Pakistan at the threshold of the 21st century: how to shape a better economic future?
Hasan, Parvez
Pakistan has been facing a deep-seated economic and financial
crisis and seemingly intractable governance issues for the last few
years. Factors such as international sanctions and global economic
slowdown, which have worsened Pakistan's economic difficulties,
were beyond Pakistan's control. But by and large, the
country's economic and financial difficulties are the result of
economic mismanagement in key areas over long periods. Bad governance,
as reflected in widespread corruption and poor delivery of public
services, and especially poor law and order have given birth to a crisis
of confidence in the state. It is argued here that despite this
scenario, a long and arduous process of building institutions, setting
the policies right, and enforcing a role-based governance stressing both
merit and accountability can put Pakistan back on the road to shared
prosperity. Resolving financial problems, accelerating demographic
transition, exploiting tremendous agricultural potential, improving both
availability and quality of education, increasing competitiveness and
bringing about structural change in exports and industry, and reforming
the government are crucial policy actions that can help shape a better
future for the country and end the economic drift.
**********
It is a great honour to be asked to give the first Mahbub ul Haq memorial lecture to The Pakistan Society of Development Economists.
Mahbub's sudden and untimely death in the summer of 1998 is still a
source of great shock. His passing away has deprived Pakistan of one of
its most illustrious sons and robbed the world community of one of the
most effective spokesmen for just development. Mahbub's path
breaking contributions to the concept of human development will be long
remembered and his influence on economic and social policies is being
felt globally. For me Mahbub was a close personal friend for nearly half
a century. It was also a source of great pleasure to work closely with
him in Pakistan's planning in the 1960s and at the World Bank in
the 1970s and to see him operate with such boldness and conviction in
dealing with issues of poverty. For all his internationalism,
Mahbub's first and lasting love was Pakistan. I know that he was
frustrated and troubled that Pakistan's economic and social
performance had not lived up to the earlier promise and had fallen much
short of the very considerable potential. In honouring Mahbub ul
Haq's memory, therefore, I will devote my lecture to conditions and
policies which are needed for an economic turnaround in Pakistan. I
believe better governance and more effective economic management can
ensure not only higher growth than in the past but more just
distribution of growth benefits, a broader human development and greater
self reliance.
PRESENT POSITION
There can be little argument that Pakistan has been facing a deep
seated economic and financial crisis and seemingly intractable
governance issues for the last few years. The financial crisis
manifested itself in a near default on external loans in 1996-97,
freezing of resident foreign currency deposits in late May 1998, and a
technical default on many external debt payment after August 1998,
latter triggered by imposition of sanctions following India and
Pakistan's nuclear explosions. A new IMF agreement and agreement by
the Paris and London clubs to reschedule substantial amount of debt
payments due in 1998-99 and possibly in 1999-2000 has staved off danger
of debt default but there is a consensus that these agreements have
provided breathing room only. The macro-economic imbalances, both fiscal
and external still remain rather large. The overhang of public debt is
how huge. By mid 1999 the ratio of public debt to GDP was over 95
percent (the comparable figures for India is 55 percent) and any
significant reduction of debt burden will require a combination of
strong financial discipline and good economic policies stretched over
several years. Meanwhile the financial constraint is aggravating the
structural economic problems notably in industry and exports and is
depressing investment in physical and human capital so badly needed to
rectify Pakistan's serious lag, in infrastructure and social
development. In 1998-99 both public investment and total fixed capital
formation as a percentage of GDP were at the lowest level in more than
two decades: total investment was only 14.9 percent of GDP in 1998-99
compared to the average of 18.8 percent during 1990-98. It is hardly
surprising that the per capita GNP growth which had already slowed to
1.1 percent annum during the first half of the 1990's from over 3
percent per annum during 1960-90 has nearly stagnated during the last
three years.
The governance issue are highlighted by the crisis of confidence in
the state which is resulting from poor delivery of public services
especially law and order. This along with wide spread corruption is
leading to a breakdown of the compact between the people and the state,
This makes it difficult among other things to collect taxes. At the
political level, the divisions in the country remain large
notwithstanding the unprecedented political mandate given to Nawaz
Sharif's Muslim League in February 1997 and notwithstanding the
large majority of the government in the Parliament. Indeed, the
Government's Standing in the smaller provinces has suffered as it
lost its coalition partners ANP and MQM. There is a sense that politics
are being dominated by the Punjab and the Prime Minister's inner
circle.
From a geo-political point of view, the fact that Pakistan has gone
from being the best performing country on the sub-continent in terms of
growth rate of GNP per capita during 1960-85 to the worst in the 1990s
is bound to have consequences for handling of foreign policy and defence
issues. In per capita GNP terms, India now seems to be growing three to
four times as fast as Pakistan. This is bound to upset the balance of
power considered so vital in South Asia. Thus notwithstanding
Pakistan's acquisition of the nuclear capability, the strategic
edge seems to belong to India.
On the external side, the crisis in East Asia, subsequent large
devaluations of East Asian Currencies, prospect of slowdown in global
economic growth, sharp curtailment in availability of international
capital flows to the not so strong borrowers has also adversely effected
Pakistan's exports and the balance of payments position. Finally
the deterioration in the climate for foreign private investment in
Pakistan due to the dispute' with IPPs (Independent Power
Producers) has also clouded economic outlook. Clearly some of the
factors which have deepened Pakistan's economic difficulties i.e.
international sanctions and global economic slowdown were beyond
Pakistan's control. But by and large, the country's economic
and financial difficulties have been building up over decades and are
the result of economic mismanagement in key areas over long periods. For
instance successive government downplayed the need for more self reliant
growth, tended to ignore the growing competition between defence and
development, invested inadequately in social and human capital and in
making economic choices often opted for the easier short term solutions.
Unfortunately, the present political and economic leadership has been no
exception. It has not recognised the serious bind in which the past
policies have placed Pakistan and the time it will take to put the
economy on a sound footing. It has not taken the public into confidence
about the tough choices the country faces and thus it has not sought to
develop a truly national consensus on key issues such as savings,
exports, population control, education, the role of government and the
relations with India. It has instead held out prospects for quick and
relatively painless recovery.
POLICY AND INSTITUTIONAL FAILURES
Let me elaborate on the policy and the institutional failures. Some
policy problems have persisted over decades. Excessive reliance on
foreign capital, low domestic savings, inadequate investment in the
social sectors and heavy protection to domestic industry, can all be
traced back to the 1960s, otherwise considered a golden era of
development. The 1970 nationalisations by Bhutto of a segment of
industry, banking, insurance and private educational institutions dealt
a major blow to the emerging private sector and even twenty five years
later large part of the financial and insurance sectors are still owned
by the public sector. At the same time, following the separation of East
Pakistan and emergence of Bangladesh, defence spending was increased and
large fiscal deficits began to be incurred. Under Zia, none of the
difficult policy issues which had emerged during the 1960s and the
1970s, unsustainable fiscal deficits, lag in social development,
unbalanced industrial development were tackled resolutely. Indeed
defence spending accelerated sharply and development spending was
squeezed seriously upsetting the balance between the two.
After ten years of democracy following Zia, macro-economic
adjustment still remains incomplete, the relative allocations between
defence and development have become even more unbalanced and progress
towards universal primary education and adult literacy remains limited.
While there has been an important policy shift towards the private
sector and greater reliance on market signals rather than administered
prices, the privatisation efforts have made limited head way and the
losses of the large public enterprises notably WAPDA have grown. The
response of the domestic private sector to the liberalisation of foreign
exchange and investment controls has been very inadequate. In face of
the challenges of resource mobilisation, export development and
structural changes in the industrial sector, private sector has been
floundering. Indeed the relative dependence of the private sector on
borrowing has grown and the textile industry has found it difficult to
cope with the phasing out of the subsidies on raw cotton. As the export
taxation of cotton, which had provided a strong but unnecessary cushion
to the profitability of the Pakistan textile industry for several
decades was phased out, cotton based exports have stagnated in the 1990s
pulling down the entire export performance because of their dominant
weight in total exports.
Two biggest failures of public policy and institutions during the
last ten years have been the sharp deterioration in the effectiveness of
resource use in the public sector and the growing abuses in the largely
public sector controlled financial system. Over the period 1990-98, real
public spending, excluding interest payments, actually declined. But the
problems arising from shortages of public sector resources for
development were made worse by the way public sector programme was
managed in the post-Zia period. The effectiveness of public sector
development and non-development suffered because political pressures in
the choice of projects and implementation arrangements became quite
overt, the institutional capacity for review and appraisal of projects
was further weakened and diffused, and the economic policy coordination
arrangements for setting economic priorities tended to be bypassed. The
institutional capability of Pakistan's planing institutions,
especially the Planning Commission, was in decline for a long time, but
the decisions to bypass the Planning Commission's approval process
for important programmes, such as highways and energy development and
politically-motivated development like the People's Work Programme,
were extremely unfortunate. All democratic governments, starting with
Junejo's in 1985, found have it difficult to resist political
pressures from regional and local interests for low priority public
spending. The ad hoc nature of decision-making appeared, however, to
reach its nadir during Benazir Bhutto's second administration
(1993-96) and proved particularly costly in terms of its macro-economic
consequences. That prime minister Benazir Bhutto also was the finance
minister contributed to diluting the force of internal procedures and
processes.
Some tightening of public spending has taken place during the last
two years. The problems with leakages in government spending have
continued to persist, however, as demonstrated by wide spread abuses
such as ghost schools and phantom teachers. Also, decisions on many
development projects continue to be made on an ad hoc basis.
The further deterioration in the health of the domestic banking
system is reflected in the rise in overdue and bad loans from Rs 80
billion or about 25 percent of outstanding loans in August 1993 to Rs
143 billion or about one-third of total outstanding loans in 1998. That
the highest default ratio occurred in the case of nationalised banks
suggests both greater inefficiencies in public sector owned banks and
their greater susceptibility to political pressures and corrupt
practices.
The present government in its first two years has certainly been
able to reign in corruption at the higher levels of government, has
reduced government administrative spending, and, as mentioned above,
made some progress in improving the effectiveness of spending. It has,
by and large reaffirmed support for the liberal economic policies,
speedy privatisation and major financial sector reform though the actual
progress on privatisation of public enterprises and public owned banks
remains painfully slow. But it has also made major economic policy
mistakes and has not en begun the difficult task of rebuilding public
institutions for development.
