Has aid helped in Pakistan?
Khan, Shahrukh Rafi
This paper has a two-fold objective: first, to examine the terms on
which Pakistan receives aid and whether its debt situation is
sustainable, and second, to examine the impact of aid and debt on
economic growth. It is found that there is little encouraging that can
be said about how the terms on which Pakistan has received aid over time
have changed, and its current debt situation is not sustainable. Also
reported is the analysis done elsewhere which shows that aid has a
negative (Granger) causal impact on GDP. and aid has a robust negative
impact on economic growth after controlling for supply-side shocks. We
provide various reasons for this negative association.
1. INTRODUCTION
Aid theory in early years of thinking on economic development was
straightforward. The developing countries were perceived to be in need
of substantial investments in infrastructure and capital which could not
be financed internally. According to the traditional two-gap theory, aid
was necessary to bridge both the savings-investment gap and the trade
gap in developing countries and was thus considered indispensable. Aid
was advocated for establishing the preconditions for growth by
strengthening institutions and building infrastructure and for enhancing
growth via resources for investment. The increase in economic activity
generated by aid supported investments was expected to increase output
growth, eventually generating enough income to render aid superfluous.
Ridell (1987) and White (1992) present rich reviews of the long and
as yet unresolved debates. For applied economists, the message is that
most attempts at assessing the impact of aid on saving, investment and
growth suffer from various flaws. These include unresolved theoretical
issues, faulty data, particularly for cross-country analysis,
specification errors that call into question the scientific rigor of the
findings and the difficulty in modelling the mechanisms via which aid
actually impacts various macroeconomic variables including growth. (1)
These reviews and the conclusions they reach would give pause to
applied economists seeking to empirically test the aid-growth
association as we do in this paper. We proceed because our contention is
that causality and sensitivity tests, that have been used elsewhere, can
make a contribution to the empirical debate on the association of aid
with economic growth. The method used in this paper is straightforward
and time series data for other countries are readily available in the
sources cited; thus the research done for this paper could easily be
replicated for other countries, given the availability of some specific
country knowledge.
In the next section, we review how the terms of aid have been
changing over time in Pakistan. In the third Section three, we present
the findings and we end with a discussion of the findings. (2)
2. AID TERMS AND STRUCTURE OF DEBT
While Pakistan's foreign debt is large (20.4 billion in 1993
in nominal terms), and has been growing rapidly (at an annual average
rate of 7.8 percent between 1972 to 1993), in a cross country
perspective it is still modest. Pakistan's total long term debt in
1992 was 57 percent below what one might expect it to be given its per
capita GDP (in purchasing power parity terms) and population. (3)
However, other than this, there is little encouraging that can be said
about the current change in Pakistan's debt situation and about how
the terms on which Pakistan receives aid over time have changed.
Concessional aid as a percentage of the total has declined, the
average interest rate has increased, the maturity period has decreased,
the net transfer has decreased and the grant element has decreased. Thus
Pakistan's debt, the debt/GDP ratio, debt/export ratio and
debt-service ratio have increased, particularly since 1987-88 when the
more intensive phase of the structural adjustment period started. In the
summary tables below, we present evidence to back these statements. Our
analysis here covers the period 1972-73 to 1992-93. (4)
As mentioned above, Table 1 shows that the terms on which Pakistan
has received aid over time have worsened across the board. The average
maturity period of loans, grant element in loans and concessional aid as
a percentage of the total have all declined. The average interest rate
on which loans are contracted increased by one percentage point at a
time when market interest rates were declining. Thus in the 1988-89 to
1992-93 period, the loans are contracted at only two percent below the
market interest rate down from 6 percent below in the 1977-78 to 1987-88
period.
With the worsening of the terms of the debt, one would expect the
debt ratios to rise and debt indicators to worsen, particularly when the
debt stock was increasing. This is evident from Table 2 below.
