A simulation analysis of the debt problem in Pakistan.
Ahmad, Eatzaz ; Ahmed, Ayaz
This paper analyses past trends in resource deficits and develops a
simulation model to forecast future trends in internal and external
resource gaps, borrowing needs, and debt accumulation. The results show
that if the past trends continue, the debt situation, especially the
need for external borrowing, will become more severe in the future. The
paper suggests a broadly based policy mix, which not only has
significant favourable effects on the budget position, external balance,
borrowings and debts, but also raises the growth rate of GDP, improves
foreign exchange reserves position, controls inflation, and stabilises
the exchange rate of the Pakistani rupee.
1. INTRODUCTION
The current debt situation in Pakistan and the resulting financial
crisis require serious attempts to find a sustainable indigenous
solution. As such it is essential to search ways and means to reduce
dependence on external borrowing over medium to long run. (1) External
debt is usually created to sustain a growth rate of the economy, which
is otherwise not feasible with the given state of domestic resources,
technology, consumption propensity and economic management practices.
However, the success of economic growth financed by external borrowing
depends on two factors, namely the domestic saving rate and
productivity.
A country with lower saving rate needs to borrow more to finance a
given rate of economic growth. In Pakistan the flow of external loans is
likely to have adversely affected the compulsion for savings. For
example, no serious attempts have been made to improve tax collection or
to control non-development government expenditure unless forced by the
donor agencies. The adverse effect of borrowing on savings has recently
been observed in [Ali et al. (1997)]. The evidence also does not support
the proposition that higher rate of economic growth results in higher
saving rate [see Ali et al. (1997)]. The saving rate in the private
sector of Pakistan has remained low because of low real interest rates
and the lack of legitimate and safe investment opportunities.
Furthermore the poor and middle-income classes have been burdened with
high inflation tax and no serious efforts have been made to tax the
rich. Saving rate in the government sector has been deteriorating due to
exponential growth in the size of this sector and extraordinarily low
productivity. Government has ventured in the territories where it had no
business in the first place. The current rate of savings in Pakistan is
stubbornly as low as it was many years ago. Thus the failure to increase
the national saving rate alone explains why the need for external
borrowing has continued to rise over the years in Pakistan.
A decline in productivity is something extra-ordinary because all
the on-going innovations in technology are meant to improve
productivity. New technologies that are inferior to the existing
technologies quickly disappear from the scene. Nevertheless a recent
study by Ahmad and Idress (1998) shows that total factor productivity in
the manufacturing sector has declined by about one percent over the
period 1971-91. This loss in productivity can most plausibly be
explained by inefficiency in the economy, especially in the public
sector.
In the light of above background this study aims to suggest a
policy prescription that can provide a sustainable solution to the
present debt crises. The analysis is based on a three-gap model of
resource flows. The model is stock-flow consistent as it considers both
the current and capital accounts of the transactions taking place across
the private and public sectors and the rest of the world.
A similar model has recently been used in Ahmad (1997) to study the
effects of various fiscal measures on the debt position and in Ahmad
(1996) to discuss the role of foreign capital inflows in reducing the
size of debt. The present study considers a broader policy prescription
that includes both the fiscal and monetary instruments. (2)
The paper is planned as follows. Section 2 provides a historic
overview of the resource deficiency in Pakistan. A three-gap simulation
model is presented in Section 3. Section 4 provides statistical
simulations for various indicators of resource deficiency over the next
two decades and studies the effectiveness of a policy prescription in
addressing the problem.
2. TRENDS IN RESOURCE DEFICIT, BORROWING, AND DEBT
When Pakistan resorted to external borrowing in 1950s and 1960s,
the objective was to accelerate growth rate of the economy. Since the
domestic saving rate was too low to finance economic growth through
productive investment, Pakistan opted for external borrowing. The idea
was that the increased growth rate in future would raise the saving rate
and produce sufficient exportable surplus to retire the debt. However,
presently we need to borrow in order to avoid debt default and improve
our credit rating so that we can maintain the supply line of borrowing.
The danger is that if the supply lines are cut-off, Pakistan's
economy will collapse.
At least in one respect the growth strategy of 1960s was successful
in the sense that resources generated through external borrowings
resulted in high rate of economic growth. If the same pace of growth
were sustained, the adverse trend in debt accumulation might have
reversed at some stage. The situation in 1970s was still manageable
despite a reduction in growth rate of the economy, mainly because the
size of external debt was small and the terms and conditions for
external borrowing were favourable. In 1980s the American aid to assist
in the Afghan war helped postpone the crisis. During this period,
however, the composition of external debt changed gradually from long
term debt to short term debt with higher rates of interest.
By the time American aid was dried up, Pakistan had accumulated
sufficient amount of external debt to worry about. The successive
governments not only opted to postpone the burden by rolling-over the
existing debt but also magnified the problem by indulging in unrealistic
adventures and ignoring the core issue of management. As a result most
of the efforts of economic policy makers and civil servants have been
diverted to negotiating bigger and bigger loan agreements with the
donors, and trying to meet the targets imposed by the donor agencies.
Not only did we fail to design a sustainable development strategy, but
we also managed to waste the highly specialised human resource on
misdirected objectives.
In the past two decades or so the debt position has worsened very
rapidly. This is evident from the trends in various indicators as shown
in Table 1. The table shows that the primary budget deficit has
increased by almost 13 percent per annum over the period 1980-81 to
1996-97. Thus even if debt servicing is ignored, the government's
budget position has deteriorated over the years. The surplus in the
private sector has also worsened quite significantly to the extent that
in the recent years it has almost vanished. While primary budget deficit
has grown due to expansion in the size of public sector, the observed
deterioration in the private sector's surplus can be attributed to
rising consumption propensity and over-invoicing of investment
expenditure to camouflage consumption loans. The table also shows that
primary budget deficit has outweighed the private sector's primary
surplus, with the result that the primary external deficit has been
positive and growing at the rate of more than 14 percent per annum.