THREE RECENT POLICY MISTAKES
Among the policy mistakes three that stand out are, the timing of
the tax reform, and the handling of the resident foreign currency
deposits and the IPPs. The not well thought out major reduction in
income tax, sales tax and customs duty rates in March 1997 led to a
decline in the already low ratio of tax to GDP to 13 percent in 1997-98
notwithstanding the windfall in form of higher taxes on petroleum
reflecting lower international oil prices. The expectations that low
income tax rates will lead to an enlargement of the base of tax payers
and that lower trade taxes will reduce smuggling have not materialised.
The basic philosophy of extending the base of taxation and reducing the
immense tax leakage and evasion through a more moderate level of
taxation might have been sound but the timing and sequencing of tax
reform measures was wrong. The loss of revenue is estimated at about 1.5
percent of GDP. The second mistake was to resist the needed up front
devaluation following the imposition of economic sanctions and the
deterioration in the foreign exchange position in May 1997 and instead
to opt for the freezing of resident foreign currency deposits to
forestall a run on these deposits. Eight months later, the government
found itself in the worst of all possible worlds, a large de-facto
devaluation, a critical loss of trust in its ability to honour
commitments, and a surrender to the demands of the holders of the
deposits to convert them to foreign exchange obligations albeit medium
term bonds with a minimum maturity of three years. Similarly the
handling of the disputes with the IPPs has left much to be desired.
While the allegedly serious corruption by the IPPs had to be
investigated, the high profile fashion in which the government has gone
about it has seriously damaged the foreign investment climate in
Pakistan.
It is not surprising that the persistent weaknesses in investment,
policies and institutions have resulted in a growth crisis. There is a
growth crisis in the sense that significant increases in the per capita
income which were enjoyed for long periods can no longer be taken for
granted. The unsustainability of the past pattern of Pakistan's
development with its excessive reliance on foreign resources, neglect of
human development and equity issues is patently clear. That we have lost
economic momentum in relation to both India and Bangladesh is also sadly
true.
In short, there cannot be too much dispute that Pakistan at the
threshold of the 21st century finds itself in deep economic and
political trouble. Under the circumstances it is not easy to reflect on
the economic future and certainly impossible to predict it. But depth of
the present crisis and the widespread pessimism about the future can and
must provide the seeds of positive thinking. I will argue that since
most of the Pakistan economic problems are the result of economic
mismanagement and poor governance setting the policies right and
starting the long and arduous process of building back institutions,
enforcing a rule based governance, stressing both merit and
accountability, can put Pakistan on the road to shared prosperity. After
a painful period of adjustment and transition lasting perhaps three to
five years Pakistan can recover to healthy average rates of per capita
GNP growth and unlike the past combine it with a broader distribution of
growth benefits and strong progress towards human development.
NEED TO DEVELOP A LONG TERM VISION
Indeed one ,can go further and present the hypothesis that with
improved political governance and moderately good economic management,
Pakistan can have a much better economic and social record during the
next twenty five years than in the past quarter or half century. But one
must hasten to add that in retrospect the overall economic performance
in the past cannot be considered very satisfactory. Contrary to general
impressions, even on the narrow criteria of per capita GNP growth,
Pakistan's increase of 2.1 percent per annum over 1973-98 was about
average in South Asia. On many other measures of performance i.e. human
development, structural change (especially development of new dynamic
exports and a modern industrial sector), domestic savings, self
reliance, and avoidance of external debt difficulties, Pakistan's
record does not compare favourably with either India or Bangladesh. In
my judgement, it will be feasible for Pakistan to attain an average GNP
per capita growth of 4 percent per annum during the next twenty five
years double the 2 percent per annum growth achieved during the last
fifty years. More importantly, higher growth with broader distribution
of growth benefits and greater self reliance will be possible if
development strategy emphasises savings, exports, human development and
agricultural and industrial modernisation and de-emphasises rent seeking and makes the tax and expenditure system both more effective and fairer.
To sum, the long term target of 4 percent per capita GNP growth may
appear too modest and inconsistent with the desire to join the ranks of
Asian Tigers in economic performance. Here two points are relevant.
First, the past neglect of investment in human capital and low levels of
educational attainment in Pakistan will continue to constrain growth for
quite sometime especially in the present circumstances where growth in
productivity as well as expansion in international trade is increasingly
related to knowledge based advances in information technology. Pakistan
cannot easily emulate countries like Korea and Malaysia because these
countries had already in the 1960s or the 1970s attained educational
standards higher than Pakistan enjoys to-day. In Korea essentially full
enrolment at the primary level was achieved in the early 1960s. By 1975
three fourth of the relevant age group was completing middle school
[Hasan and Rao (1979)]. In Malaysia primary level enrolment was 90
percent in 1974 and secondary level enrolment was 40 percent [Young,
Bussink and Hasan (1980)]. In Pakistan universal primary enrolment could
take another decade. (1) At present, the mean years of schooling of
workers aged 25 and over is only around 2.5. (2) Second, even with good
policies and strong political determination, the acceleration of growth
from the present level of barely 1 per capita per annum will take time.
The recovery from the present economic crisis, in growth terms, cannot
be quick if due attention is to be given to putting finances in order,
shifting the focus of investment towards the social sectors and
restructuring industry to face the competitive pressures of
globalisation.
The main point is that in Pakistan's context where the past
pattern of development has proven to be totally unsustainable because of
its extraordinary dependence on foreign savings and its inequitable
sharing of growth benefits, a longer run economic vision is absolutely
necessary. This vision should concern itself not only with growth but
also equity and greater financial self reliance. Unless long term goals
are defined in these broader terms, short term costs, trade offs and
sacrifices will not be either understood or accepted. A twenty five year
time horizon might be anathema to most politicians but hopefully public
opinion and the private sector can be persuaded to take the long view
instead of considering our present predicament hopeless? I recognise
that Keynes said that in the long run we are all dead but his context
was not development and structural change in a pre-modern society.
Pakistan's problems are deep seated and the government undermines
its own credibility when it promises a quick recovery in growth and a
relatively quick resolution of structural and financial issues. While
the general directions of change suggested in the programme Pakistan
2010 make sense, the growth, savings and investment targets indicated
are totally unrealistic. For instance, Pakistan 2010 implies a target of
nearly 8 percent per annum GDP growth over the next decade or so against
the actual growth of 3.7 percent per annum during 1993-98. This kind of
framework not only raises unrealistic expectations but also distorts
likely resource availability and investment priorities. Realism and
patience are qualities both our politicians and planners will need in
great measure at least for the next Plan period (1998-2003) which will
at best be a period of adjustment and transition.
CONDITIONS FOR AN ECONOMIC TURNAROUND
I think I have said enough to indicate that in aiming to treble per
capita GNP over the next twenty five to thirty years and to achieve this
with greater equity and more financial self reliance, the sights are not
being set too low. (3) But while the goals are not unambitious, their
achievement will require clearly better political governance than seen
in the last decade, a much more forceful pursuit of necessary economic
adjustments and much greater attention to institutional reforms and
implementation issues.
A strong, enlightened and honest political leadership which can
build a national consensus not only on economic priorities but also on
the more difficult issues of relations with India, the priority of
defence spending, and power sharing arrangements with the provinces is
vital for better economic performance. The record of democracy in
Pakistan during the last decade is not an encouraging one. But one hopes
that the present leadership will learn from its mistakes, not ignore
professional advice and have the political will to stay the course of
unpopular and painful economic decisions.
The governance problems of deteriorating law and order, widespread
corruption and misuse of public resources, and ineffective bureaucracy
are looming rather large in Pakistan at present and are acting as a
strong disincentive to bath foreign and domestic private investment and
have the effect of lowering economic growth. But to an extent, the
present governance problems have their roots in the pattern of economic
development over the last fifty years. The uneven distribution of growth
benefits and increasing dualism in the society are reflected in the
sharp contrast between the growing numbers of poor and illiterate, on
the one hand, and increasing wealth and sophistication and wealth of the
elite and the upper middle classes, on the other hand: The divergence in
the life style between the rich and the poor is to some extent
unavoidable in the early stages of capitalist development. In Pakistan,
however, this divergence has become especially pronounced in recent
years as economic growth has slowed down, real wages have tended to fall
and the incidence of poverty has tended to increase. Equally important,
government policies which have neglected the social sectors and bestowed
unearned benefits on industrialists and entrepreneurs have aggravated income disparities. It is not, therefore, entirely surprising that
tensions within the society have grown over time and have begun to erupt
with increasing frequency in ethnic, sectarian, and random violence.
While an improvement in the law and order situation is necessary for
stimulating growth, the pattern of future growth must also ensure that
some of the underlying causes of tensions in the society, i.e., poverty,
illiteracy, growing income disparities are removed or mitigated over
time. As Pakistan looks to the future the growth and governance agendas
appear to be intertwined .Without an improvement in the quality of
governance and a reversal in the decline in public institutions it will
be difficult to revive economic growth. But the challenge also is to
ensure that economic policies in the future will correct the imbalances
of the past, seek to greater harmony in the society, and help deal with
the governance issues such as corruption and law and order. The
political leadership can also help to promote the much needed changes in
values and attitudes by accepting the need for a rule based society in
which hard work, thrift, innovation and merit are the criteria which
guide both the civil service reform and the relations with the private
sector.
In the remaining part of this paper, I will abstract from the
political governance issues except to the extent that they are directly
relevant to economic policy reform and implementation. Thus I will focus
mainly on the structural elements, crucial economic policy actions and
institutional issues which can help shape a better future and end the
economic drift of the 1990s, with GDP growth rate of less than 4 percent
per annum, which has brought increasing unrest, growing poverty and
major financial difficulties. I will dwell on six aspects of economic
management which appear crucial to me. These are (1) resolving the
financial problems, (2) accelerating the demographic transition, (3)
exploiting the tremendous agricultural potential, (4) accelerating the
level of and improving the quality of education, (5) developing a new
compact with the private sector to increase competitiveness and bring
about structural change in exports and industry, and (6) last but not
least strengthening implementation at all levels of government thus
creating a culture of accountability and performance.
RESTORING FINANCIAL EQUILIBRIUM
The viability of all other long term policies will be vitiated if
Pakistan does not restore financial equilibrium. Pakistan's
financial difficulties have several dimensions. First, notwithstanding
some progress in the last two years, the underlying macro-imbalances
remain large. Before the external debt relief, the fiscal deficit in
1998-99 was still 4.7 percent of GDP (3.4 percent after debt relief)
compared to 6 and 5.4 percent respectively in 1996-97 and 1997-98.
