A preliminary analysis of the marketing of mango in Sindh Province, Pakistan.
Khushk, Ali Muhammed ; Smith, Laurence E.D.
Fruits are an important sub-sector in the agricultural sector of
Pakistan. This paper describes the structure and operation of the
marketing channels, and quantifies marketing margins of producers and
other market agencies.
Survey results show that more than 90 percent of producers sold
harvesting rights to their orchards to contractors. The producers'
share of the retail price was calculated to be 25 percent. The other
shares were 43 percent for contractors, 6 percent for commission agents,
5 percent for wholesalers, and 21 percent for retailers. Other
indicators reported here are net profit margins, duration and type of
contract, method of contract price determination, mode of payment, and
conduct of auctions.
INTRODUCTION
Horticultural crops contribute about 4.0 percent of the GDP and 20
percent of national food production, and annual fruit production is
about 3.96 million tonnes. The area of fruit orchards in Pakistan is
about 456 thousand hectares [Khan (1994)]. Out of this area, small
growers (0.5 to 5 hectares) farm 66 percent, medium growers (5-20 ha) 23
percent, and large growers (over 20 ha) 11 percent. Among the major
fruits, mango occupies the second most important position after citrus in terms of area and production: 173 thousand hectares is under citrus,
followed by mango (86 thousand hectares), guava (47 thousand hectares)
and date palm (42 thousand hectares).
Mango consumers are convinced by its good flavour, delicacy, and
nutrient value, and domestic demand is strong. Mango producers tend to
increase production due to the sustained and favourable income
generated. There is the potential to increase mango exports to many
countries, with strong demand for mango products in the Middle East and
Europe.
Mango yields in Pakistan are quite low, 8-9 tonnes/ha, which is
considerably less than the average world yield of 25 tonnes/ha [Sauco
(1993)]. The gap between potential and actual yields is very wide. This
yield gap is the result of poor management practices and post-harvest
losses. It has been found that the majority of growers do not follow the
recommendations for an effective use of fertilizer, sprays, and timely
irrigation. Post-harvest problems include improper handling, immature fruit harvesting, inadequate transport and storage facilities.
Post-harvest losses were estimated at about 20 to 40 percent of the
total fruit production in Pakistan [Malik (1994)]. Many orchards in
Sindh are also affected by soil waterlogging and salinity.
The objective of this paper is to report preliminary research
findings that describe the structure and operation of the mango
marketing channels and to quantify the marketing margins of producers
and market intermediaries.
METHODOLOGY
This paper is based on primary data collection from a survey of
mango producers, market intermediaries, and fruit markets in producing
and consumption areas. Sindh province was selected for this study
because it is considered to be the main fruit-growing region of
Pakistan. In Sindh, mango orchards are particularly located in Hyderabad
and Mirpurkhas districts. The taluka of Tando Allahyar in Hyderabad
district was purposively selected as a representative study area.
Initially, an informal survey of mango producers and market
intermediaries in various markets in the study area was carried out to
gain an understanding of the existing fruit marketing system. Open-ended
interviews were held with representatives of each category of
respondents to identify key issues and variables. Sampling frames for
each category of respondents were prepared and interview checklists and
general questions were refined. Formal interviews were completed with
the following samples: producers 120; contractors 20; commission agents
20; wholesalers 15; retailers 20; and exporters 10 respectively.
DESCRIPTION OF THE MANGO MARKETING SYSTEM IN SINDH
(a) Mango Marketing Channels
Agricultural marketing channels are concerned with the concept of
"marketable" or "marketed" surplus of farm
commodities that enter the process of circulation and exchange. The
purpose of exchange of commodities for money, and vice versa, is to have
access to a variety of products. Here agricultural marketing channels
refer to the outlets or routes through which commodities pass to reach
final consumers. The existing mango marketing channels are presented in
Fig. 1.
(i) Mango Producer
A large majority of the mango producers (90 percent) sold the
harvesting rights to their orchard to contractors at the flowering
stage. Only 10 percent sold their produce directly to market themselves,
mainly in the hope of getting better prices. Reasons for the dominance
of the contracting system are discussed below.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
(ii) Contractor
The contractor performs a key role in the marketing of fruits.
