Economic growth of rich and poor countries: a social accounting matrix approach.
Cohen, S.I.
Many recent empirical studies on comparative growth focus on the
supply side determinants of growth. This paper highlights the insights
to be gained from employing a demand-determined growth model. A
modelling framework along the Social Accounting Matrix, empirically
analysed for a group of sixteen countries at different stages of
economic development, gives support to the convergence thesis.
Keywords: economic growth, convergence, SAM.
1. INTRODUCTION
The well-known data set of real GDP for 130 countries over 35 years
compiled by Summers and Heston (1988), together with population figures
have been used by many economists in studying income convergence
patterns between rich and poor countries: Baumol (1986), followed by
Dowrick and Gemmell (1988); Barro (1991); Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992);
Sprout and Weaver (1992) and Theil and Seale (1994). Taking all rich vis
a vis all poor countries together the statistical material shows that
there is a slight catching up tendency but further disaggregration has
highlighted a convergence of income levels within the richer countries
but divergence within the poorer countries with some of the latter even
falling behind the rest and becoming relatively poorer. These trends can
be readily seen from Table 1.
Two economic models have been invoked to explain the above
tendencies: Solow's growth model which predicts convergence, Solow
(1956), and Krugman's divergence model Krugman (1981). The
mechanism behind Solow's growth model is diminishing returns to
reproducible capital. A poor country characterised by a low
capital/labour ratio, has a higher marginal productivity of capital and
thereby tends to grow at a higher rate than a rich country with a higher
intensity and lower marginal productivity of capital. Furthermore, there
is a tendency for capital to move from rich to poor and thereby
accelerating the convergence process. The contrary model is that of
Krugman which stresses increasing returns to capital, technological
edges and learning in assuring higher levels of more competitive capital
and industrial exports in the rich country. Endogenous growth is seen to
work to the advantage of the rich country which grows at a higher rate
than the poor country. Capital flow tends to reverse from poor to rich,
aggravating income gap between rich and poor, furthermore.
Krugman's model has been elaborated further by Lucas (1993); Barro
(1991) and others along endogenous growth theory to show basically the
same: an increasing income gap between, on the one hand, countries which
invest in human resources and are able to capture the public goods
character of those investments, and, on the other, countries which do
not (are unable or unwilling) to invest sufficiently in human resources,
learning and innovation.
A synthesis is found in Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992) who develop a
model which combines the mechanical growth theory as represented by
Solow and endogenous growth theory as represented by Krugman, Lucas and
others. They test their model to the data set of Summers and Heston and
find that countries with similar technologies and rates of accumulation
and population growth should converge in income per capita. Yet this
convergence occurs more slowly than the Solow model suggests. More
generally, the results indicate that the Solow model is consistent with
the international evidence if one takes account of intervening
(dis)advantages of individual countries with respect to human and
physical capital endowments.
Another empirical paper which contributes to a synthesis is by
Barro and Lee (1993). They explain the growth performance of 116
economies from 1965 to 1985 and find a conditional convergence effect
whereby a country grows faster if it begins with lower real GDP per
capita in relation to its initial level of human capital in the forms of
educational attainment and health; next to other stimulating factors
such as high ratio of investment to GDP, small government and political
stability.
It is noted that all the models mentioned above emphasise supply
factors in determination of economic growth. The debate has so far been
unbalanced as it excluded models of economic growth which emphasise
demand factors. This paper highlights the insights to be gained from
employing a demand-determined growth model. We use here a circular flow
model based on the Social Accounting Matrix, SAM. The results of this
model, empirically verified for a group of sixteen countries at
different stages of economic development, would give general support to
the convergence hypothesis. This paper discusses in Section 2 the
SAM-based model. In Section 3 the SAM multipliers are used to assess the
convergence hypothesis. In Section 4 empirical results are analysed. In
Section 5 a numerical demonstration is reviewed, and Section 6
concludes.
2. THE DEMAND MODEL
For the purpose in mind, the fittest framework within the wide
range of demand-oriented models is the circular flow model based on the
Social Accounting Matrix, SAM. The Social Accounting Matrix is a very
general data base which is well suited for the flexible modelling of the
economy, cf. Pyatt (1991) and Cohen (1993).
The SAM is nothing more or less than the transformation of the
circular flow into a matrix of transactions between the various agents.
In the rows of such a matrix there are the products, the factors, the
current accounts of institutions consisting of households, firms and
government as well as their capital accumulation account, the activities
and the rest of the world. The columns are ordered similarly.
Transactions between these actors take place at the filled cells and in
correspondence with the circular flow. A particular row gives receipts
of the account while columnwise we read the expenditure of the actor.
Assuming proportional relationships for the cells in terms of their
column totals a SAM coefficient matrix is obtained which can be written
as a model of the economy with the endogenous part on the left hand side
and exogenous part on the right hand side. The endogenous variables
include production, income, consumption, investment, among others. The
exogenous variables in such a model are those of government and rest of
world. We shall discuss the assumptions of the model in a moment.
A SAM-based model can take the form of Equations (1) to (6),
whereby the following notations hold:
[V.sub.v] = value of production of sector v,
[W.sub.w] = factor incomes of factor type w which can be wages,
profits, etc.,
[Z.sub.z] = receipts of household group by region z,
F = receipts of firms,
K = capital formation,
Y = national income,
X = purchases of government and/or exports, both of which are
assumed exogenous,
T = transfers from government and/or rest of the world, both
assumed exogenous.
Equation (1) gives the sectoral balance by sector v, consisting of
intermediate delivery [summation over (v')] [a.sub.vv'] V
v', consumption expenditure [summation over (z)] [c.sub.vz]
[Z.sub.z*], capital formation [e.sub.y] K, and a variable for the
sectoral receipts from both government expenditure and exports
[i.sub.v], X, where [i.sub.v] gives the sectoral share in these
receipts.
Equation (2) defines national income, consisting of factor incomes.
Equation (3) determines factor incomes by factor w, as being
originating from value added coefficients and production by sector
[summation over (v)] [a.sub.wv] [V.sub.v].
Equation (4) determines household receipts by household group z,
consisting of portions of factor income [summation over (w)] [b.sub.zw]
[W.sub.w], inter household transfers [summation over (z')]
[c.sub.zz'] [Z.sub.z'], and transfers from government and rest
of the world [i.sub.z] T, where [i.sub.z] gives the household
group's share in the transfers.
Equation (5) determines firm receipts, consisting also from
portions of factor income and transfers from government and rest of the
world.
Equation (6) shows the different sources of capital formation to
consist of deprivation summed over sectors, savings summed over
households, reinvested savings of firms and capital transfer from
government and the rest of the world.
The coefficients a,b,c are proportions of the total receipts
(outlays) for the columns corresponding with V, W, Z respectively, and
[summation]a = 1.0, [summation]b = 1.0, [summation]c = 1.0.