Furthermore, the fiscal deficit does not include the losses and
potential losses of public sector corporations and banks. The estimated
current account balance of payments deficit of $2.5 billion or 3.8
percent of GDP in 1998-99 was sustained only by extraordinary debt
relief. Second, the reduction in the fiscal and balance of payments
deficit during the last two years have been brought about mainly by
reduction in the investment rate which seriously threatens the future
growth of the economy. Thirdly, there is a correct perception in the
press and in the public that the current agreement between Pakistan
government and the IMF while helping to avoid default on external debt
will at best provide only a breather from our difficult indeed dire
economic and financial problems. The ability of the real economy to
withstand progressive financial shocks has been greatly weakened and
economic uncertainty is already playing havoc with investment and
growth. But the more fundamental point is that even with a successful
implementation of the IMF assisted programme, the financial adjustment,
both fiscal and external, will be far from complete by the middle of
2000. The final and related point is because both the domestic and
external debt has risen to extraordinary heights; the bringing down of
this debt burden to manageable levels is no simple matter and will take
several years of sustained and disciplined fiscal and external resource
management.
DEBT OVERHANG
According to my estimates, total public debt in mid 1999 was over
Rs 2800 billion (the external debt has been converted by using the
latest exchange rate) and exceeded 95 percent of GDP. This ratio has
risen from 60 percent of GDP in 1985 and 80 percent in 1990. The
economic programme even if implemented aggressively over the next twelve
months can at best bring down this ratio only marginally whereas the
need is to reduce it to at least 70 percent of GDP if Pakistan wants to
get out of the debt trap and indeed if it wants to get meaningful
control of its economic policies which will inevitably be dictated by
creditors as long as emergency infusions of external capital are needed.
The government, therefore, needs to develop and the public and the
press should debate the elements of a viable strategy of debt work out
reduction over the medium term. One must begin with outlining the nature
of Pakistan debt problem and distinguish between related but nonetheless
separate issues of external and internal debt. Till the late 1980s, the
external debt of Pakistan was more or less manageable. In the 1990s, the
burden of external debt has grown because while current account balance
of payments deficits increased (totalling $17 billion alone during the
four years ending June 1988) exports have tended to stagnate in recent
years and GDP growth slowed down. The real depreciation of the currency
in 1998 necessitated by the serious foreign exchange crisis has also
increased the burden of external debt. The ratio of foreign debt to GDP,
after debt relief, in mid 1999 was approaching 60 percent (Compared with
35 percent in 1990) and the share of relatively short-term debt in the
total has grown. As a percentage of foreign exchange earnings including
remittances, Pakistan's external debt is now close to 300 percent.
The high external debt-service payments have meant that the gross annual
external financing requirements reached the totally unsustainable level
of $9.5 billion during the last three years (1995-98). Even after annual
average the accruals to resident foreign currency deposits of $1.2
billion, the requirements were far excess of normal sources of finance.
This is the background against which the debt rescheduling had to be
sought from the London and the Paris clubs. Clearly, Pakistan's
external payments difficulties were exacerbated by the imposition of
sanctions but their root cause lies in the payments imbalances of the
last few years and rather reckless reliance on financing these
imbalances with short-term resident foreign currency deposits (RFCD) and
other short-term borrowing.
The foreign exchange crisis forced the balance of payments
adjustment which has brought down the current account balance of
payments deficit (before accruals to RFCD) from the peak of $5.3 billion
in 1995-96 or 8 percent of GDP to $2.5 billion or 3.8 percent of GDP in
1998-99. But clearly further reduction in external deficit will be
necessary. In my view, it should be the goal of policy to reduce the
deficit to around 2 percent of GDP and to maintain it at that level in
the foreseeable future or till such time that the ratio of external debt
to GDP is brought back to reasonable level of say 40 percent.
The magnitude of external adjustment needed in Pakistan is as great
as the fiscal adjustment which has been the focus of most previous IMF
agreements. In the past, the balance of payments targets suggested by
IMF were much less stringent than fiscal targets. Indeed the relatively
recent 1997 IMF agreement considered a current account balance of
payments deficit (after accrual to RFCD) of 4 percent of GDP or roughly
6 percent of GDP (before accrual to RFCD) quite feasible for 1997-98.
Both the government and the IMF were too sanguine about the prospects of
large additions to resident foreign currency deposits though it has been
evident for some time that a major factor in their increase was the
large implicit subsidy provided by the State Bank of Pakistan through
foreign exchange risk cover at a rate much below the expected
depreciation of the rupee. The stagnation in export earnings since 1995
should have also sent up a cautionary signal about the desirability of
large further increases in external obligations. No doubt the government
handling of IPPs has effected creditor confidence and made the roll over
of short-term credit much more difficult. But fundamentally,
Pakistan's balance of payments position has been precarious for a
number of years because not only were the deficit large but also the
sizeable external inflows were short-term and not financing investment
but rather sustaining consumption levels.
Because the need for external adjustment was not foreseen by
policy-makers and international institutions the adjustment that has
taken place this past year has been disorderly reflected in sharp
compression of imports. Effects of this on investment level and medium
term growth will be unavoidable. But as mentioned above, the balance of
payments adjustment will need to go further to ensure a more
self-reliant growth path. Can the future adjustment necessary to put
external finances on a sound footing and bringing Pakistan closer to a
more self-reliant growth path be made without major disruptive effects
on growth and investment? Certainly limiting the current account balance
of payments deficit to around 2 percent of GDP during the next four or
five years compared to 6-7 percent of GDP during the last five years
will not be easy. The impact on investment and growth will depend in
large part on whether additional domestic savings can be mobilised for
investment, whether exports expansion or import substitution (especially
in food grains and edible oils) can help to ensure adequate availability
of capital goods imports. It will be desirable to obtain a greater
degree of equilibrium in the balance of payments while protecting and if
possible enhancing economic growth. If a reduction in the balance of
payments deficit is achieved mainly by a further reduction in the
already low rate of investment (or further squeeze on social spending),
the long term growth will suffer seriously. The aim should be to
increase domestic savings to make up for reduced foreign inflows. But
these domestic savings must also be translated into earnings or savings
of foreign exchange.
While export, agricultural and industrial policies have all a role
to play in strengthening the balance of payments, the need for a
realistic exchange rate remains paramount. Unfortunately, devaluation
remains an emotive issue for most Pakistanis, an evil forced on them by
the IMF. By raising prices of foreign goods and other expenditures in
foreign exchange such as travel and education, devaluation puts pressure
on real consumption and investment. But precisely because it succeeds in
reducing real expenditures and switching of expenditures from foreign to
domestic goods, devaluation helps the balance of payments positively. It
is true that devaluation does not always work especially if monetary and
fiscal policies are not supportive. But the types of arguments being
frequently used in the debate on the exchange rate in Pakistan do not
withstand close examination.
For instance, it is argued that devaluation adds to inflationary
pressure and therefore the hoped for competitive advantage is quickly
eroded. However, the cost push effects of devaluation through raising of
import prices can be easily exaggerated. Imports at present account for
only 15 percent of GDP. Inflation in Pakistan is largely a monetary
phenomenon driven by sizeable fiscal deficits. Another argument is that
in the short run the response of exports and imports may be limited
because of non-price factors. Certainly a significant part of the export
problems facing Pakistan are structural and must be addressed by special
measures. But it is not true that Pakistan's experience suggests a
low response to devaluation. The relatively good export performance of
the 1980s owed a great deal to the large depreciation of real effective
exchange rate after 1982. In contrast, the nominal devaluations of the
Rupee over 1990-97 merely compensated for the higher rate of inflation
in Pakistan and there was no change in the real effective exchange rate.
Given this and the serious structural problems facing exports especially
the heavy dependence on cotton based exports, it is not altogether
surprising that exports have stagnated during the last three or four
years. Another argument against devaluation is that it negatively
effects the fiscal situation because of the large burden of external
debt. Fortunately, the significant debt rescheduling from the Paris and
London club of external debt payments in the current year and the next
will prevent exchange rate adjustments from aggravating the fiscal
position. Finally, real devaluation does put pressure on real wages as
it transfers income to exporters. In Pakistan's case the best long
run guarantee for minimising the impact on the most vulnerable groups in
the society will be the drive for self-sufficiency in wheat and edible
oils which will indeed be helped by the exchange rate depreciation.
To some extent the debate on the exchange rate has been overtaken
by events. The effective unification of the various exchange rates
through the market mechanism in the first half of 1999 has resulted in
an exchange rate of Rs 51.5 per U.S. dollar compared to the rupee parity
of Rs 44 per U.S. dollar in May 1998. This means that, for the first
time in the 1990s, there has been a significant real exchange rate
adjustment during 1998-99. This real depreciation has been necessitated
indeed forced by a change in Pakistan's external circumstances and
a delayed realisation both at the international and national level that
past balance of payments were not sustainable. Instead of this change
being resisted, it should be welcomed as an important instrument for
progress towards greater self-reliance. Paradoxical though it may seem,
a realistic value of the rupee and a reduction in the scarcity premium
in the free market is more likely than anything else to reverse the
capital flight which has been underway since the summer of 1998. For the
future also, small adjustments in the nominal exchange rate if warranted
by the differential of inflation rate between Pakistan and her major
trading partners should be made more or less automatically or least on a
regular basis so that the trauma of a major periodic adjustment can be
avoided.
External adjustment must go hand in hand with domestic financial
adjustment. Among the economic issues, nothing is quite as critical as
the need for raising the domestic saving rate. The task of raising
domestic savings is broader than the goal of reducing fiscal deficit,
though the fiscal adjustment will certainly contribute to higher
domestic savings. Hemmed in by the IMF conditionality, however, fiscal
adjustment has been viewed too narrowly. No doubt, Pakistan has run
large and unsustainable fiscal deficits for a long time and violated
close to dozen IMF agreements. But as mentioned above, much of the
reduction in the fiscal deficit in recent years has been achieved
through compression in expenditures. That squeezing of government
expenditures in the 1990s has already taken a heavy toll on development
spending is well known. But it is not widely recognised, that total real
public spending (excluding interest) over 1991-98 actually declined,
falling from 20.6 to 14.9 as a percentage of GDP. Over this period
defence spending has dropped from 6.3 to 4.8 percent of GDP while
development spending fell from 6.4 to 3.2 percent of GDP. It is doubtful
that social spending has risen significantly. Indeed implementation of
the Social Action Programme may be in jeopardy. Certainly adequate
allocations are not being made for operation and maintenance
expenditure. Since the size of the government and military establishment
has not been reduced, the cuts in spending must be further hampering the
effective delivery of services. No doubt there is a great deal of waste
in government and substantial downsizing is warranted. But on the other
hand, public pay is declining and development outlays are seriously
under funded. There is great danger that tough decisions on size of
government payroll will be postponed while further cuts will be made in
important discretionary spending reducing the effectiveness of
government services further and increasing the resistance to tax
collection by the public.