Usually, he maintains a close contact with a commission agent in the
wholesale and terminal markets. While contracting an orchard, the
contractor estimates its yield and considers the expected costs to be
incurred for supervision, labour, transportation, and marketing. After
meeting the requirements for own domestic consumption, and payment in
kind to the orchard-owners plus pre-harvest and post-harvest losses,
contractors had about 89 percent of the produce available for sale in
the market.
(iii) Commission Agent
The main function of commission agents is to bring buyers and
sellers together. They maintain contacts with inter-regional wholesale
markets and possess comprehensive and accurate information. They perform
their activities on a commission basis, and do not accept title of
goods, when selling the produce brought by producers or contractors.
They have establishments at markets, equipped with telephone and other
communication facilities.
(iv) Wholesalers
Wholesalers buy and sell large quantities of farm products. Usually
they perform their business in wholesale and terminal markets. They deal
in several commodities such as fruits, vegetables, and other
agricultural produce within interregional markets and also supply
produce to processing industries, exporters, and retailers according to their demand. They maintain contacts with commission agents in wholesale
markets and retailers in the local area. Wholesaler usually purchase
fruit from the commission agents at open auction and sell in smaller
quantities to the retailers and consumers. They mostly buy from the
commission agents on a credit basis, and about one week after selling
that quantity, they pay the commission agents. Some wholesalers also act
as commission agents.
(v) Retailer
All market activities Come to an end with the retailers. They buy
and sell small quantities according to the demand of consumers in the
area. They maintain direct contact with consumers and make transactions
according to the qualitative and quantitative aspects of the products. A
small number of fruit retailers occupy small shops in the main fruit
markets or in the town. The majority of fruit retailers are hawkers,
selling from barrows consisting of a wooden platform mounted on four
cycle wheels. They move from street to street to offer fruit for sale.
Moreover, a number of retailers are found standing at focal places of a
town, particularly railway stations, bus stands, vicinity of courts,
schools, and hospitals. Among fruit retailers there is a high degree of
competition. Retailers buy fruit from the Wholesalers on a 24-48 hour
credit basis.
(b) The Mango Contracting System
Contracting out harvest of the mango orchard is the most common
practice in the study area. Mango fruit is highly perishable in nature
and there is also market price fluctuation due to the seasonal
concentration of fruit in the market. Therefore, it needs careful
handling, quick transport, sound packing and timeliness of all
operations if good prices are to be realised.
(i) Reasons for Using Contractors
Mango producers usually avoid the marketing of fruit as they do not
want to be involved in the complication of the marketing system. Also
producers do not want to take the risk of price and income variation due
to perishability, qualities, and seasonality. In addition, the most
important reason reported by producers in response to an open-ended
question is the lack of knowledge of marketing. This needs to be
interpreted broadly.
There is a bias on the part of commission agents between producers
and contractors. The commission agents do not extend short-term loans to
producers to enable them to manage their orchard and to buy inputs and
packing material in time. Also, commission agents do not want to
transfer market price information to producers or provide other
facilities, such as accommodation and telephone access, at the
market-place. Therefore, producers have very little information about
the marketing of their produce, and face a number of barriers to active
participation in the process. It is through these mechanisms and the
tying of contractors through provision of loans that commission agents
can exert some control over the supply of produce.
Another reason reported by the producers is that they are growing
other crops, at the time of harvesting of mango. Completing the wheat
harvest and sowing of the cotton crop or other kharif crop are the main
activities. Therefore, they do not spare enough time for marketing of
fruit, and prefer to sell an orchard to a contractor. Finally, out of
the sampled respondents, 16 percent of mango producers stated that they
decided to contract out the orchard because of the need for a cash
advance.