[V.sub.v] - [summation over (v')] [a.sub.vv']
[V.sub.v'] - [summation over (z)] [c.sub.vz] [Z.sub.z] + e[K.sub.v]
= [i.sub.v] X ... (1)
Y - [summation over (w)] [W.sub.w] = 0 ... (2)
-[summation over (v)] [a.sub.wv] [V.sub.v] + [W.sub.w] = 0 ... (3)
-[summation over (w)] [b.sub.zw] - [summation over (z')]
[c.sub.zz'] [Z.sub.z'] + [Z.sub.z] = [i.sub.z] T ... (4)
-[summation over (w)] [b.sub.fw] + F = [i.sub.f] T ... (5)
-[summation over (v)] [a.sub.kv] - [summation over (z)] [c.sub.kz]
[Z.sub.z] - [d.sub.k] F + K = [i.sub.k] T ... (6)
In the above equations, the endogenous variables appearing on the
left hand side can be denoted by y, and they include national income
among other variables. The exogenous variables appear on the right hand
side and can be denoted by x. These include outlays of government and
rest of the world. While the coefficient matrix which joins them can be
denoted by S. The system can be described in matrix form by y - Sy = x,
solving gives
y = [(I - S).sup.-1] x = Mx ... (7)
where M stands for the matrix of system multipliers. We focus on
the national income multiplier of rich and poor countries and examine
their growth tendencies to shed light on the convergence hypotheses.
Before proceeding further, we discuss here main assumptions and
limitations of the SAM multiplier approach as well as our counterpart
arguments in defence of the approach for the purpose in mind.
(1) The evaluation of the multipliers of the SAM-model cannot be
done in isolation from the closure rules applied. The size of the
multipliers depends on the choice of the exogenous and endogenous
variables, which in turn depends on the problem studied. In the context
of the comparative analysis of economic systems there is an established
rationale due to Koopmans and Montias (1971) for considering government
policy and rest of the world conditions as exogenous and taking the rest
of the economy as endogenous. This is also what is postulated in the SAM
model.
(2) The SAM model describes an endogenous economy with fixed
relative prices and complementarity-based production and consumption
functions. Producers and consumers are assumed to face fixed prices, and
in their pursuit of profit and utility maximisation, respectively,
adjustment takes the form of changes in quantities supplied and
demanded. As regards the assumption of producers and consumers facing
given relative prices this is common practise in short-run models.
Moreover, even in the longer run, having in mind the broad categories of
sectors and products in the SAM we can draw on empirical evidence over
long periods which supports indefinite shifts in relative prices between
such broad categories, cf. Bleaney and Greenaway (1993).
(3) Cell entries of the SAM are amounts, i.e. products of prices
times quantities. However, quantities and prices are not explicitly
disentangled. In the SAM model, supplied amounts are supposed to adjust
to demanded amounts. They will, but if there is restricted capacity the
result is inflation. This may require a revision downwards in the real
sizes of multipliers. The role of investment in the model is confined to
that of enhancing demand, and not of adding to the productive capacity.
Whether the potential multiplier effects of impulses will be realised in
increased quantities in full or disappear for a part in increased prices
depends on the elasticity of supply. If the size of the impulse is
relatively small, which is usually the case, these multipliers can still
be seen to represent realisable quantity effects with little leakage
into price effects. It is also feasible to check in a simple way within
the SAM framework whether the capacity limits will be violated or not.
The supply side can be simply modelled as a relationship between the
investment rate and economic growth via an incremental capital output
ratio x as in K/Y = x (*** Y/Y). From the SAM we obtain multiplier
effects for K and K If division of the multiplier effects of K by those
of Y gives values equal to or above K/Y for the base period then this
implies that the SAM solves for sufficient investment to meet the
projected capacity increase. It is noted that multiplier results show
that this condition is fulfilled for the countries studied. In
principle, similar checks can be applied to trace whether the base
period equilibria in the balance of payments and the government budget
are reproduced by multiplier effects.
(4) The coefficient matrix in the SAM model, S, is a matrix of
fixed average proportions. Compared to averages, observed marginal
coefficients are better since they incorporate income and scale effects,
but they can be disputable as their estimated values may carry other
than income effects, which is inconsistent with the SAM framework. While
the c set, in the equation system (1) to (6) (these are consumption
propensities), can be calculated sensibly as marginal instead of average
values, the problem is severe for the a set (these are input-output
coefficients) as well as for the b set (these are sector--factor
earnings coefficients), and other coefficients in the model, which do
not usually depict stable marginal propensities. Taking a portion of the
coefficients as marginal and the other as an average introduces an
estimation bias. Moreover, the uniform fixed coefficient assumption in
cross-country comparisons is an advantage in contrast with incomparable specifications for individual countries (which, of course, can be
suitable for other purposes).
(5) The size of the multiplier depends to some degree on the level
of aggregation. This argument is not relevant in the context of a
uniform aggregation for the compared countries. Moreover, the
differences in multipliers due to alternative aggregations tested do not
go beyond 8 percent for the individual countries studied here.
(6) Although it is commonly perceived that a SAM-inverted model
belongs more to the prototype of demand-oriented models, yet under
general equilibrium conditions it is a representation of the supply side
as well, which is why the SAM is directly convertible to the CGE model.
Finally, although we use a demand model, this does not mean that we are
implying short-run growth rates. By analysing and fitting our hypothesis
to the economic growth of countries ranging from developing countries
such as India and Pakistan to advanced countries such as Germany and the
Netherlands we are clearly emphasising the long range character of
economic growth.
3. THE CONVERGENCE HYPOTHESIS
Recalling Equation (7) which gives the endogenous vector as
function of the system multipliers and an exogenous vector y = Mx, our
concern in this paper goes to one endogenous variable from the vector y
i.e. national income, Y, and one exogenous variable from the vector x,
namely government expenditure and exports combined, X, in Equations (2)
and (1). The multiplier elements from the multiplier matrix, which
interest us here are those giving the sum total effects of equal
sectoral injections via X on Y, which we shall call m. We shall thus
restrict our interest to the total multiplier effect of the unweighted
exogenous injections in government expenditures and exports, X, on the
national income, Y, as in Equation (8.1) where m consists of the summed
relevant elements (1) from the multiplier matrix M.
Y = mX ... (8.1)
To simplify matters we shall ignore for the moment the less
significant multiplier impact of the exogenous variable of transfer
payments by the government and the rest of the world, T, but we comment
on the impact of its incorporation in Section 4, which will be shown to
reinforce our conclusions.
Equation (8.1) can be rewritten as in Equation (8.2)
Y = m(X/Y)Y ... (8.2)
and reexpressed in growth rates as in Equation (8.3)
[Y.sup.***] = [m.sup.***] + [(X/Y).sup.***] + [Y.sup.***] ... (8.3)
If we further denote a hypothesised growth rate by * and a
realisable growth rate by o, Equation (8.3) can be rephrased as in
(8.3.1).
Note here that we treat the three growth rates on the right hand
side as hypothetical values in the sense that these growth rates are
either assumed or forecasted and are consistently estimated in relation
to each other. The combined effect of the three growth rates result in
the realisable growth rate of the national income on the left hand side.
We are in a position thus to answer the question how the economy will
perform in the longer run based on components derived from the SAM
model.