Greater revenue mobilisation is of course the key to fiscal
adjustment. As mentioned above, as a result of not very well thought out
reduction in tax rates in March 1997 and depressed imports the tax to
GDP ratio, already low, fell to 13 percent in 1997-98 notwithstanding
the large windfall gain due to lower import prices of oil. The problem
is not, however, simply that substantially higher revenues are needed
but they must be mobilised with due regards to their incidence. The
strong negative reaction to the modest increase in general sales tax
from 12.5 to 15 percent must be seen in this light.
The major failing of the tax system is the total inadequacy of
personal income tax collections which are around 10 percent of tax
revenues or barely 1.3 percent of GDP. The sharp reduction in personal
income tax rates has led to loss of revenue as it did not result in any
greater compliance. The tax base has remained very narrow. For sake of
both fairness and elasticity of the tax system, personal income taxation
must be made more effective. This is the single most important test of
new Pakistan Revenue Service. But even under the best of circumstances
the ratio of personal income tax to GDP will rise only slowly because
the maximum rate has been reduced to 20 percent. 'It will be
difficult to improve the redistribute effects of tax policies unless new
steps are taken to tax the rich more effectively.
Four measures which can yield additional revenue and improve
redistribution while not effecting negatively the economic incentives
and the level of domestic economic activity are capital gains taxation,
estate taxes (death duties), the extension of income tax to global
incomes and agricultural taxation. First, Pakistan is one of the few
countries that does not have a tax on capital gains. The exemption from
capital gains tax which was due to expire at the end of June 1997 was
extended for another three years. Now that Pakistan has a low income tax
rate there is no justification for exempting capital gains from the
normal income tax; there can be some allowance (say 25-50 percent) for
the impact of inflation on assets held longer than five or ten years.
The taxation of capital gains, which in real estate have been phenomenal
in recent years, will not only be socially just but will also tend to
curb purely speculative investments and help direct investments to
longer term productive uses.
Second, large inherited wealth should also be subject to taxation
in the interest of equity. The introduction of progressive estate duties
ranging from 10 to 30 percent on estates in excess of Rs 5 million could
help to moderate the growing income disparities in the long run. In the
short run, it will be an important political gesture for a government
which faces the danger of being over-identified with business interests.
Care has to be taken, however, that estate taxation is more effective
than the present wealth taxation which yields relatively little revenue.
Third, Pakistan should extend the coverage of income tax to income
derived from all world sources. Most countries tax the global income of
their residents. Pakistan also did in the 1960s but tax on income from
sources outside Pakistan was effectively diluted over time. Now that
maximum income tax has been lowered to 20 percent, there is even less
justification for exempting any income from outside Pakistan sources
from tax. The present situation actually encourages residents to
transfer savings and hold assets abroad and thus acts against domestic
investment. But as in all tax administration, enforcement will be
important.
Fourth agricultural income tax must be made effective. Dramatic
increase in revenue from this source should not be expected but a
working agricultural income tax is highly necessary to improve fairness,
plug leakages in the tax system and increase the tax base of provincial
governments. Alternatively, serious consideration should be given to the
imposition of a land tax. (see the discussion below.)
The broader issue is that greater freedom for the private sector
and relatively low tax regime must be accompanied by fiscal
responsibility and a reasonable degree of equity if the new capitalist
orientation of the economy is to be made acceptable to the general
public. The tax system needs to be made more efficient as well as more
equitable.
The pre-occupation with reducing the persistently large fiscal
deficits has obscured the need for increasing government savings which
at present are substantially negative. The problem with Pakistan's
fiscal deficits has been not only that they have been large but also
that a significant part of them have been financing public consumption.
For nearly twenty five years, consolidated current public expenditures
have exceeded public revenues. The difference represents negative
government savings which averaging about 2 percent of GDP have been a
major factor in depressing national savings. The situation is not
getting any better. During the last three fiscal years (1996-98) total
government dissaving was Rs 185 billion or over 2.5 percent of GDP.
Fiscal choices must be debated in the context of turning government
dissaving into a surplus of at least 2 percent of GDP. This necessary
and drastic shift must come about by a combination of higher revenues,
lower interest payments and reduced non-development spending. But the
scope for the latter is somewhat limited because possible further
savings in defence will be offset by increases in social spending.
In the short-run, the possibility of large external debt
rescheduling offers the scope for retiring expensive domestic debt. The
commentary in the press that external debt re-scheduling will provide
fiscal space is highly irresponsible. The net effect of external debt
re-scheduling will be to raise total outstanding external debt. The
counterpart resources released, therefore, must be used for
corresponding reduction in domestic debt. If any part of them are used
for expenditures, the total debt to GDP ratio will increase further. But
because the interest rate on domestic debt is substantially higher than
on external debt, some relief will be available for the budget in the
medium term. Use of privatisation proceeds for retiring external and/or
internal debt will also help to lower interest payments in the budget.
While the precise nature of fiscal adjustment can and must be
debated i.e. scope for raising taxation, reducing defence spending,
retiring debt, funding social expenditures, these should be no ambiguity
about two medium term fiscal goals: significantly positive government
savings and a sharply lower debt to GDP ratio. Whatever the pattern of
fiscal adjustment, it will be painful.
But provided government savings can swing from a negative 2 percent
of GDP to a positive 2 percent, the domestic savings picture will
improve dramatically. Control of government finances will increase
confidence in currency, reduce the need for periodic devaluations and
create conditions for reversal of capital flight. The present domestic
saving rate of 12-13 of GDP is only half the rate in India.
Pakistan's economic survival may depend on narrowing this gap.
The above Table 1 illustrates the tough financial choices Pakistan
faces. Both scenarios assume that the reduction in the ratio of national
debt to GDP will be given a very high priority and thus the fiscal and
the current account balance of payments deficits deficit will be
maintained at 3.0-3.5 and 2 percent of GDP respectively during 1998-2003
as a policy variable. Total public spending remains greatly constrained
and does not much exceed the low relative level reached in 1997-98 even
in the high growth scenario B. Even then, the ratio of debt to GDP will
drop only moderately from 97 in mid 1999 to 78 in mid 2004 and the ratio
of foreign debt to GDP will remain close to 50. (4) This ratio could be
further reduced to around 70, the minimum desired level, if sizeable
privatisation revenues accrue to the government and are earmarked for
debt reduction.
The scenarios bring out the central importance of increasing public
savings. Positive public savings are essential for raising the very
inadequate level of development spending. As we discussed above, the
scope for reducing current expenditures is relatively limited. As it is,
it has been assumed that real absolute level of defence spending will
rise only marginally in the next few years. Savings from reduced
interest payments, resulting from a declining debt to GDP ratio will be
largely offset by the needs of higher social sector spending. The
success of Pakistan's fiscal adjustment will depend critically on
whether the government can tax the well to do and the rich through
direct taxation. But even in the higher growth, higher taxation and
higher development spending scenario, the investment rate will in 2004
remain well below the average level in the 1990s mainly because of the
constraint on foreign borrowing. Investment resources should thus be
spent very carefully and growth enhancing efficiency improvements,
discussed below, will be critically important.
Managing the demographic transition
The factor which provides the greatest source of my relative
optimism about the long term future is the slowing population growth and
the possibility that through aggressive policy actions aimed especially
at female education and supporting health and family planning services,
the decline in the rate of this growth can be accelerated.
The preliminary results of 1998 census suggest that population has
grown at an annual rate of 2.6 percent per annum since 1981 and is
estimated to be growing currently at an annual rate of 2-2.2 percent per
annum now. (5) This suggests that the demographic transition has already
begun in Pakistan though both the fertility rate and natural rate of
growth of population remain substantially higher than both India and
Bangladesh: the current population growth rate in India and Bangladesh
is estimated at 1.5 and 1.3 percent respectively and their total
fertility rate is around 3 compared with 4.8 in Pakistan. Since the
total fertility rate in Pakistan, though declining, is still quite high,
the future demographic trends can be strongly influenced by policy
measures in education, health, and family planning. A paramount need is
to strengthen policies especially female education and literacy so as to
reduce desired family size. Reflecting the high rates of illiteracy
among women (75 percent) and low rate of participation of women in the
labour force (less than 15 percent), the desired number of children in
Pakistan is still 4 compared to only 2 in Bangladesh. (6) A dramatic
improvement in women's education and status in society will help to
lower the desired family Size and thus increase the demand for family
planning services. But even at present there is substantial unmet demand
for family planning services. The number of currently married women that
are users of contraceptives has risen from 12 to 24 percent over 1991-98
[NIPS (1998)]. Still the unmet need for family planning (both spacing
and limiting) is estimated is high. Only 39 percent of the total demand
for family planning is satisfied. [NIPS (1998), p. 47.] There remains
substantial scope for expansion of family planning services even with
the present attitudes towards family size.
Learning from the experience of Bangladesh, public policy should
set the ambitions goals of achieving replacement level fertility over
the next twenty five years. The effective implementation of the second
phase of the Social Action Programme (SAP) 1997-2002 will be an
important first step towards the achievement of this goal. If total
fertility rate can be reduced to 2 by 2025, the annual population growth
will drop to around 1 percent. This suggests that with proper policies
there are good prospects of limiting the annual average growth rate of
population to around 1.5 percent during the next twenty five years. Even
this rate of growth will be very much higher than what is likely in
India and Bangladesh.
In any event, Pakistan population growth rate is likely to be
dramatically lower over the next quarter century than in the past twenty
five years when it averaged close to 3 percent per annum. In the past,
the very high population growth has meant great pressures on social
services (especially education) and has adversely affected domestic
resource mobilisation, poverty alleviation and income distribution. A
sharp reduction in the population growth rate in coming decades will
ease both pressures on financial resources and help a better
distribution of growth benefits by contributing to the gradual
tightening of the labour market, though the effects of the slowing
population growth rate on the rate of labour force growth and thus need
very high employment growth will not be significant for at least a
decade. An annual population growth rate of 1.5 percent over 2000-25
will also mean that an annual GDP growth of around 5.5 percent will be
sufficient to achieve the economic goal of roughly trebling per capita
GNP in twenty five to thirty years suggested above. (7)
IMPROVING AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY
Agriculture has been a bright spot in Pakistan's economic
performance since the 1960s. The average agricultural growth rate of
nearly 4 percent annually over nearly four decades has been exceeded
internationally, among large countries, only by Malaysia and Thailand
[Hasan (1998)]. The trend has been maintained in the 1990s despite the
setbacks in cotton production. It has been argued that the agricultural
growth could have been even higher in the 1970s and 1980s if the
government price interventions had, on the whole not depressed the
prices received by the farmers [Hamid, Nabi and Nasim (1990)].