(ii) Duration of Contract
The harvesting contract is mostly decided on the basis of mutual
understanding between producer and contractor. 60 percent of producers
contracted out their orchard for one year, and the remaining 30 percent
and 10 percent of producers contracted for a period of two and three
years respectively. The contract amount is decided on a per acre or per
tree basis, but normally on a per acre basis. Mango producers lacking
capital, especially absentee landlords in a weak financial position,
tend to sell their orchard for more than one year. They bargain less on
the contract amount, but normally demand a one-year advance payment and
thus remain tied to the same contractor for a longer period.
(iii) Type of Contract
During the survey it was found that three types of contract are
commonly used. The most common method used by 50 percent of mango
producers is a contract "without management practices". In
this method, all orchard management costs upto harvest are paid by the
producer himself, and all activities are undertaken by him. The contract
is normally for one year only and the contractor simply picks and
markets the fruit. Another contract includes the cost of "pesticide spray" among the responsibilities of the contractor. In this
method, all management costs are borne by the producer except the cost
of pesticide spray. Finally, in the third method, contracts include
"all management costs", i.e., ploughing, interculturing, use
of inputs like farm yard manure, fertilizer, and pesticide sprays, and
are considered to be the responsibilities of the contractor. In this
case, the contract is usually of more than two years in duration.
(iv) Selection of Contractor
Many contractors approach growers seeking contracts by offering
their bids. Producers normally decide on a contract after meeting 5-6
contractors. 52 percent of producers selected the contractor who offered
the highest price for their orchard and 38 percent selected contractors
who have a good reputation in respect of timely payment. Once a
contractor has established his reputation among producers and commission
agents, he appears to run his business smoothly with relatively
unlimited access to capital.
(v) Mode of Payment
Payments depend on the type of contract and the conditions set out
during the agreement. The most common method, adopted by 82 percent of
contractors, is the payment of one-third of the total contract amount at
the time of signing the contract. Although there is no formal legal
procedure for signing the contract, a verbal agreement is accepted by
both parties and comes into force after payment of the first instalment.
The second instalment, again one-third of the total, is paid when half
of the crop is harvested, and the final instalment when all the crop is
harvested and before it leaves the orchard. Other methods, which are
less common, include the payment of a one-year advance, or two
instalments in a year.
(vi) Determination of the Contract Price
Almost 47 percent of mango orchards were contracted soon after
fruit formation. In this case, the contract amount is decided on the
basis of the present crop condition. In addition, contracting of
orchards continues until August and September. The contract amount is
decided in these cases for the coming season. Key factors in determining
the contract price are the orchard condition, the experience of last
year's production, and the price prevailing in the area.
The survey results showed that 35 percent of producers set prices
on the basis of the last year's production and 15 percent sold
their orchards to those contractors who offered the highest prices.
Moreover, the reputation of the contractor plays a big role in
determining the price of the mango orchard. The honesty and fair record
of the contractor regarding timely payment of instalments and other
conditions set out during the time of agreement contributes to a lower
price of contract as compared to that for other contractors.
(vii) Default in Payment
Occasionally, growers do not receive the full amount of the
contract price agreed. Failure in payments to grower is quite frequent
for one reason or another. In particular, adverse weather conditions
during harvest offer a reason for contractors to delay payments or
reduce the contract amount. The survey results show that more than 20
percent of the contractors defaulted in payment to producers. In 72
percent of these cases the producers agreed to reduce the contract
amount keeping in the view the crop production destroyed due to natural
hazards.
(viii) Relationship between Contractor and Commission Agent
More than 95 percent of contractors obtained loans from a
commission agent to pay the initial instalment to the mango producers
and to pay an advance for labour and packing material. Once a loan has
been extended, the contractor is obliged to supply mango to that
commission agent.
There are strong commission agents' associations in each
market which maintain strict procedures to control contractors.
Commission agents are not allowed to transact with a contractor who is
already indebted to another commission agent. In this case, the new
commission agent would have to pay all of a contractor's dues to
enable him to leave the first agent.
Commission agents mainly distribute credit among contractors during
February and March, when the crop is at the flowering stage. As soon as
harvest of mango starts, contractors bring their produce for sale to the
same agent. The commission agent sells the produce and keeps an account
for the contractor. During marketing of produce, the contractor can not
obtain the sales revenue from the commission agent, because he obtained
the advance credit. The commission agent only provides the contractor
with any further necessary expenses including second and third
instalments for orchard owners and payment for labour and packing
material.
