in India which is
one of the major pulses-producing countries in the world. total pulses
area declined from 23.6 million ha in 1960 to 22.4 million ha in 1993.
and the share of pulses in total food grain area dropped from 20 percent
to 18 percent: total production remained stagnant around 12-13 million t
but daily per capita availability declined from 65.5 gram to 37.0 gram
in the corresponding period [India (1994)]. The increase in pulses
prices was 40 percent higher than in cereal prices just during 1982-93
[India (1995)].
(2) The Nerlovian partial adjustment model assumes a rigid rather
than a rational price expectation behaviour without incorporating any
explicit cost of adjustment. Despite these problems, the assumption in
the model keeps the error term free of the autoregressive scheme, and
thus can be applied without prior worry about the autocorrelation problem in the lagged model, However, if such a problem is detected by
the d statistics, special estimation techniques can be applied. The
model is widely used in empirical research because of its ease in
application and interpretation of the results [Koutsoyiannis (1977)].
(3) Numerous algebraic specifications of the demand system are
available, including the linear expenditure and quadratic expenditure
systems [Swamy and Binswanger (1983)]. the working and translog models
[Christensen, Jorgenson, and Lau (1975)], the Rotterdam and Almost Ideal
Demand Systems (AIDS) [Deaton and Muellbauer (1980)]. The last two
models are more widely used to characterise the consumers demand
behaviour.
(4) The district boundaries in the data were maintained as they
existed in 1965. So the data for a new district were added in the old
district from where the new district was created [Ali (1996)]. We had 19
districts in Punjab. To avoid complete collinearity between districts
and intercept, only 18 district dummy variables can be included in the
equation.
(5) The log-linear form of supply response was selected because of
its ease in estimation and in explaining the coefficient, as estimated
coefficients directly give elasticities.
(6) We restrict our analysis for only Punjab province because more
than 75 percent of the total pulses in the country are produced in this
province [Pakistan (1995)]. Moreover, district-level output prices are
available only for Punjab.
Mubarik Ali is Agricultural Economist, Asian Vegetable Research and
Development Centre, Taiwan. Abedullah is Consultant, Social Sciences,
International Rice Research Institute, Manila.
Table 1
Area (000 ha), Production (000t), Average Yield (kg/ha) and
Availability (kg/capita) of Pulses, and Wheat Yield (kg/ha)
in Pakistan, 1973-1993.
Pulses
Year Area Production Yield
1973 1626.8 836.3 514
1974 1376.9 715.6 520
1975 1476.5 783.7 531
1976 1533.3 843.5 550
1977 1544.7 811.6 525
1978 1676.6 735.8 439
1979 1550.9 512.2 330
1980 1252.5 525.5 419
1981 1321.1 488.2 369
1982 1335.4 693.7 520
1983 1306.7 709.9 543
1984 1415.3 725.5 513
1985 11451.5 796.7 549
1986 11521.6 790.9 520
1987 1222.3 556.1 455
1988 1394.9 641.8 460
1989 11496.4 768.5 514
1990 11538.2 732.1 476
1991 11420.4 706.2 497
1992 11453.1 547.1 377
1993 11480.9 614.0 415
Pulses
Year Availability Wheat Yield
1973 9.2 1248
1974 7.6 1320
1975 8.0 1422
1976 8.4 1431
1977 7.9 1316
1978 7.0 1488
1979 4.9 1568
1980 4.8 1643
1981 4.4 1565
1982 5.9 1678
1983 5.8 1482
1984 5.7 1612
1985 6.1 1881
1986 5.9 1559
1987 4.1 1734
1988 4.5 1865
1989 5.2 1825
1990 4.8 1841
1991 4.5 1990
1992 3.5 1946
1993 3.8 1893
Source: Pakistan (1975 and 1982) issues.
Per capita availability was estimated by subtracting 31 percent of
the production in the case of gram, and 10 percent in the case of
other pulses as seed requirement.