Substantial potential for agricultural growth still exists because
a large part of the increase in agricultural output in the past has come
from enormous increases in availability of inputs, especially water and
fertiliser. On the demand side the substantial scope for import
substitutions in wheat and edible oil will help overcome the constraint
from slow growing economy. The improvements in efficiency have been
relatively limited and irrigated yields per hectare have shown only
modest increases over long periods. The important exceptions were the
dramatic increase in cotton yields during the 1980s and wheat and rice
yield improvements in the second half of the 1960s.
Pakistan's reliance on an extensive pattern of development in
agriculture becomes clear from large increase in water availability of
over 3 percent per annum during the three decades 1960-90 attributable
both to the extensive use of private tube-wells to exploit ground water
resources and large public investments in water storage and irrigation.
The construction of Mangla and Tarbela Dams and the large-scale Indus
Basin replacement works in the 1960s and early 1970s not only reduced
the variability in water availability but also added to total supplies
from the irrigation system.
Sustainability of past pattern of agricultural growth is in serious
doubt because Pakistan cannot expect major increases in water
availability in the foreseeable future. No investments in storage of
water are underway at the moment and, in any case, large projects like
Kalabagh Dam would take a decade to complete once initiated. Ground
water development through private tube-wells may be reaching a
saturation point. Future agricultural growth will have to come from
improving the efficient use of major inputs such as water and fertiliser
as well as greater agricultural diversification.
What can the state do to promote productivity growth and better
allocation within agriculture? (8)
In terms of incentives, there is still moderate negative effective
protection for wheat and very high positive protection for sugarcane.
The continuation of support prices for wheat, cotton and rice makes some
sense because the system does, by and large, work. In case of smaller
crops the price supports are not effective. In the case of sugarcane the
government intervention is definitely harmful to national interests and
serves mainly the interests of sugar mills. A dismantling of the entire
system of sugarcane supports, at least as national policy, will improve
efficiency of resource use in agriculture though it will meet tough
resistance from vested interests
More effective use of water resources would require substantial
increases in water charges, coupled with investments in improvement of
delivery, efficiency of irrigation, and appropriate on-farm investments
in land levelling, etc. At present, water charges cover less than 50
percent of operations and maintenance costs of irrigation system, let
alone recovery of capital cost. Thus, there are insufficient incentives
to conserve water and undertake on-farm investments. A sharp increase in
water charges and an earmarking of these additional funds for better
maintenance of canals will have a high economic pay-off.
There are serious problems with the quality of inputs especially
seed and pesticides distributed by the private sector. This is an ideal
area where more effective government regulation will be helpful.
Last but not least, improvement in the technical efficiency with
which agricultural inputs are used would also require strengthening of
human resource base in agriculture. Low rate of literacy and low levels
of education are a major drag on agricultural productivity.
The two broader issues relating to agriculture i.e. land reform and
agricultural taxation need also to be mentioned. Land reform, however,
desirable from the point of view of longer term productivity and equity
in agriculture is simply not likely to happen because of current
political realities and the power of landed interests. Pakistan's
experience under the last two land reforms also is not very encouraging
in terms of land that could actually be release for redistribution. It
is, therefore, more fruitful for public policy to focus on the issues of
agricultural taxation. If income taxation of agriculture, which is a
provincial subject, cannot be made effective and chances are that it
cannot be the Federal government must give serious consideration to the
imposition of a sizeable land tax on all holdings above 25 acres both to
mobilise revenue and to force a more efficient use of land resources under large holdings. Strong discrimination in favour of small and
medium scale farmers in the provision of credit will also further the
interests of equity and growth.
REMEDYING THE PAST NEGLECT OF EDUCATION
Pakistan has seriously neglected investment in human capital and
has paid the price for it not only in persistently high population
growth for a long period but also slowing rate of growth. As a result of
slow progress in education especially basic education, the adult
literacy rate is only 37 percent and the illiteracy among women is as
high as 75 percent. Current gross primary enrolment ratio of about
two-thirds compares unfavourably with both India and Bangladesh.
Furthermore, the quality of primary education is extremely
unsatisfactory. Drop out rates are high and among those who complete
primary school less than half can actually read, write, and do
arithmetic. The low level of literacy is a major drag on modernisation
of agriculture and industry and a constraint on the efforts to reduce
population growth.
To exploit fully the elements of Pakistan's long term economic
strength mentioned above (a declining population growth rate and greatly
underutilised agricultural potential) a much greater commitment to human
development and much more effective public interventions in education
are required. Remedying the past neglect of education is an important
goal in itself but has become absolutely critical in the context of
global economic challenges of an information age.
There has been a notable acceleration in primary enrolments and a
substantial narrowing of the gender gap in basic education during the
last decade and policy actions and investment allocations have become
more focused as a result of SAPI (1994-98). But as the stories about
ghost schools and phantom teachers suggest, there are substantial
leakages from the expenditures. More generally, the government does not
recognises the financial, management and institutional capacity
constraints which stand in the way of expanding and improving the
quality of education. It therefore, does not appear to be ready to deal
with them forcefully and once again the goals may be frustrated. For
instance, the new education policy has set the totally unrealistic
target of raising the present 2.2 percent allocation of GDP for
education to 4 percent by 2003, assuming in addition that the GDP will
grow at an average rate of 7 percent per annum over 1998-2003. The 20
percent annual growth in real education spending is totally beyond reach
because of fiscal problems and slow growing economy.
Fortunately, at least elementary education (up to grade 8) requires
relatively modest resources: the present spending on elementary
education is only 1.3 percent of GDP. A growth in real spending of 8-9
percent annually on elementary education will be sufficient to meet the
goal of universal primary education in ten years. (9) This will require
only a modest increase of 0.5 percent of GDP in public spending on
elementary education. (10)
The organisational and management problems in basic education are
much more critical than the mobilisation of additional resources. The
present policies have four major weaknesses: a centralist bias,
overemphasis on buildings on buildings, overloading of the curriculum
and last but not least lack of continuity and high professional
excellence of managers in education. The experience with SAP I clearly
indicates that the efficiency of resource use remains a major problem. A
better balance between the recurrent expenditures (teachers'
salaries, text books, and teaching aids) non-recurrent spending
(buildings and equipment), rationalisation of staff deployment,
adjustment of teachers' staffing to changes in enrolment, reduction
in teacher absenteeism can go a long way in improving the effectiveness
of public education spending at all levels. But these necessary
improvements can be achieved only with a high degree of political
commitment and excellence and continuity of administrative leadership in
education, the two conditions which are not met yet.
Increasing the basic level of education, improving its quality and,
increasing literacy are the most urgent social goals. But Pakistan
cannot ignore the problems with the higher level of education which
remain the key constraint on development of new industries such as
electronics and information technology. Improvement in the coverage and
quality of higher education requires a three-pronged attack: further
development of institutions of excellence; greater autonomy and/or
privatisation of public institutions, especially beyond the secondary
level; and increasing effective competition between the private and
public sectors in provision of education beyond the middle school level.
There are a few institutions of higher learning in Pakistan which have
attained international standards and acceptance. But their number is
woefully inadequate and their impact on the society is rather limited.
Government should remove obstacles in the way of development of further
private universities and should give them some preference in the
allocation of land. The management load on public sector education is
generally extremely heavy. There is no reason why in the spirit of
decentralisation financially viable or potentially viable public sector
colleges should not be made autonomous or turned over to non-profit
NGOs. This will ensure greater community involvement as well assist in
mobilisation of resources for the future. Finally, there is little
effective competition between the educational institutions in the
private and public sectors. Public sector institutions charge extremely
low fees and provide low quality education. Private colleges and
universities, on the other hand, assure a minimum quality of education
but charge fees which can be hundred times that of public sector
institutions. Under the present circumstances, there may be an element
of monopoly rent enjoyed by many private educational institutions,
especially those run on commercial lines. Raising both the level of fees
and the quality of education in the public sector institutions will help
to increase the competition between the public and private sectors.
Greater efficiencies in both sectors would help lower the present high
cost of private education.
DEFINING A NEW COMPACT WITH THE PRIVATE SECTOR
Perhaps for the first time in Pakistan's history there is a
clear consensus within the government that the private sector is pivotal
for development because the state sector is seriously over extended
financially, has become increasingly inefficient and cannot provide the
effective leadership for modernisation of the economy. While increased
public investment in physical infrastructure and human capital will be
needed it is private sector investment (both domestic and foreign) which
will be the engine of growth. But there is much less recognition both
within the government and the private sector that a well-defined new
framework is needed for long term cooperation between the public and
private sectors. Indeed, just as in the past, the private sector appears
to have been pre-occupied in obtaining tax and other concessions from
the government to revive industrial capacity, which may no longer be
economic. Meanwhile the government has been pushing ahead with
privatisation, financial sector reform, and export and tax policy
changes, many of the elements needed for a re-invigorated private sector
but without defining the latter's new responsibilities.
In our view a new compact needs to make it explicit that private
sector performance will be judged not only by the expansion in output
and exports but also by its contribution to savings, creation of jobs,
tax revenues and the modernisation of the economy. The present private
sector appears to be ill equipped to think in strategic terms and
paradoxically may need help from and a dialogue with the government to
develop the necessary capabilities and remove constraints. In the short
to medium term the private and public sectors need to work jointly on
defining and agreeing on policy goals and strategies in areas such as
export development, modernisation of agriculture and industry, skills
development, legal and regulatory framework, an effective and elastic
tax system and development of financial sector and capital markets.
Hopefully in due course the private sector will gather strength and
sophistication and the state role in economic areas can be limited to
setting broad directions of policy, macro-economic management, and all
forms of regulation (including utilities, environmental and financial
regulation).
For the near future the public and the private sector need to
develop a new partnership to foster the country's economic and
social goals. This will not be easy given the past history of public
sector mistrust of the private sector and private sector heavy reliance
on the patronage of the government for subsidies and economic rents.
What is required is a change in the mindset on both sides so that an
effective new relationship can evolve. The Nawaz Sharif Government with
its pro business bias has excellent credentials for setting the tone of
the new relationship but it needs to make sure that the private sector
clearly understands that the strong policy and institutional support for
its activities will have to be balanced with a new respect for and
conformance to tax laws and financial, environmental, and other
regulation. Also, though the private sector cannot be formally held
responsible for the social goals such as adequate job creation, skills
development, and environmentally friendly growth, it must recognise that
the range of economic freedoms it will like to enjoy will endure only if
the society can deliver sustained and equitable growth. A backlash from
unbridled capitalism cannot be ruled out in Pakistan. There need not be
any major conflict between national objectives and self-interest of the
private sector in the long run. But in the past the private sector in
Pakistan has been excessively concerned with short run profitability.
