Can cost-effective reallocation of inputs increase the efficiency of the public health system in Pakistan?
Hasan, M. Aynul ; Pasha, Hafiz A. ; Rasheed, Ajaz M. 等
Heavy investment in many developing countries in the social sector
including health is based on the premise that human capital is vital to
the growth and development of a nation. However, Pakistan's
spending on this sector has been one of the lowest in the region. In the
present environment of high budget deficits, one does not expect
substantial public funds to be forthcoming and diverted towards the
social sector in the intermediate- or medium-term future. The critical
issue facing the public sector should then be to design health policies
which must be cost-effective and efficient. This study examines these
health policy issues within the context of an optimisation framework for
public health system, forecasts future upto (2002-03) and discusses an
efficient optimal mix of health inputs, outputs, expenditures, and wage
policies under alternative scenarios. The study recommends that, first,
growth of health infrastructure building in the urban areas be slowed
down in the short-term (two to three years), and some of the resources
reallocated towards the rural sector either in terms of building new
Basic Health Units or upgrading the existing Rural Health Centres.
Second, not only attractive wage policies be formulated for health
personnel, but the status of nurses in the public health system be also
elevated by giving them higher grades, Third, for every rupee of
development expenditure incurred, Public Health Department must plan or
keep provisions for recurring outlays. All this reallocation of
resources is feasible within the projected actual budget and it will
lead to efficiency gains in the order of 8 to 10 percent for the entire
public health system.
1. INTRODUCTION
In recent years, many developing countries have invested heavily on
the social sector including basic health. This is based on the premise
that human capital is vital to the growth and development of a nation.
Therefore, keeping the mass healthy is as important as providing them
with basic education. Pakistan has had an impressive GDP growth rate of
about 8 percent per annum in 1991-92, out of which only a meagre 0.7
percent was spent on the health sector. When this figure is translated
in monetary value it amounts to only 7 cents per thousand dollar GNP spent on the health sector. This amount is very little by any standard
and, in fact, the picture is even more dismal when this figure is
compared with those of other developing countries.
Table 1 shows the percentage of total government expenditure on the
health sector in relation to government expenditure and GNP for selected
developing countries. Of the eight countries selected for comparison,
Bangladesh and Sri Lanka appeared to have spent 4.8 percent of their
government expenditure on health as opposed to only 1 percent by
Pakistan. Even a small, poor country like Nepal spends more money (4.7
percent) than Pakistan on the health sector. In the list of countries
considered, Pakistan's standing in terms of spending on health
(either as a proportion of government expenditure or GNP) is the lowest
which is very discouraging and disappointing. Although, Pakistan's
spending for this sector is one of the lowest in the region, in the
present environment of high budget deficits faced by the country, the
critical issue facing the public sector should then pertain to designing
health policies which must be cost-effective and efficient. A recent
study by the World Bank on Pakistan's Health sector 1991) noted:
... inefficiency is widely regarded as a central problem in the
health and population sectors in Pakistan ... (especially) in the
public sector. Resources are misallocated, in part because no
investigation has typically been made into the cost-effectiveness
of various options. Political influence and leakage of equipment
and supplies further distort public sector allocations. Poor
management and centralised financial, administrative and management
authority reduce the efficiency of facility-level staff services.
The major policy debate, in this context, facing the public health
system in Pakistan, should then address the problem of re-allocating the
limited resources among inputs in the most economical way. In other
words, given the limited available budget, should the public health
department (PHD) go for a more infrastructure programme (development
expenditure) or hire more health personnel (recurring expenditure) or a
combination of both so that there is a real improvement in the health
services? Or, even more importantly, what type of wage policy should it
adopt if more personnel are needed to work in rural health centres
(RHCs), basic health units (BHUs) and hospitals, especially when there
are shortages of competent nurses and doctors in the country?
Furthermore, if, historically or even in the future, there is more
emphasis on development expenditure i.e., rapid expansion of BHUs or
RHCs especially under the recently initiated Social Action Programme
(SAP), (1) what implications will this programme have on recurring
budget? Will the present health system in the country be able or capable
of handling such an accelerated expansion of facilities? That is, given
the present institutionally fixed wages and inelastic supply of health
personnel, will the health system be able to attract enough doctors or
nurses? All these public policy issues are critical for the
sustainability of the basic health programme in Pakistan and they cannot
be addressed in isolation. In this context, a general optimisation
framework for the Public Health System (PHS) is needed if the efficient
cost-effective input-output linkages consistent with the resource
(budget) constraints and institutionally fixed wage policies are to be
established.
In view of the above considerations, therefore, the objective of
this study is:
(a) To develop a general optimisation framework in order to address
the policy issue of cost-effectiveness and efficiency for the public
health system;
(b) based on the above theoretical framework, to identify and
forecast an optimal mix of cost-effective inputs (doctors, nurses,
paramedics), outputs (outdoor and indoor patients) wages and expenditure
requirements (both recurring and development) of PHS covering up to the
end of the Perspective Plan period, 2002-2003; (2) and
(c) to estimate and compare the extent of efficiency gains/loss for
PHS under alternative assumptions.
The organisation of rest of the chapter is as follows. Section 2
develops a simple optimisation model for the public health system and
then formulates propositions under alternative assumptions (e.g.,
constrained strategy etc.). In order get an intuitive insight, we first
illustrate the model using a diagram and then in Section 2.1 and 2.2 the
analytical derivations and conditions of the model to achieve positive
efficiency gains for health facilities are presented. Section 3 presents
the discussion on simulation results and ensuing policy implications.
Before discussing the simulation results, we also report parameter
estimates for input supply and production functions for Punjab in
Sections 3.1.1. The discussion on ex-ante simulation results are
presented in Sections 3.1.2 while the policy conclusions are given in
Section 4.
2. DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH OF A SIMPLE OPTIMISATION PUBLIC HEALTH
MODEL
In the following, we develop a theoretical optimal allocation model
for the health sector under institutionally fixed wage rates for health
professionals. In order to keep the analysis simple and, at the same
time, realistic, we assume that the health facility produces output
[e.g., total patients treated (Q)] using two inputs, namely,
infrastructure [represented by beds (B)] and medical professionals
[e.g., doctors (D)]. In addition, the supply of personnel is assumed to
be inelastic as there does not exist an unlimited inflow of doctors and,
especially at the institutionally set low wage rates, many of these
health professional are reluctant to offer their services to the public
health system. The public sector is assumed to be able to set the wage
rates of doctors and other government personnel (supposedly below the
market rate) because their share (in terms of total expenditure) within
the health sector is very large. Thus, the public sector, represented by
the provincial health department (PHD) in this case, can be labelled as
a monopsonist. Due to limited public funds allocated to the health and
other social sectors, the basic task of PHD (acting as a monopsonist) in
this context is to maximise the output of the health facility subject to
the available budgeted resources (TC). Assuming a well behaved production technology, c as the unit cost of a hospital bed (B) and as
the fixed wage rate for doctors, the optimal health input allocation
problem of PHD can be illustrated with the help of a diagram as given in
Figure 1.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Essentially, the diagram consists of isoquant (Q) and isocost (*)
curves for various combination of Bs and Ds. With institutionally fixed
wages for doctors and unit price per beds (c), the initial isocost line
is given by [C.sub.0] with slope (=-w/c) in Figure 1. It is, however,
important to note that not all points (particularly [E.sub.0], on the
broken portion of [C.sub.0]) on this isocost are feasible. Given the
inelastic supply of doctors, the number of professionals offering their
services will simply not exceed [D.sub.0]. Therefore, the initial
equilibrium in this case will be established at [E.sub.0] as shown in
Figure 1, which is neither efficient nor optimal even though the
available budgeted resources are completely utilised. Here obviously,
more beds and fewer doctors are employed to produce an inefficient
[Q.sub.0] level of output [i.e., patients treated].
On the other hand, however if PHD adopts a more flexible wage
policy and allows the wage rate of doctors to increase from * to
[w.sub.1]. then the availability of doctors will increase from [D.sub.o]
to [D.sub.1]. It is interesting to note that even though the isocost
line has pivoted inwards (due to higher wages) form [C.sub.0] to
[C.sub.1], the output (patients treated) however, has increased from
[Q.sub.0] to [Q.sub.1]. In fact, the new equilibrium level attained at
[E.sub.1] is at a higher isoquant which is both optimal as well as cost
effective. (3) The above simple example leads us to make the following
proposition that:
Proposition 1: It is possible for the public health policy-maker to
be cost efficient and, at the same time, achieve a higher output (in
terms of more patients treated) even with the same available budget
provided the public sector adopts a flexible wage policy (close to the
market wage) for health professionals (be it doctors, nurses or
paramedics).
2.1 Optimisation Conditions under a Monoposonistic Public Health
System
It was argued earlier that the monopsonistic equilibrium output,
such as [E.sub.2] in Figure I, will not be feasible under an
institutionally fixed wage system. However, in order to explore
alternatives (other than flexible wages) under which the monopsonist PHD
may achieve equilibrium at a higher output level, we explicitly need to
derive the first order conditions (FOCs) of the present health system.
By comparing these FOCs with those of the standard competitive producer
we may be able to establish the extent of divergence between them and
thus propose the condition(s) which will lead to an improvement in the
output for PHD.
Assuming the supply of doctors as a function of wages [D=D(w)] and
output [patients treated (Q)] being produced by doctors and beds, the
optimisation problem of the monoposonistic PHD will simply entail the
maximisation of the following:
Max: Q = Q[D(w);B]; ... (1)
subject to: [bar.C] = wD(w) + (m + c)B; ... (2)
where [lambda] is the unit recurring cost per bed. Other variables
in the above model are as defined earlier. Writing the lagrangian
function of the above, we get:
P(w,B,[lambda]) = Q|D(w);B|+ [lambda]|[C.sub.0] - wD(w)-(m + c) ...
(3)
where [lambda] is the Lagrangian multiplier. The maximisation of
the above Lagrangian will yield the following three first order
conditions (FOC):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
[partial derivative]p/[partial derivative]/B = [partial
derivative]Q/[partial derivative]B = [partial derivative]Q/[partial
derivative]/D - [lambda](c + m) = 0; ... (5)
[partial derivative]p/[partial derivative]/[lambda] = [bar.C] - wD
- (c + m)B = 0; ... (6)
From the first two FOCs, we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
If we define the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS)
between doctors and beds as:
MRT[S.sub.D,B] = [partial derivative]Q/[partial
derivative]/D/[partial derivative]Q/[partial derivative]/B; ... (8)
and the elasticity of supply of doctors with respect to wages ( )
as:
[[xi].sup.S.sub.D] = w/D x [partial derivative]D/[partial
derivative]/w; ... (9)
then the above optimisation problem of the monopsonistic PHD will
require that
[MRTS.sub.D,B] = w/(c + m) [??] 1 + 1/[[xi].sup.S.sub.d] [??]. ...
(10)
The above optimisation condition simply states that, for the
monopsonistic PHD, [MRTS.sub.D,B] should not only be equated to the
ratio of relative prices [w/Cc+m)], as is the case for the standard
competitive producer, but it should now be equated to a weighted
relative prices of doctors and beds. The weight factor simply includes
the supply elasticity of doctors ( ). It is interesting to note that,
depending on the magnitude of ( ), the above optimisation condition for
monopsony can be equivalent to that of the competitive producer. This
leads us to make our second proposition that:
Proposition 2: The optimal condition (s) for the monopsonistic
producer (PHD) can be equivalent to those of the competitive producer as
long as the price (wage rate) elasticity of supply of the monopsonistic
input (doctors) is infinitely elastic.
Whether or not the above proposition is valid in the case of PHD is
a matter of empirical investigation and we relegate this to the next
section where we report our results on estimated elasticities for
inputs.
2.2 Efficiency Gain/Loss for the Monopsonistic PHD Producer
Based on a simple model constructed earlier we can also
analytically compute and compare the efficiency gain/loss (in terms of
output) of the monopsonistic PHD under alternative scenarios. Suppose
that, at a given point in time, the actual allocation of inputs by PHD
is such that the size of the infrastructure in the form of beds (B) is
greater than that of the optimal monopsonist. In the following, we can
demonstrate that halting or reducing the growth of infrastructure
building and optimally reallocating the resources towards health
professionals may lead to an improvement in the health facilities. In
fact, what is more interesting now is that the monopsonist PHD with
fixed beds (named as constrained monopsonit) will be able to achieve an
even higher level of output as compared to the standard monopsonist.