The interest and principal payments on public debt and rental
payments on private foreign capital have been increasing even at faster
rates. The extra-ordinary growth in debt servicing payments is mainly
due to the rising public debt and inflow of capital, and partially due
to the rising rates of interest on external as well as internal debt and
the amortisation rate of external debt. With increasing difficulty in
arranging long-term soft external loans, which have also lead to
declining credit worthiness of Pakistan, the composition of external
debt has drifted towards short term commercial loans. This in turn has
resulted in the rising interest and amortisation rates and shortening of
the amortisation period as is evident from the table. Likewise the
interest rate on internal borrowing has to be increased in order to
compete in the domestic loanable funds market.
It is also evident from the table that the current account external
deficit has been rising quite fast due to the rising primary external
deficit and, especially the rising interest payments on external debt
and rental payments on foreign capital. Likewise the current account
budget deficit has been rising almost at the same rate due to the rising
primary budget deficit and interest payments on external and internal
debts.
The statistics in Table 1 also show that foreign capital inflow
both in terms of equity and direct foreign investment has increased
quite significantly, especially during 1990s. Although the direct effect
of capital inflows is that it helps control the need for external
borrowing, yet the resulting increase in rental payments abroad adds to
the burden on current account external balance and thereby indirectly
increases the need for external borrowing.
Table 2 shows the trends in deficits, borrowings and debts as
ratios to the nominal GDP. Since all the measures of resource deficit
are also given in nominal terms, the inflationary factor is eliminated
from these ratios. A rising (declining) ratio would indicate that the
resource deficit is growing in real sense faster (slower) than the real
GDP. We observe that, while the primary budget and external deficits as
proportions to the GDP have been more or less stable, the debt servicing
and rental payments, and the current account deficits have been rising
faster that the nominal GDP. That is, the burden of debt servicing and
current account balances have deteriorated in real terms as well. The
same is the case with net and gross external borrowing and external and
internal debt. On the other hand net internal borrowing has not
increased as fast as the nominal GDP.
Another notable observation is that contrary to the generally held
perception, during 1990s the current account as well as primary budget
deficits have shown some improvement in relation to the GDP growth,
while the primary and current account external deficits have been
relatively stable. This could partially be due to the discipline imposed
by the so-called IMF conditionalities. Nevertheless it is evident from
the above observations that the resource deficiency and debt positions
have severely worsened in Pakistan during 1980s and 1990s.
3. THE MODEL
The full three-gap model has been derived in Ahmad (1997). In this
paper we consider a variation of the model to highlight the role of
monetary money supply, inflation and exchange rate. However, to avoid
repetition, we give only a brief description of the model. Unless
otherwise stated, all variables are measured in domestic currency at
current prices. The parameters relate either to real quantities (at
constant prices) or to nominal values in foreign currency.
The following notations are used in the paper:
[a.sup.ED.sub.i] = Amortisation rate of external debt.
[BM.sub.i] = Base money.
[C.sup.G.sub.i] = Government consumption expenditure.
[C.sup.P.sub.i] = Private consumption expenditure.
[CBD.sub.i] = Current account budget deficit.
[CED.sub.i] = Current account external deficit.
[e.sub.i] = Rate of exchange rate depreciation.
[ED.sub.i] = External debt.
[FDI.sub.i] = Private foreign direct investment.
[FDK.sub.i] = Stock of private foreign direct capital.
[FEI.sub.i] = Private foreign equity investment.
[FEK.sub.i] = Stock of private foreign equity capital.
[FER.sub.i] = Foreign exchange reserves.
[G.sup.FDK.sub.i] = Growth rate of foreign direct capital in real
terms.
[G.sup.FEK.sub.i] = Growth rate of foreign equity capital in real
terms.
[G.sup.FER.sub.i] = Growth rate of foreign exchange reserves in
real terms.
[G.sup.BM.sub.i] = Growth rate of base money.
[G.sup.Y.sub.y] = Growth rate of real GDP.
[g.sub.i] = Marginal rate of government consumption expenditure.
[GEB.sub.i] = Gross external borrowing.
[I.sup.G.sub.i] = Government investment expenditure.
[I.sup.P.sub.i] = Private investment expenditure.
[ID.sub.i] = Internal debt.
[M.sub.i] = Imports.
[NEB.sub.i] = Net external borrowing.
[NIB.sub.i] = Net internal borrowing.
[PBD.sub.i] = Primary budget deficit.
[PED.sub.i] = Primary external deficit.
[PPD.sub.i] = Primary private sector's deficit.
[R.sub.i] = Total rental payments on foreign capital.
[r.sup.ED.sub.i] = Rate of interest on external debt.
[r.sup.ID.sub.i] = Real rate of interest on internal debt.
[S.sup.G.sub.i] = Government savings.
[S.sup.P.sub.i] = Private savings.
[s.sub.i] = Marginal private saving rate (out of private disposable
income).
[T.sub.i] = Tax and non-tax government revenues.
[t.sub.i] = Marginal tax rate.
[U.sub.i] = Unrequited transfers.
[u.sub.i] = Marginal rate of unrequited transfers.
[X.sub.i] = Exports.
[Y.sub.i] = Gross domestic product (GDP).
[[delta].sub.i] = Depreciation rate of private foreign direct
capital.
[[gamma].sub.i] = Government's share in investment
expenditure.
[[kappa].sub.i] = Marginal capital-output ratio.
[[pi].sub.i] = Domestic inflation rate.
[[rho].sup.FDK.sub.i] = Rental rate on private foreign direct
capital.
[[rho].sup.FEK.sub.i] = Rental rate on private foreign equity
capital.
According to three-gap model external deficit is a mirror, image of
the domestic resource deficit, where the latter is split into its
private and public counterparts. We can define the primary external,
budget and private sector deficits and their interrelationship as
follows.