The contractor normally remains in the orchard during the harvest
season to supervise the labour and arrange the transport and packing
material. The commission agent, when receiving the produce in the
market, is authorised to sell the produce and keep the account for the
contractor. At the end of the season, the contractor visits the market
and settles the whole season's account with the commission agent.
The commission agent prepares a statement for the contractor of the
whole season's arrival and its revenue, minus outstanding advances,
market expenses, and commission. Differences with the contractor's
own accounts or estimates are reconciled but the contractor will often
be in a weak negotiating position if he requires credit for the next
season.
Commission charges range between 8 to 12 percent of the sale
revenue. The commission varies from contractor to contractor and from
contractor to producer. A contractor who has no outstanding advance and
can supply a large quantity of produce by contracting many orchards will
be in a position to bargain on the commission rate. In contrast, a
contractor in debt and without alternative sources of credit will accept
a higher commission rate.
If, for example, due to natural hazards, the contractor does not
achieve sales sufficient to cover the contract amounts and other
management and marketing expenses, then the debt will be carried over to
the next season without any interest charges on that amount. In that
season the commission agent will again provide advances to the
contractor in the expectation of an improved year. Through these
arrangements contractors tend to become tied to the same commission
agents for a number of years.
The commission agents have the power to control the mango supply
through contractors. In the early season they encourage contractors to
bring their mango to the market as they can earn higher prices. Whereas
in mid-season they encourage the contractor to delay the harvest as they
can get a better price in late season. Due to delay in harvest during
mid-season, a large portion of the mature fruit tends to be lost, but
these losses accrue to the contractors.
(c) Mango Auctions
As soon as the mango reaches the market, the representative of the
commission agent receives the truck and takes charge of the crates.
Different varieties are stacked in different lots. During this time, the
prospective buyers form a circle around the commission agent who opens
one sample crate for each lot, and allows the buyers to inspect the top
layer of the packed mangoes. At the same time, the agent utters some
publicity slogans in favour of the produce he intends to auction. When
the buyers are satisfied with the quality of the fruit, the auction
starts. The auction is conducted in two ways: (i) open auction and (ii)
secret auction.
(i) Open Auction
In an open auction, buyers offer open prices for a lot of mangoes
offered for sale. During the market survey, it was observed that open
auctions only take place for 'B' and 'C' grade mango
quality. The open auction runs from early morning until the new arrival
of mango is completed. During the open auction, the producer or
contractor can watch the auction and know exactly the price of their
produce. In principle, lots could be withdrawn if bids are too low, but
it is unusual that a higher price could be achieved before the fruit
deteriorates.
In open auctions, the participating buyers are the wholesalers,
retailers, and shopkeepers. Price differences were observed based on
variety, grading, packing, location, and timing. Early and late mango of
any variety received good prices, whereas even top quality mango does
not achieve high prices during mid-season. The wholesaler and retailer,
after taking delivery Of the packed fruit, keep the crates closed in
store for about 5 to 7 days till the fruit turns colour but is still
firm. Then the fruit is graded according to the size, colour, and
appearance and exhibited in the shop. Different grades are offered at
different prices.
(ii) Secret Auction
In the secret auction, the commission agent covers his hand with a
piece of cloth and the buyers touch the hand of the agent and indicate
by their touch the price they are ready to pay for the lot. The
consignment is sold to the buyer offering the highest price. The secret
auction is mainly used for 'Special' and 'A' grade
mango quality. These qualities are bought by exporters for export
purposes. In the secret auction, the producers and contractors do not
know the actual price of their produce, but they must accept the price
the commission agent reports. Two main reasons for the secret auction
were revealed by the survey.
The first reason reported by the respondents was that most of the
commission agents are also engaged in fruit exports. Therefore, the
commission agent can buy produce under another name and send that
produce for export. The second reason reported was that in the secret
auction the commission agent normally retains a 10-20 percent share of
the actual price of that produce. Because of the credit-tying
arrangements, contractors feel unable to openly object to this system.