[Y.sup.*** o] [??] [m.sup.*** *] + [(X/Y).sup.*** *] + [Y.sup.***
*] ... (8.3.1)
Equation (8.3.1) reads more specifically for poor countries, p, and
rich countries, r, as follows:
[Y.sup.*** o.sub.p] [??] [m.sup.*** *.sub.p] + [(X/Y).sup.***
*.sub.p] + [Y.sup.*** *.sub.p], and
[Y.sup.*** o.sub.r] [??] [m.sup.*** *.sub.r] + [(X/Y).sup.***
*.sub.r] + [Y.sup.*** *.sub.r]
The hypothetical and realisable values of the growth rate of
income, [Y.sup.*** *] and [Y.sup.*** o], respectively, are generally
different due to the independent determinacy of [m.sup.*** *] and
[(X/Y).sup.*** *].
If it can be shown for the groups of the poor and rich countries
for which we have SAMs that starting from the same hypothetical growth
rates [Y.sup.*** *.sub.p] = [Y.sup.*** *.sub.r] we can expect [m.sup.***
*.sub.p] + [(X/Y).sup.*** *.sub.p] > [m.sup.*** *.sub.r] +
[(X/Y).sup.*** *.sub.r] then it follows that realisable growth rates
will show [Y.sup.*** o.sub.p] > [Y.sup.*** o.sub.r], which is an
indication of catching up. We may start first with growth of the
exogenous share [(X/Y).sup.*** *] and show that this can be expected to
be higher for poor than rich countries and take up later the prospects
for [m.sup.*** *]
We start first with X/Y. An interesting feature of the accounting
system is that the row element of government expenditure and exports X
can be divided by the row of total national income Y to give the
exogenous share, X/Y. We have defined X to consist of government
expenditure and exports. The hypothesis, which we put forward is that
the share of these items in the national income, X/Y, tends to grow
rapidly during early stages of economic development but ebbs down and
stops growing at higher stages of economic development. This hypothesis
is put down in Figure 1 which shows the relationship between X/Y and
income per capita, Y/N, this being the conventional expression for the
stage of economic development.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The quasi-logistic curve in Figure 1 can be formulated as Equation
(9). This is also the form in which the hypothesis will be empirically
tested.
X/Y = [beta](Y/N) / (Y/N) + [alpha] ... (9)
Wagner's law predicts that at higher levels of economic
development, that is, as income per capita grows, the relative share of
the public sector in national income will grow. Although the basis of
the statement of Wagner was the empires of the nineteenth century, the
theoretical foundations behind the phenomenon were developed later by
Peacock and Wiseman, Musgrave, Baumol and others using various public
choice arguments. More recent experiences in the balancing of budgetary
deficits in rich countries directed attention to fiscal, monetary and
incentive limits to the further growth of the government share in total
expenditure. So the share of the public sector grows as income per
capita grows, up to a certain limit. This share has a tendency to
stabilise at the higher levels of income per capita.
A similar tendency applies to the share of exports in income, which
share is very much dependent on economic development, location and
population. As per capita income grows, there is a tendency for the
economy to become more open and attain a higher share of exports up to a
point where the share levels off as more open economy countries get
their portions of world exports. It is also established that the larger
the country is in terms of population and economy the lesser the share
of exports in income. Among the four rich countries treated in this
paper Germany, Italy and Spain will be seen to fall in this class. On
the other hand, the small population countries which are also centrally
located like the Netherlands tend to have higher shares of foreign
transactions with the rest of the world.
The conclusion is that as far as the exogenous share is concerned,
and this applies to both constituents of government expenditure and
exports, the growth of this share for developing countries is higher
than for rich countries: [(X/Y).sup.** *.sub.p] > [(X/Y).sup.**
*.sub.r]
We go now to [m.sup.*** *] Recalling Equation (8.1) we have: 1/m =
X/Y. Seen as a definition a rise in X/Y should lead to a proportional
fall in m.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The relationship between m and X/Y can be put down more generally
as Equation (10), which will be empirically tested in the next section.
m = [gamma][(X/Y)-[delta]] ... (10)
In Figure 2, curve I is obtained for values [gamma] = [delta] = 1,
while curve II corresponds with our empirical estimation, which results
in 3/having a slightly lower value than 1, and [delta] < 1 indicating
that the fall in m is somewhat moderated.
The underlying relationship behind empirical curve II is that m
falls with higher X/Y but increasingly at a lower rate than
proportionally. The argument is that the income-expenditure-production
linkages in the economy, which have been accumulated throughout the past
and which have assured higher circular flow mechanisms and higher m,
have been enriched in the development process and are not lost
proportionally just like that by an increased exogeneity. The circular
flow effects fall with a rise in the exogenous share but this fall
happens at a lower rate than the rise in the exogenous share.
More generally, an open ended economy, with no specification of
closure as yet. can be written down as a system of equations in one
whole matrix with proportionate coefficients. The assignment of part of
this matrix as an exogenous part is a specification of closure and gives
determinacy to the system. The remainder of the matrix is the inverted part which gives the system multipliers. If the size of the exogenous
part is relatively small, then the size of the inverted part will be
relatively large, resulting in high multipliers, and hence low external
leakage.
The internal leakage, as the term suggests is different, and is
determined by the typical pattern of the inverted part. When the
transactions of one agent (A) with a high multiplier effect flow to
agents (B) with lower multiplier effects, thus m(A) > m(B), internal
leakage tends to be high. The more developed the economy the greater the
linkages, the more correspondence between m(A) and m(B), and the smaller
is the internal leakage. Once the endogenous linkages are built, their
multiplier effects will not be proportionally written off with an
increased exogeneity. There is an economic growth advantage here for the
rich vis a vis the poor country. Other institutional structures matter
also: there should be lesser variation of output multipliers in the free
market economy which reacts quickly and competitively in setting up new
transactions between agents when the need arises, this in contrast to
the case of the centrally planned economy which is characterised by
higher internal leakage.
All this means that the relative decline in multiplier m with
increased exogenity can be expected to be higher for the poor than for
the rich country, [m.sup.*** *.sub.p] < [m.sup.*** *.sub.r]. This
contributes to a widening of the gap between rich and poor, but as will
be empirically shown later this is not strong enough to countervail the
catching up tendency due to [(X/Y).sup.*** *.sub.p] > [(X/Y).sup.***
*.sub.r], so that in the longer run we can expect convergence,
nevertheless.
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
This section will report on selected results from cross-country
comparisons of SAM models applied to ten developing countries (India,
Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Indonesia, Iran, Kenya, Colombia, Egypt, South
Korea, and Suriname), two centrally planned economies (Poland and
Hungary) and four developed market economies (The Netherlands, Italy,
Germany, and Spain), for different years.
The classification of activities in these SAMs had to be limited to
three large groups of sectors: agriculture, industry and services;
whereby industry includes mining, manufacturing and energy utilities,
and services includes construction and transport among other private and
public services. Distinguishing more sectors would reduce the uniformity
and comparability of the sixteen SAMs reported here. The disaggregation of households in the SAMs of the developing countries emphasises
dualities in the location of population in urban and rural areas, and
the differentiation within urban and rural groups by level of income
earned. This differentiation is done by a categorical split-up among
urban households leading to the distinction between the three groups of
employers, employees and self-employed; and a split-up among rural
households by size of land ownership leading to three groups of large
landowners, medium landowners and small/landless households. As a
result, there are six groups of households. For a couple of countries a
seventh residual group was incorporated so as to accommodate for
classifications which did not fit the standardised six categories. The
SAMs of the European countries distinguish household groups by income
classes obtainable from personal income distributions.