Table 2
Supply Response Parameters of Major Pulses in Pakistan, 1970-73
Mungbean Grain
Parameter Standard Parameter Standard
Variable Estimate Error Estimate Error
[P.sub.m(t-1)] 0.223 * 0.179 0.205 * 0.125
[P.sub.g(t-1)] 0.262 *** 0.124 -0.081 0.091
[P.sub.h(t-1)] -0.387 *** 0.186 -0.601 **** 0.135
[P.sub.l(t-1)] 0.228 *** 0.105 0.018 0.075
[P.sub.w(t-1)] -0.422 0.351 -0.435 ** 0.251
[P.sub.r(t-1)] -0.002 0.014 0.013 * 0.013
[P.sub.c(t-1)] 0.041 *** 0.015 0.014 * 0.012
[P.sub.s(t-1)] -0.016 0.203 0.017 0.145
[P.sub.a(t-1)] 0.278 0.195 0.092 0.140
[W.sub.t] -0.311 ** 0.232 0.005 0.166
[I.sub.t] 0.057 0.392 -0.116 0.283
[C.sub.t] -0.013 0.163 0.193 * 0.118
[Y.sub.(t-1)] 0.785 **** 0.030 0.731 **** 0.036
T 0.012 * 0.010 -0.027 **** 0.008
[R.sup.2] 0.91 -- 0.93 --
F 124 **** -- 177 **** --
DW 2.29 -- 2.003 --
Mash Lentil
Parameter Standard Parameter Standard
Variable Estimate Error Estimate Error
[P.sub.m(t-1)] -0.103 0.211 -0.217 *** 0.095
[P.sub.g(t-1)] 0.150 0.147 0.096 0.068
[P.sub.h(t-1)] 0.040 0.082 0.094 0.105
[P.sub.l(t-1)] 0.108 0.124 0.138 *** 0.057
[P.sub.w(t-1)] 0.184 0.412 -0.074 0.190
[P.sub.r(t-1)] 0.016 0.021 0.009 0.009
[P.sub.c(t-1)] 0.020 0.019 -0.043 0.009
[P.sub.s(t-1)] -0.530 *** 0.239 0.102 0.110
[P.sub.a(t-1)] -0.179 0.229 0.068 0.106
[W.sub.t] 0.027 0.270 0.286 *** 0.125
[I.sub.t] 0.376 0.462 0.274 0.214
[C.sub.t] -0.015 0.194 -0.140 * 0.090
[Y.sub.(t-1)] 0.604 *** 0.041 0.595 **** 0.037
T 0.005 0.013 -0.028 **** 0.006
[R.sup.2] 0.84 -- 0.91 --
F 72 **** -- 134 **** --
DW 2.19 -- 1.78 --
Notes: (1.) The estimated parameters for prices and fixed factors
are short-term elasticities.
(2.) The coefficients for district dummies and intercept are not
reported here, because they are not relevant to the discussion.
(3.) The coefficient for fertiliser price can be estimated as the
sum of all price elasticities.
****, ***, **, and * imply that the coefficient are significants
at the 1 percent, 5 percent, 10 percent, and 15 percent level,
respectively.
Table 3
Long-term Supply Elasticities of Major Pulses in Pakistan, 1970-93
Independent Variable Mungbean Gram Mash Lentil
[P.sub.m(t-1)] 1.178 0.77 -- -0.537
[P.sub.g(t-1)] 1.215 -- -- 0.237
[P.sub.h(t-1)] -1.812 -2.241 -- --
[P.sub.l(t-1)] 1.055 -- -- 0.340
[P.sub.w(t-1)] -- -1.617 -- --
[P.sub.c(t-1)] 0.197 0.057 -- -0.106
[P.sub.s(t-1)] -- -- -1.338 --
[P.sub.a(t-1)] 1.287 -- -- --
[W.sub.t] -1.449 -- -- -0.706
[I.sub.t] -- -- -- 0.675
[C.sub.t] -- 0.715 -- -0.355
T 0.056 -0.100 -- -0.070
Table 4
Price Elasticities of Demand (Uncompensated) of Different Food
Items in Pakistan, 1984-86
Food Item
Price Wheat Mungbean Gram
[P.sub.w] -0.265 **** -0.183 0.742 ****
[P.sub.m] -0.012 -0.689 **** -0.058
[P.sub.g] 0.057 **** -0.097 -0.743 ****
[P.sub.h] 0.010 -0.104 *** -0.027
[P.sub.l] 0.004 0.197 **** -0.003
[P.sub.k] -0.060 0.520 **** 0.017
[P.sub.t] -0.253 **** -0.048 -0.475 ****
[P.sub.f] -0.137 **** 0.234 *** -0.069