[PED.sub.i] = (C.sup.G.sub.i] + [C.sup.P.sub.i] + [I.sup.G.sub.i] +
[I.sup.P.sub.i] - ([Y.sub.i] - [U.sub.i]) = [M.sub.i] - [X.sub.i] -
[U.sub.i], ... ... (1)
[PBD.sub.i] = [C.sup.G.sub.i] + [I.sup.G.sub.i] - T =
[I.sup.G.sub.i] - [S.sup.G.sub.i], ... ... ... ... (2)
[PPD.sub.i] = [C.sup.P.sub.i] + [I.sup.P.sub.i] + [T.sub.i] -
[Y.sub.i] - [U.sub.i] = [I.sup.P.sub.i] - [S.sup.P.sub.i], ... ... ...
... (3)
PED = [PGD.sub.i] + [PPD.sub.i], ... ... ... ... ... ... (4)
It can be shown that the time paths of the primary resource
deficits are given by the following equations. The proof is available
from the authors.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
In order to proceed further we need to trace the relationship
between stock and flow components of various variables. Since the
primary resource deficits are measured in domestic currency, the
interest payments on external debt and the rental payments on private
foreign capital must also be denominated in domestic currency for
aggregation purposes. We assume that interest rate on internal debt and
the rental rate on foreign equity capital are subject to full Fisher
effects. (3) Therefore the two are adjusted one to one for inflation.
However, we assume that foreign direct capital is fully indexed for
inflation and, therefore, the rental rate on foreign direct capital does
not incorporate inflationary factor. Finally, assuming that the
purchasing power parity holds, the exchange rate depreciation factor is
equal to the ratio of domestic inflation factor to foreign inflation
factor. This means that external debt is also indexed for domestic
inflation. It also follows that the interest rate on external debt does
not include inflationary factor.
Under the above assumptions we can write
[FDI.sub.i] = (1 + [[pi].sub.i])([G.sup.FDK.sub.i] +
[[delta].sub.i]) [FDK.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ... (8)
[FEI.sub.i] = [??](1 + [[pi].sub.i]) (1 + [G.sup.FEK.sub.i]))-1[??]
[FEK.sub.1-1] ... ... ... ... (9)
[DELTA][FER.sub.i] = [??](1 + [[pi].sub.i]) (1 + [G.sup.FER.sub.i])
- (1 + [e.sub.i])[??] [FER.sub.i-1] ... ... ... (10)
[DELTA][BM.sub.i] = [G.sup.BM.sub.i] [BM.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ...
... ... (11)
[FDK.sub.i] = (1 + [[pi].sub.i]) (1 + [G.sup.FDK.sub.i])
[FDK.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ... ... (12)
[FEK.sub.i] = (1 + [[pi].sub.i])(1 + [G.sup.FEK.sub.i])
[FEK.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ... ... (13)
[FER.sub.i] = (1 + [[pi].sub.i])(1 +
[G.sup.FER.sub.i])[FER.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ... ... (14)
[BM.sub.i] = (1 + [G.sup.BM.sub.i])[BM.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ... ...
... (15)
The time paths of current account external and budget deficits are
as follows.
[CED.sub.i] = [PED.sub.i] + (1 + [e.sub.i]) [r.sup.ED.sub.i]
[ED.sub.i-1] + (1 + [[pi].sub.i])[[rho].sup.FDK.sub.i] [FDK.sub.i-1] +
[(1 + [[pi].sub.i]) (1 + [[rho].sup.FEK.sub.i]) - 1] [FEK.sub.i-1] ...
... (16)
[CBD.sub.i] = [PBD.sub.i] + (1 + [e.sub.i]) [r.sup.ED.sub.i]
[ED.sub.i-1] + [??](1 + [[pi].sub.i]) (1 + [r.sup.ID.sub.i]) - 1[??]
[ID.sub.i-1] ... ... (17)
Net external borrowing is required to finance the part of current
account deficit which is not covered by private capital inflow, and to
increase foreign exchange reserves [see Cohen (1988)], while gross
external borrowing is equal to the net borrowing plus principal
payments. That is,
[NEB.sub.i] = [CED.sub.i] - ([FDI.sub.i] + [FEI.sub.i]) +
[DELTA][FER.sub.i] ... ... ... ... ... (18)
[GEB.sub.i] = [NEB.sub.i] + (1 + [e.sub.i])[a.sup.ED.sub.i]
[ED.sub.i-1] ... ... ... ... ... ... (19)
Budget deficit is financed by three sources: internal borrowing,
external borrowing net of the increase in foreign exchange reserves, and
monetary borrowing or the change in base money. Therefore the net
internal borrowing can be written as
[NIB.sub.i] = [CBD.sub.i] - ([NEB.sub.i] - [DELTA][FER.sub.i]) -
[DELTA][BM.sub.i] ... ... ... ... (20)
Finally, external debt, measured in local currency, accumulates for
two reasons: the local currency value of the existing volume of external
debt increases due to exchange rate depreciation; and/or if the net
external borrowing is positive during the current period. The internal
debt, on the other hand, accumulates only on account of net internal
borrowing. Therefore,
[ED.sub.i] = (1 + [e.sub.i])[ED.sub.i-1] + [NEB.sub.i] ... ... ...
... ... ... (21)
[ID.sub.i] = [ID.sub.i-1] + [NIB.sub.i] ... ... ... ... ... ...
(22)
This completes the structure of our model, which can now be used to
simulate the time paths of net external and internal borrowings and
debts under alternative parametric assumptions.
4. PARAMETER ESTIMATES AND NUMERICAL SIMULATIONS
We shall now use Equations 5-22 to study the time path of some of
the key indicators of resource deficiency in Pakistan. The base period
for projections is chosen to be 1996-97 which was relatively a normal
year and for which all the required data are available in the final
form. The time paths are derived for the period 1997-98 to 2019-20. With
a few exceptions various parameters required for simulation are
estimated using compound growth rates, averages, etc. over the past 10
years. Since no separate information is available on the rental payments
on the foreign direct and equity capital, the rental rates are estimated
as parameters from the following non-linear regressing equation using
the past 20 years data. (4)
[R.sub.i] = (1 + [[pi].sub.i]) [[rho].sup.FDK] [FDK.sub.i-1] + [(1
+ [[pi].sub.i]) [(1 + [[rho].sup.FEK]).sup.-1] [FEK.sub.i-1] ... ...