The testing of Equations (9) and (10) require data by country on
the exogenous share of government and exports in national income, X/Y,
and the income multiplier m, which are obtainable from the SAMs and the
matrix inversions, respectively. Data on a third variable is needed,
this is the GNP per capita, Y/N, expressed in US $ for the sixteen
countries and their related years. These are obtainable from published
tables of the World Bank Atlas, which are specially suitable in our
context as they are based on conversions that smoothen the impact of
annual fluctuations in exchange rates. Table 2 brings these data
together. Note that the value of X/Y varies from a lower value of 0.12
for India (poor country) to a highest value of 0.89 for the Netherlands
(rich country). The income multipliers start from 7.06 for a poor
country and fall to 0.85 for a rich country.
The regression results of Equations (9) and (10) are found in Table
3. Equation (9) describes a quasi-logistic function which makes the
level of the exogenous share dependent on the income per capita. To
account for a particularly lower share in case of a large size rich
country, e.g. Germany, Italy and Spain, and too high a share of exports
for a few particularly foreign trade oriented small countries e.g. the
Netherlands, Suriname and Kenya, a dummy variable is included which
takes the value of 1.0 for the first group and -1.0 for the second
group. The equation is estimated by non-linear least squares. The
regression performs very well, in terms of the signs of the
coefficients, their t-values and goodness of fit as indicated by
[R.sup.2] (above 0.8). The predicted highest value of the exogenous
share in the observed sample, disregarding the dummy, can be calculated
at 61 percent for the richest country. The predicted and observed lowest
value of the exogenous share are the same, at 12 percent for the poorest
country.
Because Y is determined by the whole system including Equation 9,
the question is raised on possible correlation between the explanatory variable, per capita income Y/N, and the disturbance term, yielding a
biased non-linear least square estimator. Note that the explanatory
variable is expressed as Y/N and not in terms of Y only. Furthermore,
the residuals in Equation 9 were found not to correlate with the
explaining variable of national income per capita (r = 0.34), giving no
ground for applying more sophisticated regression methods than the
followed non-linear least squares method.
Equation (10) describes a convex function between the income
multiplier and the exogenous share. For estimation purposes the equation
is formulated as ln m = ln [gamma] + [delta] ln (X/Y)and tested by
ordinary least squares. One dummy needs to be introduced to account for
a high income multiplier bias in the SAMs of both India and Pakistan:
the available SAMs of India and Pakistan do not register complementary
imports to the full extent or at all, and hence underestimate the
leakage and overestimate the multipliers.
Another dummy is required to account for the differential impacts
of economic systems, e.g. Poland and Hungary. Although one should expect
higher multipliers liar the less rich Eastern Europe (Poland and
Hungary) as compared to the more rich Western Europe; instead, they have
about the same levels, as Table 2 shows. This under-performance of
Poland and Hungary is due to the presence of institutions which do not
make full use of the potential internal leakage effects within the
system. The variation of income multipliers among the West European
countries as represented by the ratio of the highest/lowest sectoral
multiplier can be calculated as 1.44. For Eastern European countries the
variation is higher. It is noted too that Poland has a wider variation
(1.57) than Hungary (1.46), which reflects a more balanced and
well-knitted economy in this respect.
Equation (10) was tested with two separate dummies as well as with
one dummy carrying the value of -1.0 for India and Pakistan and 1.0 for
Poland and Hungary. The results are very similar so that we can work as
well with the simpler case of one dummy, which is reported in Table 3.
The regression performs very well in terms of all prerequisites.
The locus of the paper is not the relationship Y = mX for a
specific country but searching for a valid relationship between the
three variables over a range of poor and rich countries. This has led us
to use two equations: one for explaining m in terms of X/Y (Equation 10)
and one for explaining X/Y in terms of national income per capita
(Equation 9).
If the mean of m over the 16 countries in Equation 10 was anything
meaningful. we would have obtained values of 1 for [gamma] and for
[delta] in Equation 10 (curve I in Figure 2), but we do obtain curve II
in Figure 2 with values ln([gamma]) = -0.077 and [delta] = 0.619. These
results are not due to whether the m's are calculated as weighted
or unweighted sectoral impact multipliers, but they are due to the
shapes and significance of linkages changing with economic development
which were stated under Figure 2.
The paper calculates m as an unweighted sectoral average (see
Footnote 2). It can be readily seen from Table 2 that if m was
calculated as a weighted sectoral average the curve of Equation 10 would
fall more steeply and flatten earlier with values of ln([gamma]) and
[delta] even further away from [gamma] = [delta] = 1. Note that in Table
2 agricultural multipliers score highest and have the highest share in
pool countries. Weighting sectoral multipliers by sectoral shares would
result in higher aggregate m's for the poor countries as compared
to rich countries causing the curve to shift further away from curve I.
5. DEMONSTRATION
With the estimates of [alpha], [beta], [gamma], and [delta] we are
now in a position to predict for a poor and a rich country respectively,
such growth rates as [(X/Y).sup.*** *] and [m.sup.*** *] for assumed
values of [Y.sup.*** *], insert them in Equation (8.3) for the poor and
rich country separately, and solve for realised growth rates of income
of the poor and rich countries [Y.sup.*** o.sub.p] and [Y.sup.***
o.sub.r]. Recall Equation (8.3.1) for the poor and rich country:
[Y.sup.*** o.sub.p] [??] [m.sup.*** *.sub.p] + [(X/Y).sup.***
*.sub.p] + [Y.sup.*** *.sub.p], and
[Y.sup.*** o.sub.r] [??] [m.sup.*** *.sub.r] + [(X/Y).sup.***
*.sub.r] + [Y.sup.*** *.sub.r]
In Table 4 we start from initial income, population and income per
capita for a poor and a rich country (poor and rich as was indicated by
the averages in Table 2). We assume for both types of countries the same
annual rates of growth of 2 percent per income, 1 percent for population
and 1 percent for income per capita. Using the estimates of [alpha],
[beta], [gamma], and [delta] we obtain the predicted values of growth
rates of X/Y, of X, and of m in columns 8, 10, and 12 respectively.
These are used in solving for the realised growth rates of income of the
poor and rich country in the last column. The calculations show that the
realised growth rate of income of the poor country will exceed that of
the rich country. The poor country would achieve an annual growth rate
of 2.17 percent while the rich country would grow annually at 2.02
percent. Another scenario is run with assumed growth rates of income per
capita for the pool and rich at 3 percent, this scenario results also
with a higher rate of realised growth for the poor than the rich, 3.19
percent compared to 3.05 percent. In a more general way, Table 4
simulates the annual growth rate of income for rising levels of income
pet capita. The table shows higher growth rates of income at lower
levels of income per capita, the growth rates diminishing slowly and
practically stabilising at a high level of income per capita of around
US $ 20,000.
The convergence tendency, [Y.sup.*** o.sub.p] > [Y.sup.*** o.
sub.r], is decomposable into a part clue to [X.sup.**] and a part due to
[m.sup.***], Equation (8.1). The positive but diminishing contribution
of [X.sup.**] standing for a growth potential at a lower level of
economic development and an exhaustion of possibilities for exogenous
growth at higher levels of economic development dominates the negative
effect of [m.sup.***], standing for the diminishing multiplier effects
but at a reduced rate.