If we define [O.sub.c.sup.*] and [O.sub.s.sup.*], respectively, as
the optimal level of outputs for the constrained and standard
monopsonist, then the expression for efficiency gain/loss (E) can be
written as:
E = [[O.sub.c.sup.*]/[O.sub.u.sup.*] - 1] x ... (11)
Obviously, a positive value for E will lead to an efficiency gain
in favour of the constrained monopsonist and vice-versa. By substituting
the optimal values for [O.sub.c.sup.*] and [O.sub.s.sup.*] (obtained
from the optimisation model) in the above equation, we can obtain an
explicit expression for E.
If the supply elasticity and the share of doctors ([[pi].sup.D])
and nurses (([[pi].sup.B]) are assumed to be fixed in magnitude as a
simplifying assumption and the production function is assumed to be
Cobb-Douglas, then the two optimal outputs (standard and constrained)
and their corresponding input demand functions obtained through the
optimisation procedure can be written as : (4)
Standard Monopsonist
[O.sup.*.sub.s] =
[A.sub.o][([D.sup.*.sub.s]).sup.[alpha]][([B.sup.*.sub.s]).sup.[beta]];
... (12)
[B.sup.*.sub.s] = [[PI].sup.B]/(m + c)([bar.C] + c[B.sub.-1]); ...
(13)
[D.sup.*.sub.s] = [[[[PI].sup.D]([bar.C] + c[B.sub.-1].sup.Y/1+Y];
... (14)
Constrained Monopsonist
[O.sup.*.sub.c] =
[A.sub.o][([D.sup.*.sub.c]).sup.[alpha]][([bar.B]).sup.[beta]]; ... (15)
[D.sup.*.sub.c] = [([bar.C] - m[bar.B]).sup.Y/1+Y]; ... (16)
where [gamma] is the supply elasticity of doctors and [alpha] and
[beta], respectively, are the output elasticities of doctors and beds.
Substituting these optimals, we get the following explicit expression
for E which contains entities that are either exogenous [e.g., . and
[bar.B]] or fixed in values [e.g., share of doctors ([[pi].sup.D]), m,
and c]:
E = [[([bar.C] - m[bar.B])/[[PI].sub.D]([bar.C] +
c[B.sub.-1])].sup.[alpha]] x [([bar.B]/[B.sup.*]).sup.[beta]]; ... (17)
Thus, for E to be positive (implying positive efficiency gains),
the above equation should be written as:
(w[D.sub.c.sup.*]/w[D.sub.s.sup.*] >
[([B.sub.s.sup.*]/[bar.B]).sup.[beta]/[alpha]] ... (18)
This leads us to make our third proposition that:
Proposition 3: Constrained monopsonist PHD with fixed
infrastructure (beds) may have positive efficiency gains (E>0)
relative to those of a standard monopsonist as long as the fixed number
of beds (B) exceeds the optimal ([B.sub.s.sup.*) and, at the same time,
the total allocation of expenditure on doctors by the constrained
monopsonist is greater than that of the standard case.
These three propositions have important implications for public
health policies and they are summarised below:
(a) In general, given limited budgeted resources available, a
proper cost effective allocation between recurring (health professional)
and development expenditures (infrastructure) can lead to higher
efficiency gains for health facilities.
(b) In the case where PHD acts as a monopsonist and there is an
inelastic supply of health professionals, adopting a flexible wage
policy rather than institutionally set wages may not only attract more
of these professionals but it is also possible to attain a higher output
for the health system which will be both cost effective and efficient.
(c) In the even that the existing allocation of infrastructure
(beds) exceeds the optimal level, than a policy of consolidating the
infrastructure and diverting the limited available resources towards
recurring outlays can lead to efficiency gains which, in fact, will
exceed those of the optimal cost effective producer.
In order to test these theoretical propositions and also to obtain
the size and magnitude of these efficiency gains for PHD, next section,
as an example, develops an empirical simulation model based on combined
provincial data for Pakistan.
3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS FOR PUBLIC SECTOR HEALTH
This section reports simulation forecast results, both historical
and ex-ante, based on optimisation strategies subject to available
resources for the public health system in Pakistan. Estimated optimal
mix of expenditures on inputs in this context will be efficient and also
cost effective. Thus, a comparison of the actual available data on
health output with the forecasted values will enable us to compute the
efficiency gain/loss for alternative optimal health policies. In
addition, the simulation forecast results will provide us with an
opportunity-to test the validity of the propositions made in the
previous section.
Long-term forecasts generated by the model covering up to the end
of perspective plan period 2002-03 will be useful for policy-makers in
establishing the optimal requirements of physical health inputs (e.g.,
doctors, nurses, paramedics and beds), expenditure allocations (both
development and recurring) and the wage policy under alternative health
strategies.
3.1. Simulation Results for the Public Health System
In this section, we report estimated simulation results based on an
extended model developed for the public health system. The basic
parameters (e.g., elasticities, output share, etc.) used for simulation
purposes, in this study, were estimated employing health sector data on
Punjab (5). Since there is a plethora of numbers generated by the
simulation model, in order to describe these numbers more effectively,
only the broad policy oriented results are discussed in the main text.
3.1.1. Estimated Wage Elasticities and Production Functions
Estimated ordinary least squares (OLS) parameter values of the
supply function for health professionals based on RHFs and UHFs of
Punjab are given in Table 2. The supply function for each professional
included its respective wage rate and the number of registered
professionals.
Since the function used is in logarithmic form, the parameters
estimated in this context simply represent elasticities. For instance,
in case of doctors in RHFs, the estimated parameter value of 1.47 in
Table 2 represent the doctors' supply elasticity with respect to
wage rates. Analysing the results in Table 2, it is interesting to note
that health professionals in UHFs have inelastic wage elasticities (less
than one). This implies that these professionals, in most cases, will be
less than enthusiastic in offering their services in response to a wage
rate increase. These wage elasticities (less than one). This implies
that these professionals, in most cases, will be less than enthusiastic
in offering their services in response to a wage rate increase. These
results have important implications in terms of interpreting the
propositions made earlier. Obviously, with an inelastic supply of health
professionals, an institutionally fixed wage policy will not be copious enough to attract them towards the public health system.