(23)
The series of foreign direct and equity capital stocks are
estimated by accumulating past investments for the period 1959-60 and
applying 5 percent depreciation rate on the foreign direct capital.
All the required data are taken from 50 Years of Statistics in
Pakistan, various issues of Economic Survey and Statistical Supplements
(Finance Division, Government of Pakistan) and Annual Report (State Bank
of Pakistan). The estimated parameters are given in Table 3.
The expected levels of primary deficits, current external and
budget deficits, the net and gross external borrowings, net internal
borrowing and external and internal debt for the period 1997-98 to
2019-20 are reported in Table 4. These results show that the primary
budget deficit is expected to rise by about 19 percent annually. The
primary private sector's deficit, on the other hand, would grow at
a lower rate, 9 percent per annum. Since, however, the private
sector's deficit would remain quite low as compared to the budget
deficit, its slow growth would have negligible effect on the primary
external deficit, which is expected to grow at the rate of 18 percent
per annum.
The current account external deficit is expected to grow at the
rate of 20 percent per annum, faster than the growth in the budget
deficit (about 17 percent per annum). Since the current account external
deficit is the sum of the budget deficit and the private sector's
deficit, this pattern indicates deterioration in the private
sector's current account balance as well. The main reason for this
deterioration and, hence a faster growth in current account external
deficit as compared to the current account budget deficit, is the
expected growth in rental payments on private foreign capital.
If, however, the private foreign capital inflow continues to grow
at the present rate, it will more than offset the shortfall in the
private sector's balance. This also means that net external
borrowing will remain substantially below the current account external
deficit, so that the government will rely heavily on internal borrowing
to cover the budget deficit. Thus net internal borrowing would grow at a
faster rate (about 18 percent per annum) than the net external borrowing
(about 16 percent per annum). On the other hand external debt is
expected to grow faster than the internal debt because external debt is
indexed for exchange rate depreciation, and hence for inflation as it is
contracted in foreign currency, while the internal debt is not indexed
for inflation.
The above simulation results include the effects of inflation. In
order to remove the inflationary factor and to place the results in
relation to real growth in the growing economy, we now divide all the
variables by the nominal GDP. Table 5 provides the relevant information.
The table shows that the primary budget and external deficits as
percentages of the GDP are expected to grow by more than 2 percent per
annum. This means that in real terms the two measures of deficits are
expected to grow faster than real GDP. The primary deficit in the
private sector, on the other hand, would grow in real terms much slower
than the growth rate of real GDP
Although the current account external deficit, as a percentage of
the GDP, is expected to grow at about of 4 percent per annum, the net
external borrowing will remain fairly stable around 4 percent of GDP.
The basis for this expectation is the assumption that private capital
inflow will continue to contribute favourably to the capital account of
the balance of payments. The current account budget deficit as a
percentage of the GDP is also expected to remain fairly stable while the
net internal borrowing would rise at around 2 percent per annum. These
trends, in turn, translate into an exponentially rising time path for
the external debt and a relatively stable U-shaped time path of internal
debt.
The above results show that Pakistan's external debt position
is expected to become worse in future while the position of internal
debt will not improve. The burden of external debt servicing will rise
to more than 8 percent of GDP and the current account external and
budget deficits will rise beyond the acceptable limits.
We can now study the effects of changes in parameters of the system
on the simulated time paths of resource deficits. Using a model similar
to the one presented here, Ahmad (1997) has performed such simulation
exercises and has suggested two mixed policies to reduce the debt
burden. These policies are mainly focussed on fiscal measures such as
changes in tax rate, government consumption rate and the share of public
sector in investment expenditure. Although the present study is based on
updated estimates of the parameters, there is not much point in
repeating the entire simulation exercise, which in any case is
illustrative only. In this paper we shall consider a broader policy mix
that also includes monetary policy to control inflation and thereby the
rate of exchange rate devaluation.
The policy mix is designed with the multiple objectives of reducing
the debt burden, maintaining a high and steady growth rate of GDP,
producing stability in the economy and minimising the financial risk due
to low foreign exchange reserves. After a number of experiments we have
come up with the following policy mix that has a balanced effect on all
accounts.
(a) The tax rate is increased by 1 percent in each year starting
from the year 1998-99 till it is increased from 17 percent to 20 percent
in the year 2000-01.
(b) The rate of government consumption expenditure is reduced by 1
percent starting from 1998-99 till it settles at 10 percent in the
2000-01.
(c) The share of public sector in investment expenditure is reduced
by 2 percent in each year starting from 1999-00 till it is reduced from
the present 48 percent to 40 percent in 2002-03.
(d) GDP growth rate is increased from the present 5 percent per
annum to 6 percent per annum gradually over a period of 10 years from
2000-01 to 2009-10.
(e) The annual growth rate of foreign exchange reserves is set at
20 percent for 1998-99 to 2003-04 till the foreign exchange reserves
reach at about 5 percent of GDP. From the year 2004-05 onwards the
growth rate is set equal to the target GDP growth rate of 6 percent so
that the foreign exchange reserves remain around 5 percent of GDP in the
subsequent years.
(f) The growth rate of money supply is reduced from the current 13
percent by 1 percent per annum over the period 1999-00 to 2005-06 when
it reaches to 6 percent. Assuming full Fisher effects, it is expected
that inflation rate and the rate of exchange rate depreciation will
decline by the same magnitudes and settle at 3 percent and 2 percent
respectively with a lag of one year.
(g) With the resulting stability in price level and exchange rate,
a better budget position and the declining role of public sector, it is
expected that real interest rates on domestic saving instruments will
rise and the private sector will gain confidence. These factors along
with other policy measures are expected to raise the private saving rate
by 1 percent per annum over the period 1999-00 to 2001-02 till it
reaches to 15 percent.