The debt-GNP ratio was exceptionally high in the 1970s, partly due
to lower GNP growth rates. It rose 6 percent since 1988-89, which
represents the start of the intensive bouts of structural adjustment,
compared to the earlier sub-period. While debt has been steadily
mounting (from $6.8 billion in 1977 to $20.4 billion in 1993), the net
transfer (gross-inflows minus principal and interest payments) has
rapidly declined. Thus, it declined from a substantive 5.1 percent of
GNP in the 1972-73-1976-77 period to 0.3 of one percent in
1988-89-1992-93 period.
Sustainable debt management is possible if the likely trajectory of
resource inflows will exceed or at least converge on the likely
trajectory of resource outflows. The important outflows are imports and
debt servicing and the important inflows arc exports and remittances.
Based on these flows, we compared debt servicing with the sum of
remittances and export revenues minus the import bill. As a percentage
of the GNP, this sum amounted to a negative 32.9 percent in the first
period (1972-73-1976-77), improved to 3.10 percent (due to remittances)
in the second period (1977-78-198788) but worsened again to 24.9 percent
in the third period (1978-79-1992-93). The worsening of this
inflow/outflow balance resulted from both a decline in remittances and
the worsening of the balance of trade. The result is that Pakistan is
now in a non sustainable situation with regards to managing its debt
comfortably.
Given this analysis and the changing terms under which Pakistan is
receiving aid, there is every likelihood that the debt/GDP ratio will
continue to rise. Pakistan is in an all too familiar situation--as the
country's dependence on foreign aid increases, the terms and
conditions of aid inflows are becoming all the more stringent. Not only
does debt repayment threaten to become "an exchange rate drag"
in perpetuity, (5) the conditionality under which aid has been received
since the later 1980s has also become more extensive and more stringent.
(6) The total debt and debt ratios should be expected to improve over
time if the aid, as the original theory suggested, enhanced growth and
enabled the debt to be retired.
3. FINDINGS
We used two simple approaches to test the association of aid and
output. (7) The first was to test for the Granger causality between aid
and economic growth. (8) The second was to estimate the association of
aid on economic growth in a standard growth model and rigorously test,
via a sensitivity analysis proposed and used by Levine and Renalt
(1992), to see if the coefficient of aid was robust.
The result of the Granger causality tests indicated that higher GDP
did not Granger cause higher aid but that aid negatively Granger caused
GDP. This finding was not sensitive to the lag-length and suggested that
a ten percent increase in aid is associated with a 0.4 percent decline
in GDP.
The results from estimating the growth equation support these
findings. We added subsets of the conditioning variables (two variables
at a time) to the base regression equation with capital, labour and aid
and estimated twenty-one augmented growth equations. (9) These
conditioning variables include size of exports as a percentage of GDP as
a proxy for openness, foreign direct investment, inflation, size of
industry, terms of trade, age dependency ratio and total debt stock as a
percentage of GDP. We found aid to have a negative and highly
significant coefficient irrespective of the conditioning variable
combination used. (10) Also, the base aid-output elasticity coefficient
was 0.04. This elasticity varied from a high of 0.06 to a low of 0.03.
The sensitivity test showed that our finding of a negative and
significant association of aid with growth was robust. (11)
Nevertheless, due to the small sample size, we can only view these
results as suggestive.
The debt/GDP ratio was not a robust variable. Fry (1992) showed
that the debt/GDP ratio in excess of 50 percent has a negative impact on
economic growth due to capital flight and a decline in the quantity and
efficiency of investment. (12)
While we did not have data to estimate sector production functions,
we were able to correlate project aid to the agricultural and industrial
sectors with output in these sectors for the period 1972-73 to 1987-88.
These sectors combined accounted for about a third of total cumulative
project aid over this period, with industry drawing about double the
amount drawn by agriculture. (13) Both partial correlation coefficients
were very low and insignificant when aid was used as a contemporaneous variable. Aid lagged one period had a positive correlation with the
agricultural sector (.48) which was significant at the 10 percent level
but with industry it was negative (-.37) and insignificant. (14) While
the agricultural coefficient is positive, as a partial correlation
coefficient it is low and only weakly significant. Thus there is little
support for aid effectiveness even with sectoral disaggregation.
4. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION
There is little about the aid/debt scenario for Pakistan that is
positive. With the intensive period of structural adjustment in the late
1980s, the debt/GDP ratio and the debt service/export ratio rose
compared to the mid-1970s to late 1980s period. Concessional aid as a
percentage of the total has fallen, the average interest rate is higher,
the maturity period is lower and the grant element is lower. Thus not
only is Pakistan heavily in debt, but also, the changing terms of the
debt are going to make it much harder to get out of the debt trap.
The harsher terms on which Pakistan gets aid make the debt trap
more formidable as does the economics of the aid-growth nexus. At first,
our findings about the negative Granger causal effect of aid on GDP and
the statistically robust negative impact of aid on economic growth may
appear odd. In fact, one could argue that these results imply that
Pakistan would be progressively better off the more of its resources it
gifted to another country. But such an argument represents a fundamental
misunderstanding about the nature of aid. Aid represents a package
including policy parameters such as prescriptions about fiscal, trade
and exchange rate policy. Had these policies suited Pakistan's
economic environment, aid would have positively impacted GDP growth.
Another way of looking at this is to expect the debt/GDP ratio to fall
if aid was really successful. Table 2 shows that while this ratio
declined in the late-1970s to the late 1980s, it rose again from the
late 1980s to the early 1990s reflecting Pakistan's inability to
retire its debt. Co-incidently, this represents a period of intensive
structural adjustment. There are several factors that could neutralise
the effectiveness of aid. Aid goes to the public sector and blockages,
inefficiency, misuse and leakage are likely to reduce the effectiveness
in the use of these resources as is the case with other public sector
expenditures. Additional reasons identified in the literature include
project selections biased towards prestigious but economically unsound large projects, foreign exchange intensive projects and infrastructure
rather than productive projects. (15) The lack of government-donor and
intra-donor co-ordination could similarly reduce the effectiveness of
aid. (16) As is well known, much aid returns to the country of origin in
the form of expensive consulting contracts. (17) Similarly, the
effectiveness of aid can be reduced by "tying" agreements
calling for the purchase of equipment and materials from donors at costs
much more than cheaper alternatives of similar quality. (18)
The above factors explain why aid may not be as effective as it
might otherwise be. For the negative association, one can turn to the
earlier literature on the negative aid saving association. This
literature has been reviewed in detail in the surveys by Ridell (1987)
and White (1992) referred to earlier. Prominent advocates of this
negative association include Griffen and Enos (1970) and Weisskopf
(1972). Using a two stage least square model with growth estimated in
the first stage and the fitted growth used in a saving function in the
second stage, we also identified a negative association of official
transfers and the saving rate between the 1971 and 1990 period. However,
the magnitude of the effect was extremely small and, besides that, the
saving equation was not cointegrated.
In general, the negative aid-saving association may be one of the
channels explaining the negative aid-growth association. However, other
factors have also been identified in the literature as possible
explanations. That there is a short-run recessionary impact of
adjustment policies is unlikely to be questioned by any economist. In
addition, aid and debt leads to a destructive "foreign exchange
drag". As noted by [Cassen et al. (1990), p. 1.16], debt repayment
represents an outflow of free standing foreign exchange in contrast to
the conditional and tied inflow of foreign exchange that aid represents.
Further, foreign exchange, relatively easily available in the short run,
can induce the "dutch disease" syndrome (making exports
noncompetitive due to the artificial appreciation of the exchange rate).
Finally, the negative impact of commodity aid on local production has
been discussed in the literature. (19)
Surprisingly, the notion of aid to the public sector inducing
inefficiency by providing a soft-budget constraint has not been
discussed in the literature. This concept was originated by Kornoi
(1986) and is widely viewed as an important explanatory factor in the
failing of socialist economies. The extension of this concept to
aid-recipient governments seems quite self-evident, and this may be the
most important explanatory factor in explaining the negative growth-aid
association.