Table 3 reports the estimated parameter values for health output
(patients treated) production functions of both RHFs and UHFs. These
estimated regression results in Table 3 indicate that, for both RHFs and
UHFs, the role of infrastructure (in terms of large parameter values for
beds as compared to other inputs) in the production process is more
dominant than other remaining inputs, namely, health professionals.
Analysing the health problem on the basis of production function alone,
in this case, may suggest that resources be diverted towards building of
infrastructure in order to improve health facilities. However, it should
be noted that a production function approach may tell us only about the
technical efficiency of the inputs.
Whether a technically efficient input is also cost-effective from
the entire health system point of view can be established if the problem
is analysed within a broader optimisation framework where the available
cost constraints are also considered. Inputs derived from the
optimisation approach will not only be optimal but, more importantly,
they will be cost-effective. Distribution of health inputs through this
optimisation principle will ensure the allocative efficiency of the
health system. In the next section, we first discuss the historical
optimisation simulation results and then present the ex-ante results.
3.1.2. Ex-ante Forecast and Efficiency Gain/Loss (1992-2003)
Based on the estimated supply and output elasticities from Tables 2
and 3, respectively, and exogenously given profile for total cost and
total stock of registered health professionals, we can now directly
compute the optimal expansion paths for inputs, and output for both UHFs
and RHFs using the reduced form expressions derived from the
optimisation problem. (6)
Tables 4-6 show that there were more beds for urban hospitals than
they should have had in 1992 if the system had operated under a
cost-efficient approach. A pertinent public policy question that may
arise in this context is what should the PPHD do or what options are
available to them so that there is a real improvement in the system in
terms of positive efficiency gains? Obviously, one thing PPHD possibly
cannot or should not do, is to dismantle its existing infrastructure. In
fact, in future, the growth in infrastructure building programmes (in
terms of new hospital beds) undertaken by PPHD should be slowed down or
perhaps halted at the current level. Adopting such a policy will enable
the PPHD to achieve the optimal mix of inputs in due course of time so
that with each year gone by the population growth and the normal wear
and tear of capital will gradually bring the existing number of beds
closer to the optimal value.
In the following we present ex-ante simulation results, relying on
two strategies: (a) standard strategy based on normal optimisation
approach adopted earlier; and (b) constrained strategy based on an
optimisation problem in which the beds in UHFs are now fixed at the
baseline year 1992 level until they become equal to those of the
standard strategy. The simulation results for health personnel and
infrastructure, wage structure and efficiency gain/loss based on both
standard as well as constrained strategies are reported in Tables 4-6.
It should be noted that the future data under the headings of
actual in Tables 4-6, do not exist in published documents. They are,
however, generated in this study by simply taking the annual compound
growth rates of the past five to ten years of actual historical data on
these variables. The underlying behaviour in projecting these actual
data is predicated on the presumption that the Public Health Department
continues to follow the future course of actions based on their health
policies and practices of the recent past in matters concerning setting
wages, hiring health professionals, annual development plans, etc.
Comparing these actual data with the simulated ones generated by our
optimisation model will not only enable us to examine the extent of
divergence between optimal and sub-optimal health inputs within and
across different health facilities but, more importantly, the above
analysis will allow us to compute the size of ex-ante efficiency
gain/loss of the optimal approach by simply calculating the yearly
percentage deviation between optimal and actual outputs of a given
health facility.
Considering 1991-92 as the baseline year, future projections are
made up to the end of the Perspective Plan period (2002-03). In
addition, forecasts for all monetary variables are measured in current
rupees. Having computed the actual projected data on health inputs
(between 1992-93 to 2002-03) based on the methodology explained above,
the corresponding actual health output variable is generated using the
underlying estimated production technology parameters reported in Table
3. (7)
Focusing on the board policy issues, the ex-ante simulation results
reported in Tables 4-6, reveal several interesting facts that have
important implications for public Health Policies in Pakistan. The
salient features of the results are summarised below:
Infrastructure
* Actual number of beds in UHFs in the baseline year 1991-92
appeared to be greater than what an optimal optimisation strategy would
stipulate by over 13 percent. However, by the end of the perspective
plan period (2002-03), this figure may come down to about 10 percent as
shown in Table 4. It is important to note that if the public Health
Department (PHD) were to adopt a policy of slowing down the growth of
health infrastructure (in terms of beds) and re-allocate the existing
resources then our results suggest that it is possible for the PHD to
attain an efficiency gain of about 11 percent for UHFs in 1994 as
reported in Table 6.
* Furthermore, the re-allocation of resources from urban health
development expenditure may take place not only towards other urban
recurring activities (e.g., more medicine and health personnel) but,
interestingly enough, these resources can now he diverted towards rural
health facilities. In fact, our analysis suggests that some of these
funds Could be transferred towards the development of rural
infrastructure (in terms of either upgrading BHUs to RHCs or outright
construction of new BHUs).
Health Personnel
* In terms of health personnel, the optimisation model predicted a
faster growth for doctors in RHFs during the entire plan period (about
11.1 percent p.a.), which is to be induced by raising their salaries by
a substantial amount particularly in the earlier years (over 15 percent
in 1993) as shown in Table 5. However, once enough doctors are attracted
towards RHFs, the model predicts modest salary increases towards the
latter part of the plan for the health system to be cost-effective.
* As for the doctors in the UHFs, cost-effective strategy suggests
roughly the same number of doctors as the actual but with significantly
higher salaries by the end of the plan period by about 11 percent as
shown in Table 5. This result can be rationalised since, in urban areas,
enough opportunities and alternatives are available to the doctors (in
private hospitals or clinics). Thus, to improve urban health facilities
in the long run, PHD should hire fewer good-quality doctors and pay them
well.