(h) Finally, we assume that with more stability and the expanding
private sector, productivity will rise and as a result capital-output
ratio will decline gradually to 3.5 over the period 1999-00 to 2003-04.
Although the space does not allow a separate treatment of each of
the above policy measure, we can nevertheless discuss briefly the
qualitative implications of each. The increase in tax rate produces
favourable effects on all accounts; but the decrease in external deficit
is smaller than the decrease in budget deficit because the resulting
decrease in the overall resource deficiency, which determines the size
of the external deficit, is partially offset by reduced private savings.
Despite this, however, the favourable effects on external borrowing and
external debt would be greater than the effects on internal borrowing
and internal debt. The reason is that the government would reduce
internal borrowing only to the extent that the reduction in the budget
deficit is not fully matched by the reduction in external borrowing.
A cut in government consumption expenditure leaves the private
sector's resource balance unchanged. Therefore the reduction in the
primary external deficit must be equal to the reduction in primary
budget deficit. It also follows that the reduction in current account
budget deficit would be equal to the reduction in current account
external deficit, and to the reduction in net external borrowing, with
the net internal borrowing remaining unchanged.
The share of public sector in investment expenditure is reduced
gradually keeping in view the political difficulties attached with
privatisation. Since a decrease in the government's share in
investment implies an equal increase in the private sector's share,
the overall investment and resource deficiency in the country remains
unaffected. Therefore, the external balance remains unchanged. (5) With
the investment in public sector decreasing, the budget deficit improves.
Furthermore, government must fully crowd out in terms of reduced
borrowing from the domestic capital market in order to make room for the
private-sector investment. Thus both net internal borrowing and internal
debt would decrease.
The above policies are designed to reduce the pressure on internal
and external borrowing. For further relief, it is also essential that
the rate of private savings and productivity rise. For this purpose it
is essential to promote stability, efficiency and confidence in the
economy. The reduction in borrowing pressure and the increasing role of
private sector as implied by the above policies can partially serve the
purpose. However, it is also necessary to sustain a better GDP growth
rate in the long run. However, since external borrowings are highly
sensitive to the growth target and the economy is likely to remain under
strict financial constraints, the growth objective is postponed and the
GDP growth rate is increased only gradually.
When the GDP growth rate is increased, both the public and private
sectors would have to invest more according to the previously given
shares of the two sectors. Therefore, both the public and private
sector's balances would deteriorate. The required increase in
private investment can be realised only when the domestic capital market
is relieved of government borrowing. Therefore, in spite of an increase
in the budget deficit, net internal borrowing must decrease. Thus the
government has to increase external borrowing not only to finance
additional investment in public sector but also to divert borrowing from
internal to external sources. (6)
To reduce uncertainty and produce stability in the economy, it is
suggested that inflation and devaluation of rupee be controlled by a
consistent decrease in the growth rate of money supply. These policies
would affect directly the internal and external balances to the extent
that some of the stock variables are indexed for inflation (external
debt and foreign direct capital) while the inflationary factor is
included in the interest payments on some other stocks (internal debt
and foreign equity capital). Furthermore the results show that apart
from the increase in internal borrowing to replace deficit financing by
monetary expansion, the direct effects of this policy are relatively
small. The increase in internal borrowing is, however, expected to be
more than offset by the sale of public assets. It is expected that the
anti-inflationary measure would raise real interest rates on domestic
saving instruments and coupled with the other measures discussed above,
better prospects for gainful investment would promote private savings.
This in turn will further improve external balance and relieve the
pressure for external borrowing.
Finally, most of the above policies are likely to promote
efficiency and productivity in the economy. It is further suggested for
the sake of optimal resource allocation that resources are directed
towards those sectors where the marginal productivity of investment is
relatively better. Thus we assume that capital-output ratio declines
gradually from 4 to 3.5. This improvement in productivity improves
internal as well as external balances. However internal borrowing would
rise to absorb the surplus generated in the private sector.
The effects of the above policy mix on various indicators of
resource gap are presented in Tables 6 and 7. The results in Table 6
show that the policy mix has favourable effects on all accounts. The
primary budget deficit is expected to decline sharply and from the year
2010-11 onwards the deficit turns into surplus. The increase in the
private sector's primary deficit results mainly from increase in
taxation and private investment expenditure and the GDP growth rate as
required by the policy mix, though these effects are partially offset by
the reduced capital output ratio. The primary external deficit also
shows a remarkable improvement and it declines by almost 3 percent per
annum as against the expected 18 percent increase in the absence of any
policy. The current account external and budget deficits also show
substantial improvements, though the expected reduction in the former is
significantly more than the reduction in the latter. The current account
budget deficit is expected to become almost stable.
The improved current account balances in turn translate into
decrease in expected borrowings. The net external borrowing is expected
to become negative by the year 2016-17 while the gross external
borrowing will decrease by 8 percent per annum. The net internal
borrowing would, on the other hand, continue to rise, though at a
reduced rate. The substantial decrease in external borrowing despite a
much smaller improvement in current account external deficit can be
explained by the stability of exchange rate resulting from the reduction
in the growth rate of money. On the other hand, internal borrowing is
expected to increase, though at a lower rate than expected without the
policy mix, despite a stable current account budget deficit. This is
mainly because, given the net external borrowing, with a decrease in the
growth rate of base money, government would have to replace monetary
borrowing by direct internal borrowing.
Finally, the internal and external debt positions are also expected
to improve significantly after the implementation of the policy. The
improvement in external debt position is expected to be more prominent
because with the stability produced in the exchange rate, the existing
external debt would not grow as fast due to depreciating rupee as was
expected in the light of present inflation rate.
Table 7 shows the time profiles of the expected indicators of
resource deficits after the implementation of the policy mix. We observe
that, except for the private sector's primary deficit, all the
indicators show declining trends. For example the current account
deficit is expected to remain stable at about 6 percent of GDP while the
current account budget deficit would decline to below 5 percent from the
year 2003-04 onwards and by the year 2019-20 it will decline to about 1
percent of GDP. The internal and gross external borrowings as
percentages of the GDP will decline steadily. The net internal borrowing
will also decline, though towards the end of simulation period, it will
show a rising trend.