The analysis concentrated so far on the effects of exogenous
changes in sectoral allocations originating from government and the rest
of the world X. How significant are the effects of exogenous changes in
transfers originating from government and rest of world, T, and in which
direction do they act?
In principle, the above analysis as in Tables 2, 3 and 4 can be
repeated but with focus on T. It is also possible to demonstrate the
effects via short-cuts. Recalling Equation 7 which gives the vector of
endogenous variables v as function of multiplier matrix M and vector of
exogenous variables x,
y = Mx
this can be specified for variables of interest: endogenous income
Y, exogenous allocations X and exogenous transfers T.
Y = mX + m'T
and dividing throughout by Y gives
1 = m X/Y + m' T/Y
This equation can be specified for poor and rich countries as
1 = [(m).sub.p] [(X/Y).sub.p] + [(m').sub.p] [(T/Y).sub.p] ...
(11.1)
1 = [(m).sub.r] [(X/Y).sub.r] + [(m').sub.r] [(T/Y).sub.r] ...
(11.2)
Inserting the average values of the above parameters for the two
groups of countries--see appendix Table 2--gives the following results:
(2)
1 [approximately equal to] (2.545)(0.356) + (2.423)(0.078)
[approximately equal to] 0.83 + 0.17 ... (11.1)
1 [approximately equal to] (1.3)(0.543) [approximately equal to]
(1.648)(0.242) = 0.63 + 0.27 ... (11.2)
These results show the effect of X to be about 2.5 to 5.0 times
that of T in determining economic growth. At higher levels of economic
development the relative strength of X and T effects shifts from X to T.
This happens via an increase in the share of T/Y (and a lower share of
X/Y) as well as less reductions in m' (as compared to m). At still
higher levels of economic development the increases T/Y are restricted
by the same constraints which apply to X/Y. First, the T/Y share for
individual rich countries has reached its ceiling in the late
eighties/early nineties and is falling in others [Cohen and Bayens
(1994)]. Second, the growth effect of transfers in rich countries,
[m'.sub.r] forms 68 percent of that for poor countries,
[m'.sub.p]. Therefore the conclusions reached on converging tendencies due to the X effects apply to the T effects as well.
6. CONCLUSIONS
Investigation of whether the gap in the income per capita between
rich and poor countries is widening or diminishing has relied mainly on
supply side models of economic growth appropriately adapted to include
dements of endogenous growth.
In this paper a demand side model, based on the Social Accounting
Matrix (SAM) is estimated for sixteen countries. The SAM models predict
higher economic growth at lower levels of income per capita, and
indicate, therefore, the presence of a convergent tendency. The main
cause behind this convergent tendency is the ability of a poor country
to increase significantly exogenous injections of exports and
government, this in contrast to the exhaustion of possibilities for
exogenous growth--of both exports and government--at higher levels of
income per capita; while the positive effects from linkage economies at
higher levels of income per capita are too low to compensate for the
loss in the exogenous growth potential.
Can one, with the SAM based demand side approach, speak of
conditional convergence as has become common place in supply side
explanatory approaches? In principle, this can be said to apply here
too. The SAM analysis was supplemented by dummy variables to account for
particularly low/high exogenous shares, these tend to associate with
large/small sizes of the economy in relation to the rest of the world
and the openness of an economy. Furthermore, the type of the economic
system as to whether it is predominantly centrally planned or market
oriented was found to influence the size of the multiplier effects. The
inherent long-run tendencies towards convergence can be interpreted as
conditional to the extent that the above mentioned particular features
of individual countries--expressed as intervening dummies--enjoy a
permanent presence. Ceteris paribus, the SAM analysis supports the
convergence hypothesis.
The tables below Live basic variables from the SAM's which are
used in the analysis.
Appendix Table 1
Selected SAM Features and GNP Per Capita
In Bln. of Own Currency Units
(1)
Final
Currency Demand (2)
Country Year Unit Consumption Investm.
India 1968-69 Rupee 27.471 5.103
Pakistan 1979 Rupee 0.199 0.042
Sri Lanka 1970 Rupee 7.601 1.962
Indonesia 1975 Rupiah 8.201 2.227
Iran 1970 Rial 0.450 0.146
Kenya 1976 Shilling 0.951 0.199
Colombia 1970 Peso 93.863 28.660
Egypt 1976 Pound 3.927 1.198
South Korea 1979 Won 6.729 2.078
Suriname 1979 Guilder 1.026 0.181
Poland 1987 Zloty 8.371 4.425
Hungary 1990 Forint 1.094 0.409
Spain 1980 Peseta 9.791 3.548
Italy 1984 Lira 414.754 121.710
Germany 1984 Mark 823.300 310.642
The Netherlands 1987 Guilder 196.071 52.902
In Bln. of Own Currency Units
(5)
(3) (4) Interm. (6)
Country Government Export Deliv.s Output
India 0.000 1.450 18.744 52.768
Pakistan 0.022 0.034 0.168 0.465
Sri Lanka 0.302 2.113 4.358 16.336
Indonesia 1.062 3.253 5.797 21.223
Iran 0.050 0.021 0.327 0.993
Kenya 0.120 0.472 0.932 2.673
Colombia 9.962 18.516 108.065 259.066
Egypt 1.893 0.800 3.482 11.300
South Korea 0.990 2.748 8.383 20.928
Suriname 0.000 0.917 0.507 2.631
Poland 2.937 3.516 19.373 38.622
Hungary 0.166 0.685 1.953 4.360
Spain 1.929 2.400 14.071 31.739
Italy 136.677 149.717 588.080 1410.938
Germany 350.230 476.852 1508.506 3469.530
The Netherlands 70.590 203.354 222.793 745.710
In Bln. of Own Currency Units
(7) (8) (9) (10)
Country Import GDP X/O O/Y
India 1.868 32.156 0.027 1.641
Pakistan 0.059 0.238 0.121 1.953
Sri Lanka 1.389 10.589 0.148 1.543
Indonesia 3.009 11.734 0.203 1.809
Iran 0.111 0.556 0.071 1.786
Kenya 0.431 1.310 0.221 2.041
Colombia 20.639 130.362 0.110 1.987
Egypt 1.604 6.214 0.238 1.818
South Korea 3.878 8.667 0.179 2.415
Suriname 0.921 1.203 0.349 2.187
Poland 3.218 16.031 0.167 2.409
Hungary 0.605 1.749 0.195 2.493
Spain 2.664 15.004 0.136 2.115
Italy 162.013 660.845 0.203 2.135
Germany 499.370 1461.654 0.238 2.374
The Netherlands 213.312 309.605 0.367 2.409
In Bln. of Own Currency Units
(12)
Average Income
(11) Multiplier from GNP Cap
Country X/Y Injections in X (1000$)
India 0.045 7.06 0.09
Pakistan 0.237 6.11 0.17
Sri Lanka 0.228 2.32 0.17
Indonesia 0.368 2.90 0.21
Iran 0.128 2.82 0.22
Kenya 0.452 1.28 0.24
Colombia 0.218 2.47 0.34
Egypt 0.433 1.15 0.35
South Korea 0.431 1.79 1.51
Suriname 0.762 0.95 2.21
Poland 0.403 0.92 1.93
Hungary 0.487 0.77 2.59
Spain 0.289 1.53 5.40
Italy 0.433 1.50 6.42
Germany 0.566 1.32 11.11
The Netherlands 0.885 0.09 11.86
X = Government (Col. 3) + Exports (Col. 4)
O = Output (Col. 6) Y = GDP (Col. 8).