This has been partly the result of political instability and
unpredictability of policies but the private sector has also not always
concerned itself with structural problems or long term possibilities.
The present circumstances present a unique opportunity to make a new
beginning.
Liberal economic policies, which are a central element of a new
framework for the private sector are largely already in place. But the
experience of the 1990s suggests that the domestic private sector has
moved slowly to bring about structural changes in industry and exports,
has increased relative dependence on borrowing to finance investments,
and has continued to look to state patronage to make easy profits [Hasan
(1998)]. Hopefully this will change with a clearer articulation of the
new relationship between the state and the private sector. However, more
direct attention should also be paid to the issues, which may stand in
the way of rapid modernisation of both agriculture and industry. One
factor, which could hold back progress towards rapid development of
labour intensive, manufactured goods exports is the present built in
bias against large-scale production. Modern sector industrial employment
has grown little during the last few decades. Large scale production is
not necessarily superior to small scale operations but in
Pakistan's case the flight from large scale industry has not been
triggered by efficiency considerations but rather has been motivated by
the desire to evade labour and other regulations which were perceived to
have become excessively stringent. In the process not only tax
collection but also productivity and quality control have suffered
hampering exports. There is urgently need for analysis and review which
will remove any policy obstacles in the way of expansion of the large
scale sector. Such a review of the regulatory framework should include
small and medium scale industries which also remains excessively
regulated.
In terms of broad regulation and control of the private sector,
three critical areas are banking sector, the capital markets, and tax
administration. In the area of financial and capital markets regulation,
the Nawaz Sharif government has followed the lead of the caretaker
government and greatly increased the independence of the State Bank of
Pakistan in formulating monetary policy and strengthened its powers for
control and regulation of the financial institutions and has created an
independent Securities and Exchange Commission to oversee joint stock
companies and the capital markets institutions such as the stock
exchanges. Meanwhile, the new managements of remaining state owned
commercial banks have been charged to prepare them for speedy
privatisation. Hopefully a financial system which is largely private
owned but strongly regulated by the central bank will accelerate the
mobilisation of financial savings and improve the allocation of credit
by cutting costs of financial intermediation and reducing bank losses
resulting from politically motivated lending. But a change in the
financial system will also require a change in culture which can only be
brought out gradually. The State Bank of Pakistan will have a crucial
leadership role in creating this new culture of independence with
accountability in the financial sector because of its large regulatory
authority. Similarly the new Securities and Exchange Commission can
through the exercise of its regulatory authority can help to increase
confidence in the functioning of joint stock companies and capital
market institutions and thus help direct savings to the modern sector. A
strong and politically independent tax authority should be the third
institutional pillar of the regulation of the private sector. Such an
authority, by fair but forceful implementation of tax laws and policy,
can not only ensure a steady revenue growth but can through increased
insistence on documentation and reduced tax evasion help promote a
greater measure of trust in the accounts (balance sheets and profit and
loss statements) of the domestic companies thus further supporting the
processes of effective mobilisation and use of domestic savings.
FOCUSING ON IMPLEMENTATION AND INSTITUTIONAL REFORM
A measure of agreement on broad priorities, discussed above,
already exists among policy-makers, the principal exception being the
macro-economic adjustment path because there remains a great a lack of
realism on growth, savings and investment targets. But even an agreement
in principle on reform in key areas such as education, family planning,
and tax administration is not very meaningful without a forceful
implementation of the reform programme. In Pakistan failures of plan and
programme implementation have been frequent and even more serious than
policy failures. How can implementation and monitoring be made more
effective in the future especially in areas such as education and tax
administration?
First and foremost there must be the political will to stay the
course of unpopular and painful economic decisions. However, this
political will cannot exist without a broad national consensus on
economic and social priorities. This will require that public leaders
take the public in confidence, educate them about economic realities and
assure them that the costs of adjustments will not be disproportionately
placed on the lower income groups. It also requires that economic
adjustment programmes enjoy bi-partisan support and difficult economic
issues such as downsizing of government adjustments of administered
prices and tightening of tax administration are not unduly exploited for
political purposes.
Second, public institutions dealing with development must be given
new respect and authority. The measures to reduce corruption and enforce
accountability must not be allowed to further undermine the morale of
honest and hardworking civil servants. Reduced political interference in
day to day administration of public bodies can go a long way in
improving their effectiveness.
Third, the analytical capacity to examine policy options and
monitor progress must be strengthened across the board, in public and
private sectors, universities, and research institutes. Pakistan has not
developed strong traditions of academic freedom and excellence. The
economic and social reform agenda was driven excessively by
international agencies and their research financing during the last
decade. As a result, continuity in analytical work was not assured,
domestic ownership of the programmes remained weak and the task of
public education was not given must attention. In the age of
globalisation and rapid technological change, the transfer of ideas and
learning from experience abroad have become increasingly important.
However, the quick assimilation of international experience and
effective utilisation of foreign advice can be done only if the
indigenous research and policy institutions are strong and independent.
At present, the development of adequate analytical capacity in economic
and social fields is either seriously hindered by lack of resources or
driven largely by foreign funding. Just as in physical investments,
Pakistan needs both to raise the level of investments in intellectual,
research and policy endeavours and become more self-sufficient in
financing them. Policy reform is an ongoing process which requires close
monitoring and frequent adjustments. Without a strong analytical base in
domestic institutions, Pakistan's reform drive will not have strong
chances of success.
Fourth, the balance of government effort between planning and
goal-setting, on the one hand, and monitoring and implementation on the
other, needs to be tilted in favour of the latter. At present, there is
excessive preoccupation with goal-setting and the little attention is
being given to effective follow up, redressal, and course adjustment.
Enormous amount of energies continue to be devoted to the preparation of
five-year plans and related documents and not enough resources are
available to ensure that implementation problems are solved in a timely
fashion. After more than forty years of five-year plans, the credibility
of the planning processes is low not only in the public but also in the
bureaucracy. Successive plans have clearly not succeeded in solving
deep-rooted structural problems. In order to restore the credibility of
planning mechanisms and government goals, it is essential to adopt
realistic targets and to focus the implementation efforts on critical
policy areas such as savings, exports, education, and population control
where policy failures have been endemic.
Finally, on the institutional front progress will be closely tied
to the resolution of governance issues. Civil service reforms, steps to
curb corruption, and decentralisation efforts will all contribute to
increasing the efficiency of public servants while reducing the leakage
of public funds and waste of public resources. Improving the
effectiveness of the use of public resources will in turn make a direct
contribution to relieving the financial constraints which have become so
binding in recent years.
SUMMING UP
Pakistan's economic crisis is much more deep seated than the
government appears willing to admit. Both the structural and the
financial problems have been building up for a long time. The heavy
burden of debt, reflected in the debt to GDP ratio of nearly 100
percent, the low level of educational attainments, and major weaknesses
in the structure of industry and exports are problems which will
continue to influence economic prospects adversely for a number of
years.
The gravity of these problems must be recognised by policy-makers
and it should be realised that there are no quick fixes to the
predicament in which Pakistan finds itself. The government undercuts its
own credibility both at home and abroad when it promises a quick and
relatively painless economic turn around because the nature of economic
difficulties i.e. unsustainable level of dependence on external
resources, an inequitable pattern of growth, neglect of longer term
investments in human and physical capital, and broad institutional
decline are widely known and understood.
Pakistan needs a longer term economic vision not only to deal
effectively and confidently with short-term difficulties but also to
carefully choose the priorities which will shape a better and more
equitable economic future. But it also needs to come to terms with its
past of missed opportunities and inequitable pattern of growth. It also
has to brace itself for a difficult period of economic and financial
adjustment.
If short term costs are accepted by the society and political
governance can be improved, two big ifs, it would be quite feasible for
Pakistan to achieve per capita GNP growth of 4 percent per annum over
the next twenty five years, double the average rate in the last half
century, and combine it with a better distribution of growth benefits.
No long term economic policies will work if Pakistan does not
restore financial equilibrium. The reduction of the ratio of national
debt to GDP from nearly 100 to around 70 percent over the next five
years needs to be made a top national priority. This will mean keeping
fiscal and current account balance of payments deficits to very low
levels at least till 2005 and overall investment rate is likely to
stagnate. Whether the fiscal and balance of payments adjustment can be
made consistent with longer term goals and reasonable GDP growth in the
medium term will depend on three things, the ability of the tax system
to mobilise large additional resources through direct and expenditure
taxation, the greater effectiveness in the use of resources in the
public sector and the ability of the industrial sector to use the
substantial real exchange rate adjustment in 1998-99 for diversifying
and expanding exports. The form of fiscal and balance of payment
adjustment will be as important as the reduction in deficits. Fiscal
deficit reduction should not come at the cost of development spending.
Thus, a dramatic improvement in public savings is needed (from a
negative 2 percent of GDP to a positive 2 percent over the next few
years) and this can happen only with a sharp improvement in the tax: GDP
ratio and continued restraint on defence spending. Similarly, the
containment of balance of payments deficit, will prove consistent with
increase in imports and recovery in growth only if exports expand.
Declining population growth rate, which is likely (with strongly
supportive policies) to average 1.5 percent annually over 2000-25,
almost half the rate of the last twenty five years and the considerable
potential for improving factor productivity in agriculture (which in the
past has relied heavily on increasing supplies of irrigated water and
fertiliser) are two fundamental reasons for my optimism.
The success in agriculture, family planning as well as
modernisation and diversification of exports and industry will depend
critically on investments in education. Plan for the education sector
need to show greater financial realism and much more awareness of the
serious problems with the quality of education at all levels. While
resources for elementary education should be found at all cost to ensure
speedy attainment of universal primary education, the managerial
problems are even more serious even at the basic education level.
Increasing the basic level of education, improving its quality and,
increasing literacy are the most urgent social goals. But Pakistan
cannot ignore the problems with the higher level of education which
remain the key constraint on development of new industries such as
electronics and information technology. Improvement in the coverage and
quality of higher education requires a three-pronged attack: further
development of institutions of excellence; greater autonomy and/or
privatisation of public institutions, especially beyond the secondary
level; and increasing effective competition between the private and
public sectors in provision of education beyond the middle school level.
Liberal economic policies, which are a central element of a new
framework for the private sector are largely already in place. But the
experience of the 1990s suggests that the domestic private sector has
moved slowly to bring about structural changes in industry and exports,
has increased relative dependence on borrowing to finance investments,
and has continued to look to state patronage to make easy profits. The
present private sector appears to be ill equipped to think in strategic
terms and paradoxically may need help from and a dialogue with the
government to develop the necessary capabilities and remove constraints.