The internal and external debts as percentages of the GDP would
decline to about 20 percent of the GDP as against the expected figures
of 69 percent and 33 percent respectively in the absence of the policy
mix.
Before closing this section, it is to be noted that the above time
paths of resource deficits have been derived from simulation exercises
and cannot be taken as the 'estimated' time profiles. In other
words, the results are relevant in qualitative, rather than
quantitative, sense.
5. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
This paper has been an attempt to study the nature of present debt
crisis in Pakistan with the help of a stock-flow consistent three-gap
simulation model. The paper shows that if the interest/rental rates on
debt and foreign capital, growth rates of real GDP, foreign capital,
foreign exchange reserves, money supply, price level and exchange rate,
and the parameters characterising national saving rate and productivity
remain unchanged then the debt crisis in Pakistan will worsen. In
particular, the current account as well as primary budget and external
deficits, internal and external borrowings and public debt will grow to
unmanageable magnitudes.
The study considers the effectiveness of various policy instruments
in controlling the size of public debt. Keeping in view that a single
policy instrument is unlikely to produce desirable results on all
accounts, the paper recommends a policy mix that is designed to have
balanced effects on all the key indicators of resource deficiency. The
policy mix is based on a number of measures including an increase in tax
rate, a cut is government consumption expenditure, privatisation,
increase in the growth rates of GDP and foreign exchange reserves and a
decrease in the growth rate of monetary base. It is assumed that the
resulting improvements in the budget and external balances, reduced
inflation rate, stability in exchange rate and the encouragement of the
private sector, the private savings and productivity will also rise,
which further improve the position of resource balances. The policy mix
is shown to result in significant favourable effects on many accounts in
the long run, especially in terms of a reduced need for internal and
external borrowing, better growth performance, economic stability and a
reduced risk of default.
Although the study is based on simulation experiments, it provides
useful insights in the complex nature of the current debt problem in
Pakistan. In particular, we learn that external and internal debt
positions should be studied in the context of overall macroeconomic picture. A meaningful solution to the problem lies in addressing
simultaneously the core issues of poor saving performance, low
productivity, unchecked monetary expansion, unrealistically large public
sector and sluggish economic growth.
Authors' Note: We wish to thank Professor Syed Nawab Haider
Naqvi for his encouragement and useful comments on the paper.
REFERENCES
Ahamd, E. (1996) Capital Inflows and National Debt. The Pakistan
Development Review 35:4 943-960.
Ahamd, E. (1997) Dynamics of Foreign and Domestic Borrowings and
Debts. Journal of Economic Cooperation 18:3 71-113.
Ahmad, E. (1998) Retiring Public Debt through Privatisation.
Unpublished paper.
Ahmad, E., and M. Idress (1998) The Time Profile .of Cost Structure
in Pakistan's Manufacturing Sector. Unpublished.
Ahmad, E., and S. Paul (1998) Foreign Investment and the
Neo-classical Growth Model. Chapter 6, p. 90-100. In S. Paul (ed) Trade
and Growth: New Theory and the Australian Experience. Allen & Unwin,
Sydney. Forthcoming.
Ali, N., E. Ahmad, and R. Butt (1997) Dependency Burden and Savings
Rates in Pakistan-A New Strategic Study. Pakistan Economic and Social
Review 25:2 95-130.
Burney, N. (1988) Determinants of Debt Problem in Pakistan and its
Debt Servicing Capacity. The Pakistan Development Review 27:4 805-816.
Chaudhary, M. A. (1988) International Debt and Foreign Dependency:
Policy Options for Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 27:4
829-836.
Cohen, D. (1988) The Management of the Developing Countries'
Debt: Guidelines and Applications to Brazil. The World Bank Economic
Review 2:1.
Crouch, R. L. (1973) Economic Development, Foreign Aid, and
Neo-classical Growth. Journal of Development Studies 9: 353-364.
Naqvi, S. N. H. (1970) The Foreign Capital Requirements and
External Indebtedness of a Developing Country: A Case Study of Pakistan.
In E. A. G. Robinson (ed) Economic Development in South Asia. London: M.
Stockton, 504-524.
Rahman, M. A. (1967) The Pakistan's Perspective Plan and the
Objective of Elimination of Dependence on Foreign Assistance. The
Pakistan Development Review 7:3 412-415.
Tanzi, V., M. I. Blejer, and M. O. Teijeiro (1988) The Effects of
Inflation on the Measurement of Fiscal Deficits. In M. I. Blejer and C.
Ke-Young (eds) Measurement of Fiscal Impact: Methodological Issues.
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C. (Occasional Paper 59.)
(1) Using Neo-classical growth framework, Ahmad and Paul (1994) and
Crouch (1973) have shown that the benefits of foreign investment can
only be temporary unless it increases national savings rate and/or
productivity.
(2) All the earlier studies on debt simulation in Pakistan are
based on two gap models. See, for example, Burney (1988); Chaudhary
(1988); Naqvi (1970) and Rahman (1967)
(3) According to the Fisher effect, under perfect foresight, with
flexible prices and in the absence of any unexpected shocks, nominal
interest rate fully adjusts to the expected inflation rate to yield a
constant real rate of interest. Likewise, if the foreign inflation rate
is constant, the nominal exchange rate will also adjust with changes in
the domestic inflation to yield a constant real exchange rate [see Tanzi
et al. (1988)]. Although the validity of Fisher effects is an empirical
question, there is no way one could predict the future course of
disparity from the neutral assumption made above.
(4) No serious econometric problems such as autocorrelation or
multicollinearity are apparent from the results and the estimates of
both the parameters [[rho].sup.FDK] and [[rho].sup.FEK] given in Table 3
are statistically significant.