Appendix Table 2
Selected SAM Features and GNP Per Capita
Currency (9) (10)
Country Year Unit T/O O/Y
India 1968-69 Rupee 0.058 1.641
Pakistan 1979 Rupee 0.036 1.953
Sri Lanka 1970 Rupee 0.105 1.543
Indonesia 1975 Rupiah 0.009 1.809
Iran 1970 Rial 0.080 1.786
Kenya 1976 Shilling 0.063 2.041
Colombia 1970 Peso 0.016 1.987
Egypt 1976 Pound 0.027 1.818
South Korea 1979 Won 0.013 2.415
Suriname 1979 Guilder 0.008 2.187
Poland 1987 Zloty 0.019 2.409
Hungary 1990 Forint 0.055 2.493
Average of Poor
Countries
Spain 1980 Peseta 0.079 2.115
Italy 1984 Lira 0.107 2.135
Germany 1984 Murk 0.083 2.374
The Netherlands 1987 Guilder 0.157 2.409
Average of Rich
countries
(12)
Average Income
(11) Multiplier from GNP Cap
Country T/Y Transfers in T (1000$)
India 0.095 4.34 0.09
Pakistan 0.070 4.28 0.17
Sri Lanka 0.163 2.28 0.17
Indonesia 0.017 2.64 0.21
Iran 0.142 2.78 0.20
Kenya 0.129 1.98 0.24
Colombia 0.032 2.17 0.34
Egypt 0.050 1.87 0.35
South Korea 0.032 2.13 1.51
Suriname 0.018 1.67 2.21
Poland 0.047 1.54 1.93
Hungary 0.138 1.40 2.51
Average of Poor
Countries 0.078 2.42 0.84
Spain 0.167 1.87 5.40
Italy 0.228 1.73 6.42
Germany 0.196 1.57 11.13
The Netherlands 0.377 1.42 11.86
Average of Rich
countries 0.242 1.65 8.70
Comments
This is an innovative and interesting paper. It employs the Social
Accounting Matrix (SAM) framework to demonstrate that low-income
countries tend to grow faster than high-income countries. Therefore,
there is a tendency for the income per capita of low-income countries to
converge to that of high-income countries over time. While the
convergence hypothesis appears Io make sense and therefore commands
widespread support among economists, this acceptance is neither
universal nor unconditional. The author provides a good survey of the
literature of empirical growth economics based on the neoclassical
growth model stimulated by the Summers and Heston data set of 130
countries for over 35 years.
All the studies I have seen on cross-country growth, and believe me
there have been many such studies originating with Barro's work
(1991), have generally used the neoclassical growth framework. A typical
study computes averages of ten years or longer for as many countries as
possible on GDP growth rates and attempts to explain them statistically
by performing cross-section regressions. Usually the explanatory
variables are averages of labour or population growth, inflation,
investment to GDP ratios, and fiscal, monetary, social, and demographic
variables. Usually among the explanatory variables is an initial income
variable which is included to determine whether the initial income level
has bearing on long-term growth. Generally most studies have reported a
negative coefficient oil the income term implying that, ceteris paribus,
the lower the initial income level of the country, the higher the
growth. This is seen as evidence of low-income countries' tendency
to grow faster than high-income countries. I have been guilty of this
exercise too [Khilji and Zampelli (1993)]. Levine and Renelt (1992)
provide a good critical survey of such studies. The use of the
neoclassical framework for studies on long term growth makes sense since
the objective is to look at the capacity of the economy to grow which
clearly depends on its resources such as physical and human capital, and
the types of policies it pursues. In other words it is the supply of
output that has been the focus of these growth studies, and rightly so.
This paper is the first one I have seen that looks at growth from
the demand side via the SAM framework. Using highly aggregated SAMs of
various vintages for 16 countries (one SAM for each country) it works
out the familiar system of equations [Equation (7) in the paper] that
links value added by industry and other endogenous variables to
exogenous variables through a system of multipliers. Focussing on the
income Equation in this system and expressing il in growth rates
produces the equation (8.3.1) in the paper. This equation is written for
poor and rich countries separately. I reproduce these equations below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The subscripts p and i refer to poor and rich countries
respectively, the superscripts *o, and ** refer to hypothesised and
realisable growth respectively in the variables, Y stands for income,
X/Y is the ratio of exogenous variables to income. and m is the SAM
multiplier. The author conveniently forgets the double inequalities in
these equations and assumes the equalities to hold for the rest of iris
paper. The basic point of the paper is that if it can be shown that
starting from the same growth rates, i.e., [Y.sup.**.sub.p] =
[Y.sup.**.sub.r] the right hand side of the poor countries'
equation is greater than the right hand side of the rich countries'
equation then the observed growth rate in the poor countries will be
greater than the rich countries.
The author focuses first on the growth in the share of the
exogenous variables (exports and government expenditures) in income
[[(X/Y).sup.**]] and reasons that this share grows rapidly in the early
stages of development and then this growth tapers of at higher stages.
He models this phenomenon as a quasi-logistic curve. For the growth in
the multiplier ([m.sup.**]), the reasoning is just the opposite.
Low-income countries are supposed to have high multiplier effects which
taper off at higher levels of development. This phenomenon is modelled
as a rectangular hyperbola. These two models are then estimated based on
16 observations (one for each country). Based on the parameter estimates, simulations are performed for the two group of countries
starting with the same per capita growth rates in income. Over time it
is seen that the realised growth rate in income is higher for the poor
countries than in rich countries. This is seen to prove the convergence
hypothesis using a demand model.
Overall I found the paper to be interesting and ingenious. However
I have several problems with the paper. First there are no price effects
and it is assumed that long run supply will grow in conjunction with
increased demand. Although the author reasons that relative prices will
not change, I find that reasoning unconvincing for the long run. It is
hard to conceive that the terms of trade between agriculture and
industry will remain the same in developing countries. The author argues
that the increase in (nominal) investment demand will be realised in a
higher real capital stock which will bring forth the requisite supply.
Again, in the absence of price effects in the model, this is all
conjectural.
The argument that at high stages of development the exogenous
sector is larger is not true for many high-income countries like the
U.S. which is conspicuous by its absence. It is interesting to observe
the choice of rich countries which are well known for their large social
programmes and export sectors like Italy, The Netherlands and Germany.
Among the rich countries Poland and Hungary are also included which by
no means are the typical or desirable models of development. Nominal
multiplier effects for poor countries may be larger but with supply
constraints in these economies, this translates mainly into inflation as
we all know.
The SAMs that are used are based on years that vary widely. We find
that India's SAM is for 1968-69 while Pakistan's is lot 1979.
For the rich countries the SAMs are for a more recent years. Besides the
different vintages, it is not clear how reliable these SAMs are,
especially for the developing countries. We do not know how typical were
the years for the countries involved. Basing long term growth tendencies
on average coefficients for one year arouses a great deal of skepticism.