The public choice literature which discusses inefficient
rent-seeking and empire building also provides a rationale for this
association in so far as aid enables inefficient administrative
structures to survive. The realisation for the need for accountable
government has not yet translated into effective institutional reform.
The reasoning above and our findings show that it is possible to
rule out the counter factual that matters may have been even worse
without aid. Given the negative Granger causal effect of aid on GDP and
the robust negative and significant statistical association of growth
and aid, one can only expect Pakistan to get more and more indebted. As
earlier mentioned, our method explores an aggregate association. Our
findings thus are not inconsistent with the existence of effective
(where the benefits out-weigh the costs) donor programmes and projects
initiated by bilateral and multilateral aid agencies. (20) Also, it is
possible that we have identified a negative association in the
"second phase" of aid receiving whereas in the "first
phase" of aid receiving, on more generous terms, the infrastructure
basis of later growth may have been established.
If aid in the aggregate sense is "bad", why does Pakistan
continue to solicit it'? While aid may have a negative impact on
the economy, it could benefit at least some of those who decide whether
or not to solicit it. Even if one can rule out overt vested interests,
aid represents the path of least resistance. Policy-makers in Pakistan
jump from managing one crisis to the next one and grasp at whatever
straws they can in the process, no matter how harmful they are in the
long run. Furthermore, sensible long run policies are not avoided
because they inflict pain on the poor. Pakistan's policymakers have
shown themselves quite adept at testing these limits. Sensible long run
policies are avoided because they inflict pain on the elites.
The only alternative to aid is to raise revenues internally and to
institute just economies in expenditures. But this would mean sensible
long run policies like tax reform, including closing exemptions and
other tax loopholes, asking legislators to start taxing their
agricultural incomes and the cutting of luxurious expenditures by
politicians and the civil and military bureaucracies at state expense.
The issue of peace and cutting the military budget has also been raised
many times by others. This and other economies are now more necessary
than ever.
Comments
The paper presented by Shahrukh Raft Khan addresses the most
important economic problem Pakistan is facing currently. The question he
has raised is whether foreign aid is useful or detrimental to economic
growth in Pakistan. Using standard regression analysis, the author shows
that growth in foreign aid in a year results in reduced rate of economic
growth in the same year. The results also show that the negative effect
of the growth rate of aid on the GDP growth rate is not very sensitive
to various conditioning variables included in the regression equation,
one at a time.
These results are in sharp contrast to the traditional view that
foreign aid contributes to economic growth. The author provides several
convincing arguments to explain the negative association between aid and
growth. One of the main arguments is that aid can contribute to economic
growth when it is assumed that parameters of the economy remain
unchanged. Since aid is usually contracted as a package that includes
specific policy prescriptions, such an assumption is unrealistic.
According to the author, some other factors that can neutralise the
contribution of aid to economic growth include mismanagement,
inefficiency, and leakages in the utilisation and allocation of aid.
Thus, the paper does an excellent job in explaining the results and
concludes that the presumed positive contribution of foreign aid to
economic growth is based on misperceived assumptions that do not hold in
reality.
While the paper addresses the core issue of the current debt
problem in Pakistan and the conclusions reached are plausible, I have a
few observations on the way the relationship between aid and growth is
structured in the theoretical part of the paper. As the author has
mentioned in the introduction, the relationship between aid and growth
is quite complicated. The model developed in the paper, however, does
not provide sufficient theoretical underpinnings that can be linked to
the observations. In my opinion, the econometric approach adopted in the
paper is inappropriate to address the problem at hand.
Whether aid is good or bad for the economy is an inter-temporal
problem. When the focal point of analysis is economic growth, the
relationship could be framed in a better way around a dynamic structure.
This is how the literature treats the problem. The traditional dynamic
models of, for example, Kemp and Hamada or the gap models can be easily
modified to consider the effects of changing parameters (for example,
due to inefficiency or policy prescriptions) on the relationship between
aid and growth. Using a straight-line relationship between aid and
growth can at best be a crude approximation.