(5) These results rest on the assumption that all the disinvested
businesses are purchased by domestic residents. If some of these
purchases come from foreign residents, the resulting net capital inflow
would have some favourable effect on the external borrowing and external
debt as well. See Ahmad (1996, 1998).
(6) In other words, since domestic savings are already fully used
for investment, the additional investment required to finance an
increase in the GDP growth rate has to be funded by external borrowing,
irrespective of the shares of the additional investment undertaken in
the public and private sectors.
Eatzaz Ahmad and Ayaz Ahmed are respectively Associate Professor at
the Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad and Staff Economist at the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Indicators of Resource Deficiency (Billion Rupees Per Year)
Indicators of Resource Deficits 1980-85 1985-89 1989-93
Primary Budget Deficit 12.85 35.82 45.42
Primary Private Sector Deficit -3.68 -24.46 -20.08
Primary External Deficit 9.17 11.35 25.34
Interest Payments on External Debt 2.97 6.83 13.51
Rental Payments on Foreign Capital 1.95 6.58 15.76
Principal Payments on External Debt 5.02 11.87 20.56
External Debt Servicing 7.99 18.70 34.07
Debt Servicing and Rental Payments
Abroad 9.94 25.28 49.83
Interest Payments on Internal Debt 7.86 22.00 48.47
Total Debt Servicing 15.85 40.71 82.54
Current External Deficit 14.09 24.77 54.60
Current Budget Deficit 23.69 64.65 107.41
Net Internal Borrowing 21.62 41.16 70.52
Net External Borrowing 13.11 31.30 55.43
Gross External Borrowing 18.13 43.18 75.99
External Debt 112.70 221.44 399.07
Internal Debt 105.50 268.73 494.07
Interest Rate on Internal Debt 9.00 9.52 11.35
Interest Rate on External Debt 2.97 3.57 3.93
Amortisation Rate of External Debt 4.90 6.30 5.96
External Debt Servicing Rate 7.88 9.88 9.89
Average Amortisation Period of
Outstanding Debt 27.41 24.92 22.33
Foreign Exchange Reserves 16.18 12.88 19.18
Foreign Equity Investment 3.11 4.69 7.64
Foreign Direct Investment 0.86 2.76 8.89
Total Foreign Investment 3.97 7.46 16.53
Indicators of Resource Deficits 1993-97 Growth Rate
Primary Budget Deficit 55.72 12.79
Primary Private Sector Deficit -9.09
Primary External Deficit 46.64 14.44
Interest Payments on External Debt 24.70 17.09
Rental Payments on Foreign Capital 38.52 27.40
Principal Payments on External Debt 44.23 17.50
External Debt Servicing 68.93 17.34
Debt Servicing and Rental Payments
Abroad 107.45 19.36
Interest Payments on Internal Debt 97.57 21.23
Total Debt Servicing 166.50 19.35
Current External Deficit 109.86 17.18
Current Budget Deficit 177.99 16.96
Net Internal Borrowing 108.38 12.25
Net External Borrowing 102.03 20.82
Gross External Borrowing 146.26 18.77
External Debt 736.39 15.04
Internal Debt 871.54 17.44
Interest Rate on Internal Debt 12.76 3.39
Interest Rate on External Debt 3.91 2.35
Amortisation Rate of External Debt 6.91 2.75
External Debt Servicing Rate 10.81 2.59
Average Amortisation Period of
Outstanding Debt 22.95 -1.60
Foreign Exchange Reserves 77.09 11.13
Foreign Equity Investment 27.89 14.83
Foreign Direct Investment 37.13 29.45
Total Foreign Investment 65.02 21.29
Table 2
Indicators of Resource Deficiency (Percentage of the GDP)
Indicators of Resource Deficits 1980-85 1985-89 1989-93
Primary Budget Deficit 3.35 5.48 4.17
Primary Private Sector Deficit -0.91 -3.78 -1.94
Primary External Deficit 2.45 1.70 2.24
Interest Payments on External Debt 0.79 1.07 1.22
Rental Payments on Foreign Capital 0.48 1.04 1.40
Principal Payments on External Debt 1.31 1.89 1.85
External Debt Servicing 2.11 2.97 3.07
Debt Servicing and Rental Payments
Abroad 2.59 4.00 4.47
Interest Payments on Internal Debt 2.01 3.41 4.34
Total Debt Servicing 4.12 6.37 7.41
Current External Deficit 3.72 3.81 4.85
Current Budget Deficit 6.16 9.96 9.74
Net Internal Borrowing 5.29 6.60 6.32
Net External Borrowing 3.33 4.98 4.98
Gross External Borrowing 4.64 6.87 6.83
External Debt 30.16 35.00 36.07
Internal Debt 27.50 42.28 44.55
Foreign Exchange Reserves 4.40 2.15 1.76
Foreign Equity Investment 0.88 0.81 0.66
Foreign Direct Investment 0.23 0.44 0.77
Total Foreign Investment 1.11 1.25 1.43
Indicators of Resource Deficits 1993-97 Growth Rate
Primary Budget Deficit 2.80 -0.73
Primary Private Sector Deficit -0.63
Primary External Deficit 2.16 0.90
Interest Payments on External Debt 1.24 3.58
Rental Payments on Foreign Capital 1.89 13.95
Principal Payments on External Debt 2.18 4.00
External Debt Servicing 3.42 3.83
Debt Servicing and Rental Payments
Abroad 5.31 5.84
Interest Payments on Internal Debt 4.86 7.71
Total Debt Servicing 8.28 5.84
Current External Deficit 5.29 3.66
Current Budget Deficit 8.89 3.45
Net Internal Borrowing 5.44 -1.33