MARKETING MARGINS ANALYSIS
Marketing margins are the differences between prices at two market
levels and are commonly used to examine the differences between producer
and consumer prices for the same quantity of a commodity. Marketing
margins represent the price charged by market agencies for the services
provided, including buying, packing, transportation, storage, and
processing. Under competitive market conditions, market margins are the
result of the demand for marketing services and equal to the minimum
cost of services provided plus normal profit [Scarborough and Kydd
(1992)].
In order to measure market margins, data on mango prices were
obtained at different stages in the marketing chain. It is very
difficult to come up with a unique solution for the price to be used.
There are many complications in formulating standard prices, which can
be summarised as: (a) day-to-day variation of prices, (b) varietal differences, (c) grade differences, (d) price variation over the season,
(e) basis for averaging the various grades and varieties, and (f) price
differences in consumption and production areas.
Such problems have been resolved by collecting prices which may
cover most of the above conditions. The price of mango was collected on
a per crate basis; the average weight per crate is about 14-15 kg. Mango
prices were collected fortnightly throughout the harvest season from
assembly, wholesale, and terminal markets and for different market
intermediaries. At the same time, retail prices of mango were collected
from the same city from retailers and shopkeepers. Simple averages for
the mango price per crate for three time periods and different market
intermediaries were calculated.
(a) Absolute Cash Margins
It is often believed, particularly by growers, that middlemen in
agricultural produce marketing take away a large share of the total
profit. To investigate this issue, the absolute cash margins for each
market intermediary have been estimated (Table 1). The absolute cash
margin or price spread is the difference between the price paid and
received by each specific market intermediary.
The absolute cash margin of producers was calculated as the sale
price of the orchard per crate harvested by the contractor. The absolute
cash margin of contractors is the sale price in the market less this
purchase price and sale commission per crate. The absolute margin of
commission agents is the commission on sale revenue.
To estimate the margins of wholesalers and retailers was more
difficult. The margin varied from one variety to another and from one
grade to the next. The figures in Table 1 are simple averages for all
varieties and grades. "Look at the difference in the size of the
mango in this crate and difference in quality", one wholesaler
explained in the Karachi market.
(b) Net Profit Margin
The production costs of mango producers were estimated at Rs 14 per
crate, which includes ploughing, farm-yard manure (FYM), fertilizer,
pesticides, and interculturing during the year. The contractor incurred
costs of Rs 42 to 53 per crate. This variation occurred due to the
variation in commission on mango prices during the season. Commission
agents incurred costs of Rs 6.50 per crate. This includes an accountant
(Munshi), shop rent, telephone bill, and the entertainment of
contractors and producers at the market. Wholesalers had costs of Rs
4.65 per crate, and this included transportation of produce from the
auction floor to shop, rent, and licence fees. Retailers had costs of Rs
9 per crate, which included transportation of produce from market to
sales area and rent of shop or barrow, etc.
The net profit margin of a market intermediary is the net earning
gained after paying all costs (Table 2). Mango producers do not benefit
from seasonal price variation, because they contract out their orchards
at the time of flowering. In contrast, contractors received a maximum
price of Rs 139 per crate at the end of the harvest season and a minimum
of Rs 31 per crate during mid-season. There is a similar pattern for
wholesalers and retailers.
DISCUSSION
Abid (1980) studied the major fruits, i.e., dates, bananas, and
mangoes, in Sindh province and estimated the producer share of the
retail price as 20, 15 to 22, and 22 to 24 percent, respectively.
Siddiqui (1979) estimated equivalent figures of 27, 15, and 24 percent,
respectively.
Memon (1978) quotes figures of 24, 23, and 22 percent,
respectively. The economic research unit in Quetta estimated a producer
share of 30 percent of the retail price for apples [University of
Balochistan (1988)]. Muhy-ud-din (1991) estimated a producer share of 40
percent for citrus in Punjab.