An alternative framework of analysis could be to trace the effect
of aid injections on the time paths of the key parameters that affect
the savings rate and productivity and then determine the effect of the
latter on the time path of growth rate. Such an analysis is more likely
to expose the complex relationship between aid and growth. For example,
one can determine the timing of the turning-points when the nature of
the relationship is altered in a fundamental way.
Despite the above observations, it is difficult to understate the
contribution of this paper to the understanding of a complex problem. An
important contribution of the paper is that, despite being a
quantitative exercise, it relates the results with some of the
well-known qualitative issues relating to aid, which are often discussed
but seldom incorporated in formal economic modelling exercises.
Eatzaz Ahmad
Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Author's Note: Thanks are due to Safiya Aftab, Tariq Banuri,
and Zia Mian for useful comments. Our analysis dealt with economic aid,
since no data on military aid were available.
REFERENCES
Banuri, T., S. R. Khan, and M. Mahmood (eds) (1997) Just
Development: Protecting the Vulnerable and Promoting Growth. Karachi:
Oxford University Press.
Cassen, R., and Associates ([986) Does Aid Work? New York: Oxford
University Press.
Cassen, R., A. Duncun, S. Guisinger, E. Hooper, and O. Noman (1990)
The Effectiveness of Aid to Pakistan. Islamabad: Economic Affairs
Division. Pakistan and UNDP.
Chishti, S., and M. A. Khan (1992) Foreign Aid, Defence Expenditure
and Public Investment in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 31:4
895-908.
Edwards, S. (1993) Openness, Trade Liberalisation and Growth in
Developing Countries. Journal of Economic Literature 31:1358-1393.
Fry, M. J. (1992) Some Stabilising and Destabilising Effects of
Foreign Debt Accumulation in Developing Countries. Economic Letters 39:
315-321.
Granger, C. W. J. (1969) Investigating Causal Relations by
Econometric Methods and Cross-sectoral Methods. Econometrica 37:
424-438.
Griffen, K. B., and J. L. Enos (1970) Foreign Assistance,
Objectives, and Consequences, Economic Development and Cultural Change 18:313-327. International Monetary Fund (1994) international Financial
Statistics. Washington, D. C.: IMF.
Levine, R., and D. Renelt (1992) A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-country Growth Regressions. American Economic Review 82: 942-963.
Kemal, A. R. (1992) Self-reliance and Implications for Growth and
Resource Mobilisations. The Pakistan Development Review 31:4 1101-1110.
Khan, N. Z., and E. Rahim (1993) Foreign Aid, Domestic Saving and
Economic
Growth, 1960-1988. The Pakistan Development Review 32:4 1157-1167.
Kornai, J. (1986) The Soft Budget Constraint. Kyklos 39: 3-30.
McGillivray, M., H. White, and A. Ahmed (1994) Evaluating the
Effectiveness of Structural Adjustment Policies on Macroeconomic
Performance: A Review of the Evidence with Special Reference to
Pakistan. Paper prepared for presentation at AERC/Goethe Conference on
Political and Socioeconomic Consequences of Policy-based Lending,
Karachi.
Mosley, P., J. Hudson, and S. Horrell (1987) Aid, the Public
Sector, and the Market in Less Developed Countries. Economic Journal
97:616-641.
Ridell, R. C. (1987) Foreign Aid Reconsidered. London: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Sims, C. A. (1972) Money, Income, and Causality. American Economic
Review 62: 540-552.
Weisskopf, T. E. (1972) The Impact of Foreign Capital Inflows on
Domestic Saving in Underdeveloped Countries. Journal of International
Economics 2: 25-38.
White, H. (1992) The Macroeconomic Impact of Development Aid: A
Critical Survey. Journal of Development Studies 28: 163-240.
(1) Empirical research in Pakistan by Kemal (1992): Chisti and
Hasan (1992); Khan and Rahim (1993) and McGillivray, White and Ahmad
(1994) are subject to the same critique.
(2) To meet space requirements. the details of the analysis and
tables are not reported. but are available on request from the author.