[P.sub.v] 0.101 **** -0.159 0.283 ***
[P.sub.o] 0.025 0.088 -0.149
Food Item
Price Mash Lentil Milk
[P.sub.w] 0.272 0.108 -0.245 ****
[P.sub.m] -0.132 **** 0.194 **** 0.010
[P.sub.g] -0.062 -0.005 -0.015 **
[P.sub.h] -0.728 **** -0.119 **** -0.001
[P.sub.l] -0.150 **** -0.821 **** 0.002
[P.sub.k] 0.150 0.291 -0.943 ****
[P.sub.t] -0.264 -0.484 0.123 ***
[P.sub.f] 0.121 -0.153 0.071 ****
[P.sub.v] -0.274 ** 0.450 *** -0.039
[P.sub.o] 0.467 0.099 -0.220
Food Item
Price Meat Fruit
[P.sub.w] -0.618 **** -1.093 ****
[P.sub.m] -0.017 0.043 *
[P.sub.g] -0.075 **** -0.056 **
[P.sub.h] -0.022 ** 0.015
[P.sub.l] -0.044 *** -0.054 ***
[P.sub.k] 0.152 ** 0.312 ****
[P.sub.t] -0.763 **** -0.007
[P.sub.f] 0.010 -0.349 ****
[P.sub.v] -0.271 **** -0.422 ****
[P.sub.o] 0.216 -0.092
Food Item
Price Vegetables O.Cereal
[P.sub.w] 0.192 *** -0.021
[P.sub.m] -0.025 0.004
[P.sub.g] 0.051 *** -0.044
[P.sub.h] -0.028 ** 0.049
[P.sub.l] 0.048 *** 0.008
[P.sub.k] 0.017 -0.627
[P.sub.t] -0.362 **** 0.529
[P.sub.f] 0.152 **** -0.013
[P.sub.v] -0.412 **** -0.171
[P.sub.o] -0.139 -0.614
****, ***, **, * imply mat me etastrctttes are srgntncant at the
1 percent, 5 percent, 10 percent, and 15 percent levels at the
mean level of budget shares. The elasticities for other cereals
are estimated by invoking the adding up restriction, thus not
statistically tested. [P.sub.w], [P.sub.g], [P.sub.h], [P.sub.m]
and [P.sub.l] are as defined in Equation (5), and [P.sub.k],
[P.sub.t], [P.sub.f], [P.sub.v], [P.sub.o] respectively the
prices of milk, meat, fruit, vegetables, and other cereals.
Table 5
Compensated Demand Elasticities
Food Item
Price Wheat Mungbean Gram Mash
[P.sub.w] -0.127 -0.120 0.868 0.429
[P.sub.m] -0.005 -0.686 -0.053 -0.125
[P.sub.g] 0.068 -0.093 -0.733 -0.050
[P.sub.h] 0.015 -0.102 -0.033 -0.723
[P.sub.l] 0.010 0.200 0.002 -0.143
[P.sub.k] 0.090 0.588 0.153 0.320
[P.sub.t] -0.162 -0.007 -0.391 -0.160
[P.sub.f] -0.113 0.245 -0.047 0.148
[P.sub.v] 0.154 -0.135 0.331 -0.214
[P.sub.o] 0.070 0.109 -0.108 0.518
Food Item
Price Lentil Milk Meat
[P.sub.w] 0.223 0.083 -0.244
[P.sub.m] 0.199 0.024 0.000
[P.sub.g] 0.004 0.011 -0.046
[P.sub.h] -0.115 0.011 -0.009
[P.sub.l] -0.816 0.017 -0.028
[P.sub.k] 0.415 -0.588 0.557
[P.sub.t] -0.408 0.340 -0.515
[P.sub.f] -0.133 0.138 0.076
[P.sub.v] 0.494 0.087 -0.128
[P.sub.o] 0.137 -0.113 0.338
Food Item
Price Fruit Vegetables O.Cereal
[P.sub.w] -0.648 0.403 0.214
[P.sub.m] 0.063 -0.016 0.015
[P.sub.g] -0.031 0.068 -0.026
[P.sub.h] 0.031 -0.020 0.057
[P.sub.l] -0.034 0.058 0.019
[P.sub.k] 0.793 0.246 -0.373
[P.sub.t] 0.287 -0.322 0.684
[P.sub.f] -0.372 -0.115 0.028
[P.sub.v] -0.251 -0.332 -0.081
[P.sub.o] 0.053 -0.070 -0.537
Table 6
Income Elasticities of Demand of Different Food Items in
Pakistan, 1984-86
Food Item Elasticity
Wheat 0.530 ****
Mungbean 0.241 ****
Gram 0.483 ****
Mash 0.601 ****
Lentil 0.440 ****
Milk 1.28 ****
Meat 1.433 ****
Fruit 1.705 ****
Vegetables 0.809 ****
Other Cereal 0.900 ****