In the short to medium term the private and public sectors need to work
jointly on defining and agreeing on policy goals and strategies in areas
such as export development, modernisation of agriculture and industry,
skills development, legal and regulatory framework, an effective and
elastic tax system and development of financial sector and capital
markets.
Effective management and implementation of policies is even more
important than plans as such. In Pakistan failures of plan and programme
implementation have been frequent and even more serious than policy
failures. Unless implementation and monitoring can be made more
effective in the future especially in areas such as education and tax
administration, there cannot be much hope for achieving economic goals,
however sensible. This requires progress on the institutional front
which is closely tied to the resolution of governance issues; civil
service reforms, steps to curb corruption, and decentralisation efforts
will all contribute to increasing the efficiency of public servants
while reducing the leakage of public funds and wastage of public
resources
The final point is that while future policies need to focus both on
growth and distribution issues, many economic and social policies can
have a positive impact on both growth and distribution and good results
can often be mutually reinforcing. The reduction of population growth
will increase per capita income growth, reduce poverty and help future
growth through its positive impact on savings. Investments in human
capital (especially the education of women) will contribute to slowing
population growth, will have salutary effects on growth and exports
(through raising productivity), and will help poverty alleviation by
reducing the number of dependent children. Financial sector reform will
stimulate savings and improve the allocative efficiency but also will
prevent the abuse of the credit system which bestowed unearned benefits
on those with preferred access. Better tax policies and administration
will help resource mobilisation but through creating a fair and elastic
tax system can provide the underpinnings of a much-needed expansion in
social expenditures and also contribute to moderating income
disparities. Exports of labour intensive manufactured goods will create
jobs, increase export earnings, help growth and reduce reliance on
foreign capital.
If the Pakistan elite and politicians manage to do a better job of
political governance and economic management in the first two decades of
the 21st century than in the last half century, the past policy mistakes
can be written off to experience.
Comments.
1.
Dr Qureshi asked me to comment on a paper by my old friend and
ex-colleague Dr Parvez Hasan, which he said was entitled "Pakistan
at the Threshold of the 12th Century." When I wrote that I knew
nothing about mediaeval Pakistan, could it be a typing error for the
21st century, Dr Qureshi insisted in his reply that it is the 12th
century that I had to discuss. I assumed it was at least the 12th
century AD, not BC. Roads having been iced up and non-negotiable where I
live, and no packages being delivered, I clued myself up on 12th century
Pakistan. Had I delved into BC, I would have had to talk about Mohenjo
Daro in NW Sindh and Harappa in Punjab, when in 2,500-1,500 BC the Indus
Valley civilisation flourished there.
The NW of the Indian subcontinent corresponds to today's
Pakistan. There were invasion routes through the Khyber, Gumal and Bolan
passes from Central Asia to the heartland of India. For thousands of
years invaders and adventurers swept down on the settlements there. In
712 the Muslim Arabs appeared and conquered Sindh and by 900 they
controlled most of NW India. They were followed by the Ghaznavit and
Ghorid Turks. The first Turki invaders reached Bengal c. 1200 and an
important Muslim centre was established, mainly through the conversion
of the Hindus. The NW was overrun many times before it became part of
British India in 1857. It was overrun by the Persians (1730s) by the
Afghans who held Sindh and Punjab during the latter half of 18th century
and by the Sikhs. And so I would have gone on, had not the paper arrived
finally. I saw with considerable relief that, pace Dr Qureshi, it had
been a typing error after all, and that I was to discuss the threshold,
not of the 12th, but of the 21st century.
My first visit to Pakistan was with Barbara Castle in the winter of
1965. She had been the first British Minister of Overseas Development
with Cabinet rank. An interesting moment of the tour, but for reasons
different from those intended by the Pakistanis, was Mrs Castle's
visit to Naudero where she met the President and the Foreign Minister.
Naudero, situated in Upper Sindh, is the centre of the Bhutto
family's sphere of influence, and the President was spending a few
days there shooting in the company of close friends and advisers. The
glamorous but disquietingly feudal scene of wealth and good living, with
a background of security officers and motorcades of armed police and
military, emphasised the regime's identity with the landlords, big
businessmen, upper civil servants and the military forces. There was a
vivid human and physical contrast between the eupeptic tweed-clad
grandees of the President's shooting party, and the gaunt, lanky,
forelock-touching Sindhi peasantry (most of them poor sharecroppers) who
thronged the narrow streets of Naudero, submissively and
uncomprehendingly, to watch us all arrive.
It is sad to reflect that things have not changed much in Pakistan
in the 36 years that have passed since our visit. For a while in the
late 1960s, Pakistan was help up as a model to the Third World,
replacing the earlier enthusiasm for Indian planning. I remember another
Barbara, Barbara Ward, lecturing enthusiastically about the tube wells
installed in Punjab and Mrs Castle being impressed by the practical,
down-to-earth efforts of Pakistani women at family planning. They would
pull IUDs from under their saris, to Barbara Castle's delight. She
contrasted this with a meeting with the Indian Planning Commission, with
which her natural sympathies could have been expected to lie. But,
instead of getting down to practical matters, the members of the
Commission with Ashok Mehta in the chair, waffled sentimentally about
the good old days of Fabian socialism and the writings of Brailsford in
the New Statesman. The contrast between the ideology of the Indians and
the good practical sense of the Pakistanis was striking. But this
wonderful, promising Pakistan momentum was not kept up. I agree with Dr
Hasan's analysis and recommendations. Following Mahbub ul Haq, in
whose memory Dr Hasan's lecture is delivered, the emphasis in
policy-making should be on the following principal issues.
Mass primary and secondary education, especially of girls, should
have top priority. It is content should be relevant, so that they can
later enter the labour market and also be better mothers. Linked with
education should be measures to promote better nutrition and health. At
the same time, higher technological education should not be neglected.
It is important in order to remain competitive in exports.
It is often claimed that the resources are not available. But there
are plenty of resources to be found in reducing defence expenditure (in
1998 it was 4.8 percent of GDP); from loss-making public enterprises,
and from unnecessary prestige projects. The Pakistan government can use
the proceeds of privatisation for reducing the internal debt, and use
the saved interest payments for increasing and improving social
services.
Job opportunities should be created, for example by
labour-intensive exports. Correct pricing of labour, capital and the
exchange rate is a precondition. Credit for small businesses is an
important component of an employment strategy.
Finally, government should be cleaned up and corruption eliminated.
Dr Hasan says that land reform is not politically likely to happen, but
it is surely time for the taxation of landowners.
The only point on which I should like to register a mild
disagreement is Parvez Hasan's use of the expression
"political will." Frequently authors from different schools,
in the good company of Dr Hasan, attribute poor policies to "lack
of political will." But it is futile (or tautological) to say that
the political will is lacking. It is an expression that should, in my
view, be banned from political discourse. One does not have to be a
behaviourist to think that behaviour is the manifestation of will.
Sometimes a student comes to a teacher and says, "Sir, I cannot
concentrate." A stupid teacher would say to him; "Well, you
must make yourself concentrate; you must have the will to
concentrate." But if he does not have the will, he cannot have the
will to have the will, etc. If the will to action is lacking, there is
no point in asking for the will to have the will to action. This only
leads either to an infinite regress or to the charge of hypocrisy.
Saying one good thing and doing something bad is called hypocritical. It
is a case of ignotum per ignotius. Political will itself should be
subjected to analysis, and, for purposes of action, to pressures and to
mobilisation. It is more fruitful to think of how to create a political
base for policies that promote efficiency, equity and liberty; how to
build up pressure groups, how to mobilise the poor, how to shape
reformist alliances, how to recruit coalitions for progress, how to
strike bargains, achieve compromises, forge compacts, resolve conflicts,
or permit their tolerance, how to use persuasion, when to offer
compensation to losers when total gains exceed total losses, etc. Such a
normative political economy holds out great promise.
Paul Streeten
Department of Economics, Boston University, USA.
2
Dr Parvez Hasan has presented a comprehensive and balanced paper to
highlight some of the repercussions of ad hoc and inadequate economic
policies in Pakistan. The cumulative outcome of these failures has
manifested itself in the large domestic and foreign debt which now
stands at 100 percent of GDP against 55 percent for India, decline in
per capita income from 3 percent in the 1960s to 1.1 percent in the
1990s, crisis of confidence generated by the deteriorating law and order
situation, by corruption, and by the declining trust of the smaller
provinces in their equidistance from the federal structure. Investment
climate has suffered a sharp set-back due the freezing of foreign
currency accounts and the rough treatment meted out to the independent
power producers. The paper makes a fair assessment of the achievements
and failures of different regimes. It is well to remember that the so
called golden era of 1960s had many glaring weaknesses, some of which
have been identified by the author, such as excessive reliance on
foreign aid, low domestic savings, inadequate attention to the social
sectors, heavy protection to domestic industry. This was the also the
time when crony capitalism made a quantum jump in the industrial
structure nurtured by the rents from the system of macro-management an
aspect that could have justified more emphasis. Bhutto's
nationalisation policies and their impact on the investment climate are
well covered, though the large investments made in the public sector
which helped economic growth in the future have been left out of focus.
Similarly the heavy defence expenditure under Zia appears to have
escaped attention. The lack of institution building and failure of the
home grown supply side economics to kick start the economy reflect a
fair judgement. The author has rightly concluded that the country now
faces a major growth crisis.
The response to the crisis covers diverse areas such as, further
decline in population growth rate, more emphasis on agriculture,
expanding education and improving its quality, structural reforms in
banking and capital markets, more emphasis on personal taxes (which
presently amount to only 10 percent of total taxation), a plea for
capital gains tax, institutional reform and in contrast to the current
policy stance of the government, a more aggressive approach to exchange
rate adjustment. I agree with much of this analysis.
One could also accept the view that a measure of inequality can be
tolerated in the initial stages of development. I would however hasten
to add the following qualifications.
(a) Equidistant policies and a level playing field for all actors
on the economic stage.
(b) Reduction of rent seeking opportunities.
(c) Competitive markets.
(d) A merit based selection system.
(e) Equality of opportunity reflected in vertical mobility.
The author expresses optimism on the slow down in population
growth. It would be appropriate to add a caveat.
--The impact of the high rate of growth experienced earlier would
last well into the next century.
--Immediate cognisance should be taken of the problem emerging on
the supply side, as only 39 percent of the demand for family planning
services is currently met. This deserves the highest priority in
allocation of financial and management resources.