(3) This result is based on the fitted value and residual of a
cross-country regression using a sample of 49 LDCs, with long term debt
as the dependent variable and population, population squared and GDP in
purchasing power parity terms as predictor variables
(4) The period after the creation of Bangladesh.
(5) By this we mean that Pakistan will continue to have to push
export growth, which gives a articular slant to the economy, and turn
over the foreign exchange earnings as debt repayment.
(6) See chapter five of eds. Banuri, Khan and Mahmood (1997) for an
account of these onditionalities and their social and economic impact.
(7) Our interest is in the impact of aid, as an aggregate variable,
on economic growth. This is because policy leverage is conditional on
the sum of loan and grant aid. Nonetheless, we also explored the
separate impact of grants (with and without technical assistance) on
economic growth. We explored the robustness of the association between
aid and economic growth and not the channels via which aid can affect
growth. Mosley, Hudson and Horrel (1987) model the channels via which
aid can influence growth.
(8) Granger (1969).
(9) We used two conditioning variables at a time because of the
small sample.
(10) The results of the base regression were much weaker when only
grants (with or without technical assistance) was used instead of the
aid variable. Also, the results were much weaker when aid was included
in the base regression contemporaneously.
(11) An advantage of the co-integration analysis which we utilised
is that it helped in avoiding spurious results.
(12) See Table 1 for Pakistan's debt/GDP ratio.
(13) Cassen et al. (1990), Annex, Tables and Bibliography, Table
10-z.
(14) The contemporaneous and one period lagged aid correlation
coefficient was .32 (p = .23) and 48 (p = .07) with agricultural output
and -. 14 (p = .59) and -.36 (p =. 18) with industrial output.
(15) [Ridell (1987), pp. 114].
(16) [Cassen et al. (1990)].
(17) [Cassen et al. (1990), p. 2A.9] report that consulting draws
away about 10 percent of all aid in Pakistan.
(18) [Cassen et al. (1990), p 1.50] speculate, based on the
findings of an earlier study, that tying" increases the cost of
procurement in Pakistan by about 30 percent.
(19) Commodity aid was about a quarter of total non-military aid in
1987-88, the latest year for which such disaggregated data are
available. [Cassen et al. (1990), Annex, Tables and Bibliography. Tables
2z and 6z].
(20) For examples, see Cassen et al. (1990), pp. 1.12-1.22.
Shahrukh Raft Khan is Executive Director, Sustainable Development
Policy Institute. Islamabad.
Table 1 Terms of Debt
Average Average
Average Market Interest Maturity
Years Interest Rate Rate (@) Period (Years)
1972-73 to 1976-77 4 na 28
1977-78 to 1987-88 5 11.20 27
1988-89 to 1992-93 5 6.70 22
Concessional
Average Grant Aid as a % of
Years Element Total
1972-73 to 1976-77 48 73
1977-78 to 1987-88 42 69
1988-89 to 1992-93 37 56
Source: World Debt Tables, World Bank.
Notes: @ = LIBOR for one year $ deposits (International Financial
Statistics Yearbook 1994, IMF. Washington, D. C., p. 96).
Table 2 Debt Ratios and Debt Indicators
Average Average Debt Average Net
Debt-GNP Service-export Transfer
Period Ratio Ratio (Billion $)
1972-73 to 1976-77 57 0.21 0.51
1977-78 to 1987-88 42 0.20 0.16
1988-89 to 1992-93 48 0.24 0.14
Average Nominal End
Net Transfer as Period Debt (@)
Period a % of GNP. (Billion $s)
1972-73 to 1976-77 5.08 6.8
1977-78 to 1987-88 0.87 13.9
1988-89 to 1992-93 0.30 20.4
Source: World Bank, World Debt Tables.
Notes: @ = End period is the last year of the period in question.
For-example, for the 1972-73-1976-77 period, the end period year is
1976-77. For trended variables, such as debt, end-period numbers
rather than period averages often give a better picture of the
existing situation and how it has changed over time.