* If PHD were to pursue its wage policies for nurses at the
existing pattern, then the optimisation model predicts severe shortages
of nurses to the extent of over forty-two percent in 1992 as reported in
Table 4. Shortages will persist even at the end of the plan period
2002-2003. This excruciating situation of nurses in the present set-up
in Pakistan is due to a combination of many factors. Obviously, one of
the important reasons is the present low salary structure and, in this
regard, the optimisation model suggests an immediate boost in
nurses' salary by over 26 percent as shown in Table 5. Another
reason is the social stigma attached to this profession particularly in
the public sector health system in Pakistan. It needs to be emphasised
that, even in the Defence Medical Services in Pakistan, nurses are not
only paid reasonable salaries but, more importantly, they are accorded
an honourable status in the military hierarchy. For instance, a nurse
would begin her career in the Armed Forces as a commissioned officer
while, in the public health system, the starting level is only at the
BSP grade 11 that is far below the category of an officer (BSP-17).
Expenditure Pattern
* The critical public policy issue that deserves some discussion in
this context is the availability of funds to meet the future recurring
expenditure obligations for the health system. Our optimisation model
predicts recurring outlays of over 5 and 2.5 times that of development
expenditures for UHFs and RHFs, respectively, in 1992-93. These figures
are expected to remain high until the end of the Perspective Plan
period. Many plans formulated in the past emphasised the establishment
of infrastructure in terms of opening new hospitals, RHSs, and BHUs
without giving due consideration towards the recurring expenditures
[e.g. health personnel and other inputs (medicine, x-ray films, etc.)].
What is crucial for the long-term sustainability of the Public Health
System is the commitment from the policy-makers for provision of steady
inflow of funds to meet recurring expenditure.
Efficiency Gains
* A crucial part of our analysis in this study is to investigate
whether by becoming more cost-effective it is possible for the Public
Health Departments to improve their provision of basic health
facilities. The optimisation results in Table 6 suggest that about ten
percent efficiency gains can be made in UHFs and RHFs. In fact, our
simulation results in Table 6 clearly supports the proposition made
earlier that, by reallocating resources within UHFs from development to
recurring expenditures, reasonable efficiency gains of over ten percent
were attained in 1994. The efficiency gains for the combined health
system were also in the order of eight to nine percent.
4. CONCLUSION AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS
Pakistan's share of total health expenditure to gross national
product has never exceeded 0.8 percent per annum [Economic Survey
1992-93], which is significantly lower than many of its neighbouring
countries in the region. If the future is any reflection of past
history, then one does not expect substantial public funds to be
forthcoming and diverted towards this sector in the immediate or medium
term future especially when the country is already experiencing large
increasing budgetary deficits. Prudent public policy research in this
context, based on a realistic pragmatic approach, should then be geared
towards an investigation into measures to improve the present Public
Health system (PHS) through an efficient, cost-effective reallocation of
health inputs within the existing limited budget. This study has
examined these health policy issues within the context of an
optimisation framework for PHS and forecasted future (up to 2002-03)
efficient optimal mix of health inputs (doctors, nurses, paramedics),
outputs (patients treated for urban and rural health facilities),
expenditures (development and recurrent) and wage policies (health
personnel) under alternative scenarios. Comparing the projected actual
health output (based on historical growth rates) with those of optimal
values, efficiency gains were also computed. Based on these simulation
results, this study makes policy recommendations for PHS and some of the
important ones are summarised below:
* Our optimisation model predicts an excess build-up of
infrastructure (measured in terms of beds) in the present urban health
facilities while, in the rural areas, there is a paucity of RHCs and
BHUs. We recommend that the growth of health infrastructure building in
the urban areas be slowed down in the short-run (two to three years) and
some of the resources be reallocated toward the rural sector either in
terms o building new BHUs or upgrading the existing RHCs.
* Our optimal forecasts suggest that both more nurses and doctors
should be hired in UHFs and RHFs, respectively, during the entire plan
period though in terms of percentage, the demand for nurses will exceed
that of doctors in RHFs. We recommend that not only attractive wage
policies be formulated for these personnel but, more importantly, like
the Armed Forces, the status of nurses in the Public Health System be
elevated by giving them higher BSP.
* There is a shift in focus from development towards recurring
expenditure a predicted by the optimisation model. It is, therefore,
recommended that for every rupee of development expenditure incurred,
PHD must plan or keep provisions for recurring outlays. This is critical
from the point o view of long-term sustainability of PHS.
It is important to note that all this reallocation of resources is
feasible within the projected actual budget and, interestingly enough,
it will also lead to efficiency gains in the order of 8 to 10 percent
for the entire Public Health System.
Comments
I commend the authors for attempting to analyse rigorously the
economics the public health sector in Pakistan. The main conclusions are
that channelling more resources to personnel, nurses, and doctors and
less to infrastructure for the same total cost will result in more
output of about 8-10 percent. I do not necessarily disagree with the
authors' conclusions, but I recommend that we should treat these
conclusions with extreme caution and as highly tentative. This is
because the study suffers from several conceptual problems and employs
highly questionable assumptions and data set.
The paper starts out by lamenting on the meager resources that are
devoted to the public health sector. Statistics on health as a
percentage of GNP for some neighbouring and other countries are provided
with the purpose of showing the dismal state of relative expenditures on
health in Pakistan. At this point I was expecting that the authors would
go on to forcefully argue for more expenditures be allocated to public
health. Instead, the authors' objective turns out to be of finding
whether the health sector is economically efficient with the meager
resource that it gets.
The framework employed is the neoclassical optimisation problem
whereby the health sector maximises output with respect to the various
inputs subject to a budget constraint. Remember we are talking about the
public sector here and not the private sector. The equilibrium solution
to this problem determines the optimal amounts of health personnel and
output in each time period. While the framework employed is more
elaborate, it is the same one that I used in my paper entitle,
"Optimal Resource Utilisation in Pakistan Agriculture"
presented at the third PSDE Meetings, Khilji (1986). There are some
methodological differences though among these papers. My paper focussed
on the private agricultural sector and not on the public sector. It
allowed equilibrium to be reached over several periods instead of
assuming that equilibrium is reached in each period as in this paper. My
paper allowed the output elasticities, with respect to the various
inputs, to vary over time instead of the constant elasticities assumed
in this paper.