Swarup (1985) ascertained the producer share in Himachal apple
cultivation in India. He concluded that the producer share did not
increase despite a sharp increase in apple prices. Results showed that
producers received 46 and 48 percent of the retail price in Amritsar
market during 1975 and 1984 respectively.
The results here are thus consistent with other similar research in
the region. Assessment of whether or not the values found for the
indicators presented here show definitively that the marketing system is
fair and efficient is, however, a difficult exercise and beyond the
scope of this paper.
In general, it has been observed that there is competition at each
market stage. No strong evidence was found of collusion among agencies,
with prices at each stage normally set by supply and demand factors;
whilst spread of information regarding quantity and price is fast and
rapid amongst all agencies other than producers.
Timely and accurate availability of market information is important
since any improvements in the quality and dissemination of market
information should, in theory, improve both operational and pricing
efficiency. The main sources of market information for mango producers
are commission agents, transporters, contractors, and neighbouring
growers. The information received was often inaccurate, misleading,
delayed, and without uniform distribution among producers. There is no
effective dissemination of market information among producers that can
help them decide the best time to bring their produce to the market.
There are no fixed criteria for entry and exit as a contractor.
Anyone who has contact with a commission agent and is able to receive
advances for contracting the orchard could enter the business. However,
it was observed that the majority of contractors belong to the interior
area of Sindh, and are associated with the farming community. This may
be essential to gain acceptance from land-owners.
In contrast, for commission agents and wholesalers, there are many
barriers to entry in the business. Lack of space in the market is one of
the most important elements because shops and auction floors are fully
occupied and tend to remain occupied by the same family for a long time.
It was also observed that certain ethnic groups dominate and may
restrict the entry of other groups, especially in wholesale and terminal
markets. Finally, a large initial investment is required, particularly
for a commission agent. A successful commission agent must have a strong
relationship with contractors, and sufficient capital to invest in the
seasonal advances.
In general, other studies of fruit marketing systems in Pakistan
have taken the relatively low marketing margins of producers as an
indicator of non-competitive and exploitative market systems that favour
traders. Here contractors have been found to receive the highest margins
in the marketing of mango in Sindh, but this may reflect their
relatively high and unpredictable costs, and the fact that they bear the
most risk. Apart from variation in yield and post-harvest losses, risk
also arises from transport problems, variation in the price of packing
material, management of labour, and the unregulated behaviour of
commission agents. Whilst producers can potentially achieve higher
returns by marketing mango themselves, they may prefer a lower but less
risky income paid partly in advance, particularly when account is taken
of the opportunity cost of the management input required for fruit
picking and marketing.
Commission agents obtain a relatively low margin per unit volume of
mango but are transacting large volumes over each season. Their main
risk is non-recovery of loans which are advanced to secure a reliable
and controllable supply rather than to generate profit from the credit
transaction itself. Higher profits may arise from the practice of
'secret auctions' and the combination of wholesale or export
businesses with their role of commission agent.
The main risks for wholesalers and retailers are price variation
and the failure to sell perishable produce in time. Also, while
wholesalers generally grade and repack, their stock retailers have less
opportunity to ascertain the .quality of lower layers of fruit in the
crates purchased. The degree of competition apparent between
wholesalers, and particularly retailers, suggests that their market
margins are not excessive.
CONCLUSION
Further investigation is required before definitive judgements can
be made about the efficiency of the marketing system in Sindh. Analysis
is needed of the transaction costs and risks for producers and market
intermediaries in an environment of poor transport and communications
infrastructure, poor security, a dysfunctional legal system for the
enforcement of agreements, and widespread public sector corruption.
Given such an environment, it is, however, simplistic and unrealistic to
conclude that the relatively low share of the retail price received by
producers is the result of monopsonistic or exploitative behaviour by
traders, as has tended to be the trend in past studies.
