Government investment and economic growth in the developing world.
Khan, Mohsin S.
I. INTRODUCTION
There has been a sea change in the views of the economics
profession as well as economic policy-makers over the past decade or so
regarding the role of the government in the development process. Indeed,
it is now becoming conventional wisdom that government can no longer be
a dominant player in economic activities, but rather should restrict
itself to providing an "enabling" environment within which the
private sector can take the lead and flourish. More specifically,
government intervention in the economy has to be designed carefully so
as to support the private sector and not inhibit its development. The
general acceptance of this paradigm is evident in the steadily declining
importance of government activities in the economies of most of the
developing world.
But does this new paradigm mean that government investment has no
role whatsoever in affecting growth in developing countries? Reality is
that public investment still represents a large share of total
investment in the majority of developing countries, and the question is
what role it plays in relation to private investment in stimulating
economic growth. The objective of this paper is to ascertain empirically
for a large group of developing countries the relative importance of
public and private investment in promoting and sustaining growth.
Despite considerable interest in the issue, the empirical evidence
on the relative effects of public and private investment on growth in
developing countries is quite limited. A number of recent studies
examining this issue have shown that private investment has a larger
positive impact on growth than public investment [Khan and Reinhart
(1990); Coutinho and Gallo (1991); Serven and Solimano (1990) and Khan
and Kumar (1997)]. However, many of the existing studies have used small
samples of countries over limited time periods, so that the validity and
robustness of this conclusion is still in doubt. Moreover, to examine
the relative effects of public and private investment, a number of other
important issues related to differences in the two components of
investment across developing country regions or across countries in
different income groups need to be investigated. Finally, other
determinants of growth, such as macroeconomic instability, which have
received considerable attention in the recent literature, have also to
be taken into account when assessing this issue.
The empirical analysis in this paper is undertaken for a sample of
95 developing countries for the period 1970-90. The large sample allows
for consideration of the hypothesis that there are significant
differences in the differential effects of public and private investment
on growth for four developing country regions--Africa, Asia, Middle
East, and Latin America. (1) Such an examination has merit in view of
the marked differences in the performance of developing countries during
the last two decades. Asian countries, for instance, have had generally
a superior performance than have African or Latin American countries. To
the extent that the steady-state conditions underlying the differential
growth performance--reflecting, for example, the rate of technological
change and population growth--are likely to be more similar across
developing countries, looking specifically at these countries can yield
additional insights into the process of convergence of real per capital
incomes of developing countries. (2)
The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section II first
discusses-the extent to which public and private investment may be
complementary or substitutes, and then describes the estimation equations to be used in the empirical analysis. Section III contains the
main empirical results. While the bulk of the empirical analysis is
undertaken using cross-sectional data and single equation estimation
techniques, estimates using pooled-time series data, with growth
computed over different time horizons, and instrumental variable
techniques to take into account the simultaneity between private
investment and growth, are also presented. Section IV examines the
implications of the differential impact of public and private investment
for the speed of convergence to a steady-state. Finally, Section V
contains a summary of the main findings.
II. PUBLIC INVESTMENT AND GROWTH
1. Patterns of Public and Private Investment
The magnitude of public and private investment in developing
countries over the last two decades is illustrated in Table 1. It is
striking that public sector investment in developing countries accounts
for nearly half of total investment. In industrial countries, by
contrast, public investment accounts for less than one fifth of total
investment. (3) To the extent that the needs of developing countries for
infrastructural and related capital are greater than those of the
industrial countries, and given the indivisibilities and risks involved
in the provision of such capital, the share of public investment might
be expected to be higher in lower-income countries. Nevertheless, the
information in Table 1 raises questions concerning the efficiency of
public investment relative to private investment and its contribution to
long-run growth in developing countries.
In general, public investment in infrastructure, by being
complementary to private investment, could increase the marginal product of private capital. (4) This is most likely to be true in those
developing countries where the existing stock of infrastructure capital
is generally inadequate. In this regard, it is worth noting in Table 1
that the share of public investment in countries in Africa and the
Middle East is higher than that of private investment; in Asian and
Latin American countries private investment has a higher share. It has
become evident over the last few years, however, that public investment
in infrastructure may not automatically have a beneficial impact on
private investment and growth. In many cases, political-bureaucratic
motivations have led to expenditures in infrastructure facilities that
were sub-optimal. This occurred in part because the concern was with
maximising employment than with creating these facilities at low cost.