In terms of efficiency, the authors are never clear of what type of
inefficiency they are referring to. According to the quotation from the
World Bank study which they present on the first page, inefficiency is
due to, "Political influence and leakage of equipment and
supplies.... Poor management and centralised financial, administrative
and management authority..." These notions of inefficiency are
different than what the authors model, The paper talks about allocative
inefficiency due to the monopsonistic power of the public health sector,
which is assumed rather than proved. Employing isoquant and isocost
curves in Figure 1, the authors painstakingly explain that a fixed wage
for doctors below a market determined wage would bring in fewer doctors.
This will result in less output for the same cost. All this is familiar
to undergraduate students in economics. There are many ways the same
point is normally made. Price and wage ceilings result in misallocation
of resources. This is a proposition that we teach our first year
students and is not as novel as is presented in Proposition I of the
paper. However, the question arises, what is the source of inefficiency?
Is it an institutionally fixed wage or is it the monopsonistic power of
the public health sector. Instead of worrying about isoquants and
isocosts, which are rather cumbersome, the point can be equally made by
using the familiar supply and demand diagrams. Figure 1 below does just
that.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The figure presents the market for doctors. D is the demand curve
by the public health sector for doctors and S is the supply of doctors
at various wage rates W. The wage [W.sub.pc] is the market clearing wage
where supply is equal to demand. It would result in [N.sub.pc] amount of
doctors hired per period of time. Since D is also the Value Marginal
Product (VMP) of Doctors = [Price.sup.*] Marginal Product of Doctors,
[N.sub.pc] amount of doctors coincides with [D.sub.1] in Figure 1 of the
paper. Output would be [Q.sub.1] which is optimal. The problem with a
monopsonist is that he faces an upward sloping supply curve. This means
that when he hires additional doctors, he has to raise the wage, not
only for the additional doctor, but also for all doctors in his
employment. This gives rise to a marginal factor cost (MFC) for him
which is higher than the supply price of doctors. In order to maximise
output for a given cost, he will equate the VMP of doctors not to the
wage rate but rather additional cost of hiring them which is MFC. This
occurs at point c in Figure 1. The wage that corresponds to MFC at point
c is [W.sub.m] which is what the monopsonist will pay. At this wage only
[N.sub.M] doctors will be willing to work. [N.sub.M] doctors corresponds
to [D.sub.0] in Figure 1 of the paper where the wage rate < VMP of
doctors resulting in sub-optimal amounts (from the economy's
stand-point) of doctors and output. The reason here for allocative
inefficiency in the economy is the monopsonistic power of the producer.
The point of presenting all this is to show that both
institutionally fixed wages below the market clearing wages or monopsony
elements lead to inefficient allocation of resources. For example,
[W.sub.m] could be either institutionally fixed or can be the result of
the monopsonist's optimisation behaviour The effects will be the
same. The paper moves back and forth between these two. Moreover this is
a far cry from what the World Bank study had in mind about leaks,
political influence, and poor management. These types of inefficiencies
would be hard to put in the optimisation framework employed in the
paper.
I wander why the paper wastes so much time proving Propositions 2
and 3. We all know that if a monopsonist faces an infinitely elastic
supply curve he would not be, by definition, a monoposonist but a
perfect competitor in that factor market. Proposition 3 is also well
known. If you are stuck with a fixed factor higher than the optimal
amount than keeping it fixed and increasing other inputs will result in
higher output than a situation where you start with an optimal
combination of inputs. This has to do with higher marginal products of
the relatively scarce factors.
Let me turn now to the econometrics, solution algorithm, and
simulations in the paper. Unfortunately the paper is not very
forthcoming about any of these matters. In fact it does not even
elaborate on the data employed except to state that it is the health
sector data on Punjab. The other thing we know is that this data is for
the period 1977-1992.
Essentially there are two outputs, one is an index of patients
treated in Rural Health Facilities, and the other is an index of
patients treated in Urban Health Facilities. These outputs are related
to inputs through production functions which are statistically estimated
with inputs as doctors, paramedics, hospital beds, and registered
paramedics. Given these estimated production functions and an exogenous
budget to be allocated for a year, constrained optimisation of output
leads to demand equations for medical personnel for each year. The
supply equations of doctors nurses and paramedics are statistically
estimated. Equating these factors' supplies to their demands for a
particular year provides equilibrium solutions for the amounts of
factors employed and their wage rates for that year. Substituting these
solution values of inputs into the respective production equations
generates values for the two outputs tot the year. This solution
algorithm is repeated each year based on a new budget allocation. The
solution algorithm calculates equilibrium amounts of inputs employed,
wage rates, and outputs each year.
In standard forecasting there are two types of simulations. These
are ex-post and ex-ante simulations. Historical simulations (or ex-post
simulations) involve the comparison of predicted values of inputs and
outputs in the past with the actual values of these variables The
purpose is to check on the forecasting accuracy of the estimated model.
Ex-ante simulations (or forecasts) involve projecting the endogenous variables into the future based on expected values of all exogenous
variables. Since the future has not happened, it is not possible to
check whether the ex-ante forecasts are accurate or not.
The paper performs ex-ante simulations with a twist. The twist is
that it also projects forward, from 1992 to 2003, what the likely values
of the endogenous variables (inputs, wage rates, and outputs) are going
to be based on past growth rates. These are compared with the values
generated from the solution algorithm. This is absolutely bizarre! The
questions is that, are not the estimated input elasticities, and supply
equations based on historical values of the same endogenous variables?
One can understand the use of the word optimal in the ex-ante
simulations. It can be rationalised as follows: Given the existing
structure of production, budget allocation to health, input supply
equations, and assuming that the public health sector wants to maximise
output, then the optimal amounts of inputs, wage rates, and outputs are
the ones that are reported as optimal in Tables 4, 5, and 6. Actual has
no meaning here. except for 1992, since the values are not observed.
If the purpose were to show efficiency gains, would not ex-post
simulations be more relevant? Even if we were to accept the procedure
adopted in the paper, we find that the actual amounts of doctors
employed are higher than optimal for UHFs and for RHFs (for most years)
in Table 4. I thought that the point of the exercise was to show that
because wages of doctors were lower than the competitive wages due to
monopsonistic elements, less doctors were employed than optimal.