The fact that ninety percent of producers sell the harvesting
rights to their orchards to contractors indicates that the contract
system provides economic advantages to them. On the other hand, it is
also apparent that producers face great difficulties in marketing their
own produce. In assembly, and particularly in wholesale markets, they
are treated as temporary clients without access to the credit and other
facilities extended to contractors. Without adequate access to market
information, they also face high price uncertainties. Lack of capital
and limited access to institutional credit lead producers to rely on
relatively high-cost informal credit sources and advances from fruit
contractors.
In the current environment, it is difficult to recommend feasible
means to improve the efficiency of the fruit marketing system in Sindh.
Public investment in infrastructure is justifiable to reduce
transactions costs and risks. Encouraging at least some entrepreneurial
producers to market their own output would introduce more competition
into the first stage of the marketing chain and help ensure that the
margins gained by contractors are not excessive. This requires
improvement of access to credit at the mango flowering stage to finance
an improved use of inputs in orchards and the working capital for labour
and packing material. It also requires dissemination of the market price
information through mass media.
Improved access to alternative sources of credit for both producers
and contractors, as well as effective legislation to outlaw 'secret
auctions', would also improve their bargaining position in dealing
with commission agents, helping to reduce the dominant market position
of the latter.
REFERENCES
Abid, M. Sami Khan (1980) Marketing lnfra-structure, Margins and
Seasonal Price Variation of Selected Agricultural Commodities in Sindh
Province of Pakistan. Tando Jam: Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, Sindh Agriculture University.
Khan, D. A. (1994) Problems and Prospects of Horticulture in
Pakistan. Proceedings of the First International Horticulture Seminar.
Islamabad: Pakistan Agriculture Research Council.
Mohy-ud-din, Q. (1991) Improving Marketing System of Citrus Fruit
in the Punjab Province. Pakistan Agricultural Development Review 1:2
35-44.
Memon, R. A. (1978) Marketing Infra-structure, Margins and Seasonal
Price Variation of Selected Agricultural Commodities in Sindh Province
of Pakistan. Tando Jam: Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural
Sociology, Sindh Agriculture University.
Malik, M. N. (1994) Challenges for the Year 2000 in the Field of
Horticulture. Proceedings of the First International Horticulture
Seminar. Islamabad: Pakistan Agriculture Research Council.
Scarborough, V., and J. Kydd (1992) Economic Analysis of
Agricultural Marketing: A Manual. Chatham, U.K: Natural Resources
Institute.
Siddiqui, S. A. (1979) Marketing of Agricultural Products in Sindh.
Tando Jam: Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology,
Sindh Agriculture University.
Swarup, et al. (1985) Price Spread and Marketing Margins for
Himachal Apples: Temporal and Spatial Analysis. Indian Journal of
Agricultural Economics 11:3 433-446.
Sauco, V. G. (1993) The Situation of Mango Culture in the World.
Acta Horticulture (Fourth International Mango Symposium, Miami, USA)
341: 31-41.
University of Balochistan (1988) A Study of Channels and Margins in
the Marketing of Apple in Balochistan. Quetta: Economic Research Unit.
Ali Muhammed Khushk and Laurence E. D. Smith are based at the
Department of Agricultural Economics. Wye College, University of London.
Table 1
Market Margins of Mango Producers and Other Market Intermediaries
(Absolute Cash Margin Rs/Crate and % Share of Retail Price)
Market Early Mid Late Whole
Intermediaries Season Season Season Season
Producer 70 (28%) 70 (35%) 70 (18%) 70 (25%)
Contractor 98 (39%) 73 (36%) 192 (49%) 121 (43%)
Commission Agent 15 (6%) 12 (6%) 23 (6%) 17 (6%)
Wholesaler 17 (7%) 10 (5%) 15 (4%) 14 (5%)
Retailer 50 (20%) 35 (18%) 90 (23%) 58 (21%)
Retail Price Rs 250 200 390 280
Source: Survey data, 1995.
Table 2
Net Profit Margin of Mango Producer and Other Market
Intermediaries (Rs/Crate)
Market Early Mid Late Whole
Intermediaries Season Season Season Season
Producer 56 56 56 56
Contractor 53 31 139 74
Commission Agent 8 6 16 10
Wholesaler 12 5 10 9
Retailer 41 26 81 49