The author points out that CGEs are also based on SAMs. However the CGEs
are purported to be applicable for only the medium term (5 years or so).
Their forecasting performance has not been very promising anyway. Since
the interindustry linkages and flows in the SAM are not utilised for the
exercise in this paper, perhaps a Keynesian demand model (Hicksian IS/LM
framework), based on the National Income and Product Accounts, would
have been more useful. It would have accomplished the same purpose and
the parameter estimates for the calculation of the multipliers would
have been based on longer time series.
This study complements the cross-country growth studies based on
the neoclassical framework. However, it is no substitute.
Nasir M. Khilji
U.S. Bureau of the Census and Economic Adviser
U.S./Saudi Arabian Joint Commission on Economic Cooperation
(JECOR).
REFERENCES
Khilji, N. M., and E. Zampelli (1993) U.S. Assistance and Economic
Growth of Major Aid Recipients. Paper presented at the Annual Meetings
of the Eastern Economic Association held in Washington, D. C., U.S.A.
Marcia.
Levine, R., and D. Renelt (1992) A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-Country Growth Regressions. American Economic Review September.
The sources of SAMs from several developing countries are as
follows:
Egypt: Eckhaus R. S., F. D. McCarthy and A Mohie-Eldin (1981) A
Social Accounting Matrix tot Egypt (1976) Journal of Development
Economics Oct. 1981.
India: Cole S. and G. A. Meagher (1984) Growth and Income
Distribution in India, a General Equilibrium Analysis. In Cohen S. I.,
P.A. Cornelisse, R. Teckers, and E. Thorbecke (eds) The Modelling of
Socio-Economic Planning Processes. Aldershot: Gower Publishing.
Indonesia: Biro Pusat Statistik Indonesia (1982) Social Accounting
Matrix Indonesia 1975. Jakarta: BPS.
Iran: Pyatt G. and J. I. Round (1985) Social Accounting Matrixes.
Symposium Series. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank Publications
Department.
Kenya: Vander Hoeven R. E. (1987) Planning for Basic Needs: A Basic
Needs Simulation Model Applied to Kenya. Amsterdam: Free University
Press.
Sri Lanka: Pyatt G. and A. Roe (1977) Social Accounting for
Development Planning. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
The SAMs for Columbia, Suriname, Korea, and Pakistan have been
constructed by the author and several associates and are reported upon
in detail in Cohen S. I. (1989) Multiplier Analysis in Social Accounting
and Input-Output Frameworks: Evidence for Several Countries. In R. E.
Miller, K. R. Polenske, and A. Z. Roze, Frontiers in Input-Output
Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
The SAMs for six countries from Europe are constructed from the
following sources.
Italy. Civardi M. C. B. and R. T. Lenti (1990). A SAM for Italy.
Paper presented at the conference 'A SAM for Europe'.
Universidad International Mendez Pelayo, Valencia, September 1990.
Spain: Kehoe T. et al. (1985) A Social Accounting Matrix for Spain
1980. Working paper 6386, Universidad Autonoma de Barcelona.
The SAMs for The Netherlands, Germany, Hungary, and Poland have
been constructed by several associates under supervision of the author.
The SAMs for Hungary were done in collaboration with T. Revesz and E.
Zalai of Budapest University of Economic Sciences, and the SAMs for
Poland were done in collaboration with A. Czyzewski, L. Zienkowki, and
Z. Zolkiewski, of the Research Centre for Economic and Social Studies.
Central Statistical Office, Warsaw. More details on the SAMs for Italy,
Germany, The Netherlands, Spain, Hungary, and Poland are found in Cohen
(1993)
Author's Note: The author acknowledges the special
contributions of M. de Zeeuw regarding computations.
REFERENCES
Barro, R. J., and J.-W. Lee (1993) Losers and Winners in Economic
Growth. In Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on
Development Economics 267-298.
Barro, R. J. (1991) Economic Growth in a Cross Section of
Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 407-443.
Baumol, W. J. (1986) Productivity Growth, Convergence, and Welfare:
What the Long-run Data Show. American Economic Review 1072-1185.
Bleaney. M., and D. Greenaway (1993) Long-run Trends in the
Relative Price of Primary Commodities and in the Terms of Trade of
Developing Countries. Oxford Economic Papers 45: 349-363.
Cohen, S. I. (ed) (1993) Patterns of Economic Restructuring for
Eastern Europe. Aldershot: Avebury.
Choen, S. I., and R. Bayens (1994)Dependency Rates in the Dutch
Economy. In P. L. T. Homkers (ed) Solidarity of Generations. Amsterdam:
Thesis Publishers. 315-350.
Dowrick, S., and N. Gemmell (1988) Industrialisation, Catching Up,
and Economic Growth: A Comparative Study across the World's
Capitalist Economies. Economic Journal 101 : 263-275.
Koopmans, T., and J. M. Montias (1971) On the Description and
Comparison of Economic Systems. In A. Eckstein (ed) Comparison of
Economic Systems 27-28.
Krugman, P. R. (1981) Trade, Accumulation and Uneven Development.
Journal of Development Economics 8:149-161.
Lucas, R. E. (1993) Making a Miracle. Econometrica 61:2 251-272.
Mankiw, N. G., D. Romer, and D. N. Weil (1992) A Contribution to
the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 407-437.
Pyatt, G. (1991) Fundamentals of Social Accounting. Economic System
Research 3: 315-341.
Solow. R. M. (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65-94.
Sprout, R. V. A., and J. H. Weaver (1992) International
Distribution of Income: 1960-1987. Kyklos 45: 237-258.
Summers, R., and A. Heston (1988) A New Set of International
Comparisons of Real Product and Price Levels: Estimates for 130
Countries. Review of Income and Wealth 34: 1-25.
Theil. H.. and J. L. Seale (1994) The Geographic Distribution of
World Income. 1950-1990. De Economist 142:4 387-419.
(1) m is a weighted sum of multipliers by sector, i.e. y =
[[summation].sub.v] [m.sub.v] [X.sub.v] = [[summation].sub.v] [m.sub.v]
[s.sub.v] X = mX, where [s.sub.v] is sectoral share of the exogenous
variable X.
(2) The sum of Equation 11.1 does not tally to one because of
unweighted values over sectors and countries. Similarly for Equation
11.2.
S. I. Cohen is Professor of Economics, Faculty of Economic
Sciences, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, The Netherlands.
Table 1 Income, Population, and Income Per Capita: Values,
and Growth Rates by World Regions
Values 1987
Income Income
(Billions Population Per
of US $) (Millions) Capita
(US $)
World 24388 4866 5012
Rich Countries 13583 1032 13162
OECD Countries 10657 707 15074
Communist Countries 2926 325 9003
Poor Countries 10805 3835 2817
S. America and Carib. 1782 404 4411
S. Asia 1164 1076 1082
E. Asia 5270 1441 3657
Arab Region
(W. Asia + N. Afr) 2112 436 4844
Other Africa 296 448 661
Average Annual Income Growth Rates
1961-1987
Income
Per
Income Population Capita
World 4.4 1.8 2.5
Rich Countries 3.7 0.8 2.9
OECD Countries 3.7 0.8 2.9
Communist Countries 3.8 0.9 2.9
Poor Countries 5.4 2.2 3.2
S. America and Carib. 4.8 2.5 2.3
S. Asia 3.9 2.3 1.5
E. Asia 7.0 1.8 5.2
Arab Region
(W. Asia + N. Afr) 4.6 1.9 2.7
Other Africa 2.8 2.8 0.0
Source: Sprout and Weaver (1992), based on Summers and Heston (1988).