Finally, comparison of actual output to optimal output in Table 6 shows
efficiency gains in output of the order of 8-10 percent. This is not
much given that most of the important parameters are statistically
estimated. It would be useful to present the standard errors associated
with these efficiency gains to assess their significance. Even if these
were not calculable, some qualifications about these point estimates
would make sense.
Recently Anne Krueger (1997) remarked that when economists present
empirical results that are favourable to one point of view, politicians,
whose side is flavoured, exploit this result claiming it to be gospel
truth. They do not heed all the qualifications, conditions, and
assumptions the economists may have employed and stated when presenting
their results. Unfortunately no qualifications are put in this paper
making it easier for people to claim that the health sector is
inefficient. There need to be several qualifications put in this paper.
These have to do with the limited data employed, the definition of
output, the statistical estimations of coefficients which are assumed to
stay constant in the future and their associated standard errors.
Additionally, the arbitrary nature of the assumptions about the future
course of budget allocations, and expected inputs, wage rates and
outputs should be emphasised
While this is an elegant and elaborate piece of work, I am sure the
authors would agree that, we should be extremely careful in using the
results reported in this study, especially for policy purposes.
Nasir M. Khiiji
U.S. Bureau of the Census and Economic Adviser
U.S./Saudi Arabian Joint Commission on Economic Cooperation (JECOR)
Riyadh
REFERENCES
Khilji, N. M. (1986) Optimum Resource Utilisation in
Pakistan's Agriculture. The Pakistan Development Review 25:4
469-487.
Krueger, A. O. (1997) Trade Policy and Economic Development: How We
Learn. The American Economic Review March.
Authors' Note: This study was initiated Aynul Hasan was
visiting the Social Policy and Development Centre, Karachi as Senior
Technical Adviser on behalf of the Canadian International Development
Agency (CIDA). He wishes to thank the Agency for providing financial
support for the study. Research assistance and primary data collection
were conducted by Zahid Hasnain, Naveed Hanif, Nooreen Mujahid, and
Nasrul Eman. Any errors are the responsibilities of the authors.
REFERENCES
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Finance Division, Economic Advisors Wings.
Punjab, Government of (Various Issues) Demand for Grants Current
Expenditure.
Punjab, Government of (Various Issues) Punjab Development
Statistics. Lahore Bureau of Statistics.
The World Bank Report (1991) Pakistan Health Sector Study: Key
Concerns and Solution. New York: The World Bank Report.
World Development Report (1991) The Challenge of Development. New
York: Oxford University Press.
(1) In response to donor agencies' insistence, the Government
of Pakistan recently initiated an accelerated Social Action Programme
(SAP), whereby the policy-makers have committed to revamp public
expenditures in certain key areas namely, primary education, basic
health, public health, population planning etc.
(2) In order to undertake long-run planning, Government of Pakistan
prepared a fifteen-year perspective plan covering a period between
1988-89 to 2002-2003, wherein it stipulated targets for all key economic
and social variables including basic health.
(3) It should be noted that [E.sub.2] on the old isocost line
[C.sub.0] is also an equilibrium point for a fixed monosonistic wage
rate which is both efficient and at a higher output level. However, to
attain such a level of output, the producer (PHD) must be able to exert
enough monopsony power to hire the required level of doctors. Here we
argue that such a situation will be difficult if not impossible to
achieve particularly when there are alternatives available to superior
qualified health professionals within (in the private sector) and
outside the country.
(4) Note that the case of constrained monopsonist, since the number
of beds are fixed at [bar.B] ([B.sub.-1]), the budget constraint will
now be changed to * = wD + m [bar.B].
(5) A discussion on data sources, definition of variables, and
ensuing problems and anomalies are reported in a technical Appendix,
which is available on request the authors.
(6) The detailed reduced form for the optimisation problem is
available from the authors on request.
(7) Forecasting the actual health outputs based on the estimated
production function, reported in Table 3, will not be unreasonable as
the predictive power of these equations are very high (99 percent).
M. Aynul Hasan is Professor of Economics, Acadia University,
Wolfville, Nova Scotia, Canada. Hafiz A. Pasha was Deputy Chairman of
the Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad. Ajaz M.
Rasheed is Senior Systems Analyst, Social Policy and Development Centre,
Karachi.
Table 1
Expenditure on Health for Selected Developing Countries
% of Total Govt. % of GNP Spent
Country Expenditure on Health on Health
Pakistan 1 0.002
Bangladesh 4.8 0.007
Nepal 4.7 0.009
India 1.6 0.003
Sri Lanka 4.8 0.014
Indonesia 2.4 0.005
Egypt 2.8 0.011
Philippines 4.2 0.008
Source: World Development Report, 1991-92.
Table 2
Estimated Supply Functions of Health Personnel
Rural Health Facilities
(RHFs)
Variables Doctors Paramedics
Intercept -15.450 -8.108
(-3.572) * (-8.585) *
Doctors 1.472 --
Nominal Wage (1.761) *
Nurses -- --
Nominal Wage
Paramedics -- 1.078
Nominal Wage (3.239) *
Registered 0.759 --
Doctors (1.849) *
Registered -- --
Nurses
Registered -- 0.715
Paramedics (2.021) *
[R.sup.2] 0.969 0.987
DW-test 1.690 1.570
Observations 1977-92 1977-92
Urban Health Facilities
(UHFs)
Variables Doctors Nurses Paramedics
Intercept 0.295 -3.917 -1.587
(0.202) (-3.182) * (-2.149) *
Doctors 0.659 -- --
Nominal Wage (2.258) *
Nurses -- 0.253 --
Nominal Wage (0.440)
Paramedics -- -- 0.498
Nominal Wage (2.909) *
Registered 0.127 -- --
Doctors (0.780)
Registered -- 0.9792 --
Nurses (1.956) *
Registered -- -- 0.271
Paramedics (2.737) *
[R.sup.2] 0.949 0.932 0.976
DW-test 2.386 1.837 2.44
Observations 1977-92 1977-92 1977-92
Notes: 1. Numbers in Parentheses are t-values.