While the author recognises the importance of water resources
development for agriculture, I would also draw his attention to the
serious issue of water mining in Balochistan where the water table is
going down by 1 meter per annum, undermining the sustainability of
horticulture which has been the vanguard of Balochistan's
prosperity. Secondly the cost of the irrigation system has been taken on
an integrated basis, but the real problems of subsidy arise primarily
from the tubewells. The operative costs of canal irrigation are
recovered to a large extent. The deficit on the side of tubewells is
high. Additionally, the amortisation of the capital costs of canal
system have never been even contemplated. Another problem which has been
suffered benign neglect relates to the large windfall gains accruing to
the landowners in the areas opened to canal irrigation. There has always
been a dramatic increase in the land values and output levels in the
areas opened to canal irrigation. But these gains have never been tapped
for state revenues. The fourth problem is the neglect of the drainage
needs at the time the irrigation system was laid out. This subsidy
granted by history (or the Ministry of Finance) to the earlier
generations, has had to recovered from the present generation.
The author's emphasis on education is well taken, though it
must be reiterated that the real challenge is not investment but in the
field of quality assurance and management. There is a growing
realisation of this, but it has come late because the aid giving
agencies are prone to the measurement of progress by the level for
financial disbursements. Secondly the time has come to prepare a master
plan for the expansion of primary education, because in the category of
boys schools we may already be close to optimal levels in quantitative
terms. The cut off in terms of population coverage should be defined and
translated into a spatial plan for provision of public sector schools.
Proper evaluation of the mosque schools and the non-formal schools
catering to the drop outs and trying to cover 5 year curriculum in 3
years should also be organised.
As regards private sector, the importance of a well defined policy
framework and its proper application at the ground level is well
articulated. In fact we need an optimal balance between regulation and
promotion. A viable trade off has yet to emerge. The tradition of heavy
reliance on loans and thus having capital structures that are highly
geared, has been responsible for the plight of our industry which cannot
easily service loans in times of recession. The issue of crony
capitalism has not been fully addressed. Loan recovery mechanism are
undoubtedly important, but it is even more important to ensure that
loans are not granted on the basis of pressure and influence. Similarly
the openings for rent seeking have not been fully identified or
investigated. It is vital to do so, if we have to move towards a
competitive economic structure.
On the author's observation that in the 1990's our
external debt has increase considerably, from 35 percent of GDP in 1990
to 55 percent of GDP in 1998, he might as well ask the power
structure--what happened to our grandiose claims of self-reliance?
On foreign currency accounts I agree with Dr Parvez that the
premium for foreign exchange cover is concessional, not covering the
average devaluation of 10 percent experienced in the recent years. This
is a subsidy. But the assumption of a higher level of devaluation at the
time budget making is an issue that goes far beyond foreign currency
accounts. The budgetary implications of a higher exchange rate
adjustment, in term of debt service, defence imports, wheat import costs
(therefore wheat subsidy) import costs of POL, if duly reflected, would
substantially enlarge the fiscal deficit, forcing recourse to higher
taxation or sharp reductions in expenditure, including development
expenditure. This prompts a tendency to take a more optimistic scenario
as the basis of budget estimates. Of course a part of the uncovered
margin in exchange rate, would be affected in the budget in the form of
reduced dividend from the State Bank, which decline when actual
devaluation is higher than the level assumed at the time of budget, but
the overall impact of assuming a higher exchange rate would be greater
on other counts. This has led to a tradition of soft budgeting, a short
sighted policy.
The author has taken a rather kindly view of devaluation, but there
are many in the country who do not share his easy optimism on this
account. I am sure the other point of view would be articulated during
the debate. What we need to emphasise is that devaluation in basically a
pricing instrument. The weaknesses of our exports go beyond the issue of
pricing. We should guard against the tendency to offer price adjustments
as a compensation of our failures in the fields of factor productivity,
quality control, effective marketing, and the absence of the right
technologies. Such compensatory mechanisms may condemn us to the dustbin
of a low price low quality syndrome.
As regards fiscal deficit, the instrument of expenditure reduction
may already have reached its limits. We should worry more about the
declining tax to GDP ratio, about the lack of buoyancy in provincial
taxes, about sharing costs when revenues cannot be quickly expanded.
Also there should be more emphasis on the revenue deficit, because this
measure the extent to which we are borrowing money for current
consumption. Our revenue deficit has already reached Rs 129 billion.
Preoccupation with fiscal deficit tends to blur the vision on the
growing revenue deficit. We should also begin to consider the growing
payroll in the public sector. The number of government employees has
already crossed 2.5 million nearly five time the strength of Pakistan
Army. Another aspect not touched upon is the changing pattern of
financing. There is an increasing recourse to short-term borrowing, to
commercial loans, to the kerb market. These quick fixes harden the debt
profile and delay the necessary structural adjustments.
Another area requiring more attention is the dollarisation of the
economy. This is a subject that deserves a special in-depth study and
case histories are available in the Latin American models. It was
believed that the freezing of foreign currency might close this chapter,
but new accounts are now being opened and some local transactions are
still being carried out in dollar terms. The longer term implications of
this process need to be brought out by the academia.
Finally, we cannot discuss the trends in the next century merely in
terms of a linear projection of the past trends in our economy, because
we are on the threshold of profound qualitative changes that might
overtake, perhaps overwhelm us. With weak institutions, an archaic
private sector, and slow response mechanisms, our susceptibility to
future shock is high. Some of these changes are already being discussed
and analysed in the futuristic literature. The rapid advances in
information technology and the consequent marginalisation of regulatory
mechanisms has immense implications. What would be the effects of
business in cyberspace on our fiscal system which stands isolated from
it? Would the state die of fiscal starvation as some have predicted? The
emerging pressures of globalisation on the economic side and the growing
articulation of sub-national grievances and aspirations of the
subnational entities may place the state machinery in a straitjacket for
which it lacks the coping capacity. The autonomy of the international
financial market and the enormity of its size, with transactions at the
level of $1.3 trillion per day, is a development which even the most
powerful economies may find difficult to handle. What would happen to
small and structurally weak economies like Pakistan? The breath-taking
pace of technological change and the vanishing blue collar worker,
offers uncomfortable prospects for countries with low level of education
and a large illiterate labour force is something that we have not even
contemplated so far. At the same time the disappearance of our
traditional role models such as Japan and East Asian tiger economies,
increases manifold the strains of adjustment. I hope these areas would
be debated during the discussion that follows the main presentation.
With these few words I would like to conclude and look forward to the
answers to some of the issues that have been raised in the paper and in
this intervention.
Saeed Ahmad Qureshi
Formerly Deputy Chairman, The Planning Commission, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Hamid, Nabi, and Nasim (1990) Quoted in Parvez Hasan,
Pakistan's Economy at the Crossroads: Past Policies and Present
Imperatives. Karachi: Oxford University Press, p. 265.
Hasan, Parvez (1998) Pakistan's Economy at the Crossroads:
Past Policies and Present Imperatives. Karachi: Oxford University Press.
Hasan, Parvez, and D. C. Rao (1979) Korea: Policy Options for
Long-Term Growth. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. p. 152.
NIPS (1998) Pakistan Fertility and Family Planning Survey 1996-97.
Islamabad: National Institute of Population Studies, January.
Pakistan, Government of (1997-98) Economic Survey 1997-98. Table
13.2 p.120. The Male and Female Data has been Combined Using their Ratio
in the Labour Force.
Young, Kevin, Willem Bussink, and Parvez Hasan (1980) Malaysia,
Growth and Equity in a Multi-Racial Society. Baltimore: John Hopkins
University Press. p.131.
(1) The government has set an ambitious target of universal primary
education by the year 2006. But this target is likely to be missed not
so much because of financial difficulties but rather institutional
capacity and managerial constraints.
(2) Pakistan (1997-98). The male and female data has been combined
using their ratio in the labour force.
(3) With an annual average growth of 4 percent per annum, it will
take per capita GNP twenty eight years to treble.
(4) The analysis behind these calculations makes the further
assumptions of 8 percent domestic inflation and an average devaluation
of 6 percent per annum to compensate for the difference between Pakistan
and international inflation rates.
(5) This analysis is based on discussion with Sultan Hashmi, a
Pakistan authority on demographic trends.
(6) These numbers were quoted by Attiya Inayatullah, a leading
figure in family planning in Pakistan, at a conference held at the Human
Development Centre in Islamabad in April 1997.
(7) See footnote 3 in Table 1.
(8) In making the following suggestions, I have benefited from a
discussion with Shafi Niaz, a well-known expert on agricultural policies
in Pakistan.
(9) See footnote 3 above.
(10) It is assumed that annual GDP growth over the next decade will
average a modest 5 percent.
Parvez Hasan is a former Director and Chief Economist of the World
Bank.
Table 1
Two Scenarios of Economic and Financial Adjustment Figures
as Percent of GDP
Years 1989-90 1997-98 1998-99
GDP Growth 4.6 5.4 3.1
Investment 18.1 17.2 14.9
National Savings 13.6 12.0 11.1
Foreign Savings (2) 4.5 5.4 3.8
Public Savings (3) -0.6 -2.0 -1.7
Private Savings 14.2 14.0 12.6
Government Revenues 18.6 16.0 16.5
Tax Revenues 14.0 13.0 12.0
Total Public Spending 25.7 21.5 21.2
Defence 6.8 4.8 4.5
Interest 5.4 6.9 7.0
General Administration 1.4 1.4 1.3
Other Non-Development 5.6 5.4 5.4
Development 6.5 3.0 3.0
Fiscal Deficit 6.5 5.5 4.7
Years 2003-2004 1999-2004
A B
GDP Growth 4.0 (1) 5.0
Investment 16.0 16.8
National Savings 14.0 14.8
Foreign Savings (2) 2.0 2.0
Public Savings (3) 0.5 2.0
Private Savings 13.5 12.8
Government Revenues 17.5 19.0
Tax Revenues 14.5 15.5
Total Public Spending 21.0 22.0
Defence 4.0 3.8
Interest 5.7 5.6
General Administration 1.3 1.3
Other Non-Development 6.0 6.3
Development 4.0 5.0
Fiscal Deficit 3.5 3.0
Sources: Economic Survey 1997-98 and author's estimates and
assumptions. The marginal saving rate is assumed at 20 percent
in the scenario A and 25 percent in scenario B. See also footnote 8.
(1) The GDP growth rates figures in both scenarios A and B are
assumptions relating to the five year period 1999-2000 to 2003-4.
(2) Defined as current account balance of payments deficit.
(3) Defined as excess of consolidated public revenues over
current expenditures.