Net External Borrowing 5.17 7.33
Gross External Borrowing 7.36 5.25
External Debt 36.82 1.53
Internal Debt 43.54 3.92
Foreign Exchange Reserves 4.00 -2.38
Foreign Equity Investment 1.45 0.97
Foreign Direct Investment 1.84 15.94
Total Foreign Investment 3.29 7.76
Table 3
Estimates of the Parameters
Parameter Estimate
[a.sup.ED.sub.i] = amortisation rate of external debt 0.06
[e.sub.i] = rate of exchange rate depreciation 0.09
[G.sup.Y.sub.i] = growth rate of real GDP 0.05
[G.sup.FER.sub.i] = growth rate of the foreign exchange
reserves 0.05
[G.sup.FEK.sub.i] = growth rate of foreign equity capital 0.10
[G.sup.FDK.sub.i] = growth rate of foreign direct capital 0.13
[G.sup.BM.sub.i] = growth rate of base money 0.13
[g.sub.i] = marginal rate of government consumption
expenditure 0.13
[r.sup.ED.sub.i] = dollar rate of interest on external debt 0.04
[r.sup.ID.sub.i] = real rate of interest on internal debt 0.02
[s.sub.i] = marginal private saving rate (out of private
disposable income) 0.12
[t.sub.i] = marginal tax rate 0.17
[u.sub.i] = marginal rate of unrequited transfers 0.04
[[delta].sub.i] = depreciation rate of private foreign
direct capital 0.05
[[gamma].sub.i] = government's share in investment
expenditure 0.48
[[kappa].sub.i] = marginal capital-output ratio 4
[[pi].sub.i] = inflation rate 0.10
[[rho].FDK.sub.i] = rental rate on private foreign direct
capital 0.11
[[rho].FEK.sub.i] = rental rate on private foreign equity
capital 0.07
Table 4
Projected Resource Deficits (Billion Rupees)
Primary Primary Primary Current Current
Budget Private External External Budget
Year Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit
1997-98 67 12 79 173 235
1998-99 83 13 96 209 271
1999-00 101 14 115 253 313
2004-05 255 22 277 641 654
2009-10 600 35 635 1588 1406
2014-15 1357 53 1410 3891 3092
2019-20 2987 79 3066 9508 6935
Annual 18.80 9.01 18.07 19.98 16.64
Growth
Rate
Net Gross Net
External External Internal External Internal
Year Borrowing Borrowing Borrowing Debt Debt
1997-98 102 161 104 1086 1153
1998-99 123 194 116 1307 1269
1999-00 147 232 130 1571 1399
2004-05 343 555 246 3886 2358
2009-10 750 1261 538 9268 4352
2014-15 1530 2707 1348 21155 9138
2019-20 2836 5417 3712 45855 21967
Annual 16.29 17.31 17.64 18.55 14.34
Growth
Rate
Table 5
Projected Resource Deficits (Percentage of the GDP)
Primary Primary Primary Current Current
Budget Private External External Budget
Year Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit
1997-98 2.43 0.43 2.86 6.22 8.45
1998-99 2.58 0.41 2.99 6.52 8.44
1999-00 2.72 0.39 3.11 6.83 8.44
2004-05 3.35 0.29 3.64 8.41 8.59
2009-10 3.83 0.22 4.06 10.14 8.98
2014-15 4.22 0.16 4.38 12.09 9.61
2019-20 4.52 0.12 4.64 14.38 10.49
Annual
Growth
Rate 2.86 -5.62 2.22 3.88 0.98
Net Gross Net
External External Internal External Internal
Year Borrowing Borrowing Borrowing Debt Debt
1997-98 3.69 5.81 3.74 39.11 41.51
1998-99 3.83 6.04 3.62 40.74 39.55
1999-00 3.96 6.27 3.51 42.40 37.75
2004-05 4.50 7.29 3.23 51.02 30.96
2009-10 4.79 8.05 3.44 59.20 27.80
2014-15 4.75 8.41 4.19 65.75 28.40
2019-20 4.29 8.19 5.61 69.33 33.22
Annual
Growth
Rate 0.69 1.57 1.86 2.64 -1.01
Table 6
Projected Resource with Policy Mix (Billion Rupees)
Primary Primary Primary Current Current
Budget Private External External Budget
Year Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit
1997-98 67 12 79 173 235
1998-99 80 13 93 206 268
1999-00 74 26 100 238 286
2004-05 2 79 81 358 243
2009-10 6 158 164 637 276
2014-15 -59 184 125 967 293
2019-20 -170 213 43 1546 281
Annual
Growth
Rate 14.00 -2.72 10.48 0.81
Net Gross Net
External External Internal External Internal
Year Borrowing Borrowing Borrowing Debt Debt
1997-98 102 161 104 1086 1153
1998-99 130 201 116 1314 1269
1999-00 145 231 121 1578 1390
2004-05 141 311 88 2966 1885
2009-10 206 451 63 4291 2174
2014-15 72 395 218 5464 2895
2019-20 -315 26 603 5366 5009
Annual
Growth
Rate -8.01 8.32 7.53 6.90
Table 7
Projected Resource with Policy Mix (Percentage of the GDP)
Primary Primary Primary Current Current
Budget Private External External Budget
Year Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit Deficit
1997-98 2.43 0.43 2.86 6.22 8.45
1998-99 2.48 0.41 2.90 6.43 8.35
1999-00 1.99 0.70 2.69 6.42 7.72
2004-05 0.04 1.17 1.21 5.33 3.61
2009-10 0.06 1.52 1.57 6.10 2.65
2014-15 -0.36 1.13 0.77 5.98 1.81
2019-20 -0.68 0.85 0.17 6.16 1.12
Annual
Growth
Rate 3.15 -11.98 -0.05 -8.79
Net Gross Net
External External Internal External Internal
Year Borrowing Borrowing Borrowing Debt Debt
1997-98 3.69 5.81 3.74 39.11 41.51
1998-99 4.05 6.26 3.61 40.96 39.55
1999-00 3.93 6.25 3.27 42.58 37.51
2004-05 2.10 4.62 1.31 44.10 28.03
2009-10 1.97 4.32 0.60 41.12 20.83
2014-15 0.44 2.44 1.35 33.76 17.88
2019-20 -1.25 0.10 0.20 21.37 19.94
Annual
Growth
Rate -16.77 -2.00 -2.71 -3.28