2. Paramedics in RHFs include Nurses and Paramedics.
3. Asterisk indicates significance of the estimated parameters at 10
percent or less level of significance.
Table 3
Estimated Production Functions for RHFs and UHFs
Rural Health Urban Health
Variables Facilities Facilities
(RHFs) (RHFs)
Intercept 1.373 -6.449
(5.205) * (-12.97) *
Doctors 0.129 0.353
(0.929) (8.024) *
Paramedics 0.360 0.290
(3.095) * (4.836) *
Hospital Beds -- 0.701
(6.194) *
RHFs 0.561 --
(1.948) *
Registered Paramedics 0.715
(2.021) * --
[R.sup.2] 0.995 0.999
DW-test 2.297 1.961
Observations 1977-92 1977-92
Notes : (1.) Numbers in parenthesis are t-values.
(2.) Paramedics in RHFs include Nurses and Paramedics.
(3.) Asterisk indicates significance of the estimated
parameters at 10 percent or less level of significance.
Table 4
Health Personnel and Physical Infrastructure:
Ex-ante Forecasts for Standard and Constrained
Optimisation
Year
1992 1994 2003
Urban Health Facility (UHF)
Variables Baseline Standard
Doctors
Actual 23,5528 26,620 45,989
Optimal 22,044 24,842 24,533
% Change -6.31% -6.68% -7.51%
Nurses
Actual 10,981 12,990 27,421
Optimal 15,634 18,249 36,609
% Change 42.37% 40.48% 33.51%
Paramedics
Actual 31,350 34,372 54,572
Optimal 33,458 37,462 62,305
% Change 6.72% 8.99% 14.17%
Beds
Actual 50,138 54,800 81,028
Optimal 43,196 47,480 73,038
% Change -13.85% -13.36% -9.86%
Rural Health Facility (RHF)
Doctors
Actual 10,083 11,913 25,001
Optimal 9,605 11,755 29,179
% Change -4.74% -1.33% 16.71%
Paramedics
Actual 20,900 25,718 64,820
Optimal 22,726 27,273 61,988
% Change 8.74% 6.05% -4.37%
RHF
Actual 1,274 1,442 2,499
Optimal 1,465 1,656 2,879
% Change 14.99% 14.84% 15.21%
Year
1994 2003
Urban Health Facility (UHF)
Variables Constrained
Doctors
Actual 26,620 45,989
Optimal 24,499 42,533
% Change -7.97% -7.51%
Nurses
Actual 12,990 27,421
Optimal 18,120 36,609
% Change 39.49% 33.51%
Paramedics
Actual 34,372 54,572
Optimal 37,016 62,305
% Change 7.69% 14.17%
Beds
Actual 54,800 81,028
Optimal 50,138 73,038
% Change -8.51% -9.86%
Doctors
Actual 11,913 25,001
Optimal 11,516 29,179
% Change -3.33% 16.71%
Paramedics
Actual 25,718 64,820
Optimal 26,782 61,988
% Change 4.14% -4.37%
RHF
Actual 1,442 2,499
Optimal 1,599 2,879
% Change 10.89% 15.21%
Table 5
Wage Structure for Health Facilities: Ex-ante Forecasts for
Standard and Constrained Optimisation
Year
1992 1994 2003
Variable Urban Health Facility (UHF)
Actual Standard
Doctors
Actual 54,303 61,208 103,954
Optimal 49,862 58,070 115,286
% Change -8.18% -5.13% 10.90%
Nurses
Actual 24,438 28,376 55,091
Optimal 30,801 34,630 58,680
% Change 26.04% 22.04% 6.51%
Paramedics
Actual 17,975 20,703 38,753
Optimal 16,155 18,936 38,702
% Change -10.13% -8.53% -0.13%
Rural Health
Facility (RHF)
Doctors
Actual 42,114 47,620 82,041
Optimal 51,389 55,107 75,463
% Change 22.02% 15.72% -8.02%
Paramedics
Actual 16,651 20,240 48,274
Optimal 23,049 25,207 37,698
% Change 38.42% 24.54% -21.91%
Year
1994 2003
Variable Urban Health Facility (UHF)
Constrained
Doctors
Actual 61,208 103,954
Optimal 56,858 115,286
% Change -7.11% 10.90%
Nurses
Actual 28,376 55,091
Optimal 33,678 58,680
% Change 18.68% 6.51%
Paramedics
Actual 20,703 38,753
Optimal 18,505 38,702
% Change
Rural Health
Facility (RHF)
Doctors
Actual 47,620 82,041
Optimal 54,316 75,463
% Change 14.06% -8.02%
Paramedics
Actual 20,240 48,274
Optimal 24,786 37,698
% Change 22.46% -21.91%
Note: Wages are reported in current Pakistani rupees (Rs).
Table 6
Efficiency Gain/Loss for Health Facilities:
Ex-ante Forecasts for Standard and Constrained
Optimisation
Year
1992 1994 2003
Variables Urban Health Facility (UHF)
Actual Standard
Health Output
(Composite Index)
Actual 13,182 17,703 65,288
Optimal 14,288 19,145 71,713
Efficiency (gain/loss) 8.39% 8.15% 9.84%
Rural Health Facility (RHF)
Health Output RHFs
(Patient Treated)
Actual 35,027 41,351 86,448
Optimal 38,055 44,948 95,450
Efficiency (gain/loss) 8.65% 8.70% 10.40%
Combined Health Facilities
Total Health Output
(Composite Index)
Actual 20,664 29,411 74,288
Optimal 22,422 31,882 81,794
Total Efficiency
(gain/loss) 8.51% 8.40% 10.10%
Year
1994 2003
Urban Health Facility (UHF)
Constrained
Health Output
(Composite Index)
Actual 17,703 65,288
Optimal 19,572 71,713
Efficiency (gain/loss) 10.56% 9.8417
Rural Health Facility (RHF)
Health Output RHFs
(Patient Treated)
Actual 41,351 86,448
Optimal 43,703 95,450
Efficiency (gain/loss) 5.69% 10.40%
Combined Health Facilities
Total Health Output
(Composite Index)
Actual 26,154 7,429e+09
Optimal 28,322
Total Efficiency
(gain/loss) 8.29% 10.10%