Table 2
SAM Features and GNP Per Capita of Sixteen Countries
Country Year GNPP Exogenous
per Cap. Share
(1000$) = X/Y
Poor Countries
Unweighted Average 0.55 0.34
India 1963-69 0.09 0.13
Pakistan 1979 0.17 0.34
Sri Lanka 1970 0.17 0.23
Indonesia 1975 0.21 0.37
Iran 1970 0.22 0.13
Kenya 1976 0.34 0.45
Colombia 1970 0.34 0.22
Egypt 1976 0.35 0.43
South Korea 1979 1.51 0.43
Suriname 1979 2.21 0.76
Rich Countries
Eastern Europe
Unweighted Average 2.26 0.45
Poland 1987 1.93 0.40
Hungary 1990 3.59 0.49
Rich Countries
Western Europe
Unweighted Average 8.70 0.54
Spain 1980 5.40 0.29
Italy 1984 6.42 0.43
Germany 1984 11.13 0.57
The Netherlands 1987 11.86 0.89
Average Multipliers in SAM
Country
Multiplier Highest/
Effect = m Rank (a) Lowest (b)
Poor Countries
Unweighted Average 2.39 ASI 1.54
India 7.06 ASI 1.20
Pakistan 6.11 ASI 1.24
Sri Lanka 3.32 ASI 1.24
Indonesia 2.90 ASI 3.15
Iran 3.33 ASI 1.40
Kenya 1.28 ASI 3.03
Colombia 2.47 SAI 1.18
Egypt 1.15 ASI 1.86
South Korea 1.79 ASI 1.66
Suriname 0.95 SAI 1.48
Rich Countries
Eastern Europe
Unweighted Average 0.85 SAI 1.52
Poland 0.92 SAI 1.57
Hungary 0.77 SAI 1.46
Rich Countries
Western Europe
Unweighted Average 1.30 SAI 1.32
Spain 1.53 ASI 1.36
Italy 1.50 SAI 1.43
Germany 1.33 SAI 1.47
The Netherlands 0.85 SAI 1.13
(a) ASI = Agriculture-Services-Industry;
SAI= Services-Agriculture-Industry.
(b) For example, in the case of India dividing the average
income multiplier of agriculture by that of industry gives
1.20.
Table 3
Regression Results of Equations (9) and (10)
Explained, Explanatory Variables and
Coefficient Estimates [R.sup.2]
Equation (9) X/Y = [beta] [[alpha] + + [E.sub.9]
(Y/N)/ (Y/N)] [D.sub.9]
Coefficient 0.632 0.369 -0.201 0.813
t-value (12.95) (3.25) (-4.84)
Equation (10) ln m = ln [delta] ln + [D.sub.10]
[gamma] + (X/Y) [D.sub.10]
Coefficient -0.077 -0.619 -0.799 0.890
t-value (-0.58) (5.41) (-6.39)
Table 4
Selected Simulations
Assumed
Incomer per
Capita Y/P Population P Income Y
($) Growth (Mln.) Growth (Mln. $) Growth
Year Rate Rate Rate
Simulation for Rich and Poor
Rich 0 8703.0 220.0 1914660
1 8790.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 1953145 0.02010
1 8877.1 0.02 222.2 0.01 1972483 0.03020
Poor 0 551.0 880.0 484880
1 556.5 0.01 888.8 0.01 494626 0.02010
1 556.5 0.01 897.6 0.02 499523 0.03020
1 562.0 0.02 897.6 0.02 504469 0.04040
1 567.5 0.03 897.6 0.02 509415 0.05060
1 573.0 0.04 897.6 0.02 514361 0.06080
Simulations for Different Income Levels
0 100.0 220.0 22000
1 101.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 22442 0.02010
0 551.0 220.0 121220
1 556.5 0.01 222.2 0.01 123657 0.02010
0 1000.0 220.0 220000
1 1010.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 224422 0.02010
0 2000.0 220.0 440000
1 2020.0 0.01 222.0 0.01 448844 0.02010
0 4000.0 220.0 880000
1 4040.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 897688 0.02010
0 6000.0 220.0 1320000
1 6060.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 1346532 0.02010
0 8000.0 220.0 1760000
1 8080.0 1.00 222.2 0.01 1795376 0.02010
0 8703.0 220.0 1914660
1 8790.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 1953145 0.02010
0 10000.0 220.0 2200000
1 10100.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 2244220 0.02010
0 12000.0 220.0 2640000
1 12120.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 2693064 0.02010
0 20000.0 220.0 4400000
1 20200.0 0.01 222.2 0.01 4488440 0.02010
Predicted Solution
Exogenous Exogenous
Share X/Y Value X Multiplier m Income
(%) Growth (mln. $) Growth Value Growth Growth
Year Rate Rate Rate Rate
Simulation for Rich and Poor
Rich 0 0.606 11609 1.2612
1 0.607 0.00040 11847 0.02051 1.2609 -0.0003 0.02026
1 0.607 0.00080 11969 0.03102 1.2606 -0.0005 0.03053
Poor 0 0.379 1835 1.6879
1 0.380 0.00399 1880 0.02417 1.6838 -0.0025 0.02171
1 0.380 0.00399 1898 0.03431 1.6838 -0.0025 0.03185
1 0.382 0.00793 1925 0.04865 1.6797 -0.0049 0.04377
1 0.383 0.01182 1951 O.06302 1.6757 -0.0072 0.05578
1 0.384 0.01567 1978 0.07742 1.6718 -0.0096 0.06785
Simulations for Different Income Levels
0 0.135 30 3.1977
1 0.136 0.00785 30 0.02811 1.1822 -0.0048 0.02328
0 0.379 459 1.6879
1 0.380 0.00399 470 0.02417 1.6838 -0.0025 0.02171
0 0.462 1016 1.4928
1 0.463 0.00268 1039 0.02283 1.4903 -0.0017 0.02118
0 0.534 2348 1.3649
1 0.534 0.00154 2399 0.02168 1.3636 -0.0010 0.02072
0 0.579 5092 1.2982
1 0.579 0.00084 5199 0.02095 1.2975 -0.0005 0.02044
0 0.595 7860 1.2754
1 0.596 0.00057 8022 0.02069 1.2750 0.0004 0.02033
0 0.604 10633 1.2640
1 0.604 0.00044 10852 0.02055 1.2636 -0.0003 0.02028
0 0.606 11609 1.2612
1 0.607 0.00040 11847 0.02051 1.2609 -0.0003 0.02026
0 0.610 13410 1.2571
1 0.610 0.00035 13684 0.02046 1.2568 -0.0002 0.02024
0 0.613 16188 1.2524
1 0.613 0.00030 16518 0.02040 1.2522 -0.0002 0.02022
0 0.621 27306 1.2432
1 0.621 0.00018 27860 0.02028 1.2430 -0.0001 0.02017