Also, it occurred because regional or other political considerations
resulted in uneconomic location, size, or even sector of the investment
projects.
In addition to investment in infrastructure, a large part of public
investment is undertaken by state-owned enterprises. In most developing
countries, industrial policy and the regulatory framework have linked
private sector production directly to public sector activities in both
goods and factor markets. For instance, an expansion of the capacity of
public enterprises to produce industrial inputs--including production of
basic metals, chemicals, and so on--is necessary before the private
sector can undertake investments in sectors that are dependent on these
basic inputs. Given the pervasive role of public enterprises in many
countries, capacity expansion by such enterprises can lead to an
increase in private sector investment undertaken for the purpose of
satisfying the additional demand. This complementarity may have been
encouraged through the granting of selective incentives for directing
private investment to fulfil public investment plans.
The above considerations suggest that while the public sector
capital stock may be complementary to private sector activities and have
a positive effect on growth, its efficiency may be questionable
sometimes. Moreover, in many developing countries public sector
enterprises often compete directly with the private sector in the
provision of goods and services. In these cases, an increase in public
investment could have an adverse effect on private investment both
directly, as well as indirectly via the public sector budget constraint.
In the case of the latter, each of the different modes of financing
public sector investment can have an effect on private investment. If,
for example, public investment is financed by increasing taxes, it may
further exacerbate distortions in the economy and increase the costs of
inputs, leading to an adverse effect on expected output growth and
private investment. Where it is financed by market borrowing, public
investment could have an adverse effect on the availability of credit,
as well as on the real cost of capital to the private sector. Finally,
in the case of monetisation of deficits, crowding out occurs through an
increase in the inflation rate, which creates uncertainty with regard to
the expected returns from investment.
2. Specification of Equations
The differential impact of private and public sector investment on
growth can be evaluated via the framework of an extended neoclassical
growth model [Solow (1956)]. In this well-known model, capital
accumulation, growth of labour force, and technical change are the key
determinants of real per capita income. Thus real per capita income in
this model is specified as follows: (5)
Ln(Y/L) = a + [gamma] t + [alpha]/1 - [alpha] Ln(S) - ([alpha]/1 -
[alpha]) Ln(n + [gamma] + [delta]) + [epsilon] ... (1)
where Y and L denote real output and labour respectively; [alpha]
refers to the share of aggregate capital in income; S is the aggregate
saving (and investment) rate; n and [gamma] are respectively the growth
rate of labour and technology; [delta] denotes depreciation of the
capital stock; and [epsilon] is an error term.
The above model was extended by including separately public and
private capital stocks. Assuming that both types of capital stock
depreciate at the same rate [delta], real output per capita can be
specified as follows:
Ln(Y/L) = a + [gamma] t + [alpha]/1 - [alpha] - [beta] Ln(Sg) +
[beta]/1 - [alpha] - [beta] (Sp) -
[alpha] + [beta]/(1 - [alpha] - [beta]) Ln(n + [gamma] + [delta]) +
[epsilon] ... (2)
where in addition to the above variables, Sg and Sp now denote
public and private investment respectively; and [alpha] and [beta]
denote the shares of public and private capital in income.
The specification of Equations (1) and (2) is based on a strong
assumption that all countries are at their steady states. However, it is
possible to extend Equation (2) to allow estimation of the effect of
various explanatory variables on per capita growth.
Following Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992), it can be shown that
Equation (2) can be transformed into an equation for the steady state
growth path as follows:
Ln(y(t)) - Ln(y(0)) = (1 - [e.sup.-[lambda]t) [[alpha]/1 - [alpha]
- beta] Ln(Sg) + [beta]/1 - [alpha] - [beta] Ln(Sp) - [alpha] + [beta]/1
- [alpha] + [beta] Ln(n + [gamma] + [delta]) - Ln(y(0))] + [epsilon] ...
(3)
where the left-hand side of the equation is the growth of per
capita income, [lambda] = (n + [gamma] + [delta])/(1 - [alpha] - [beta])
is the speed of convergence and y(0) is income per capita at some
initial date; the other variables are defined as before.
Equation (3) is the basis for the empirical analysis of the effect
of public and private investment on per capita growth. The estimates of
variants of Equation (3) are all obtained in unrestricted form, that is
without imposition of the theoretical restrictions across the parameters
of the various explanatory variables.
In estimating Equation (3), allowance is made for cross-country
differences in [gamma], reflecting technical change, as well as
differences in human capital and macroeconomic stability. Concerning
technical change, it is sometimes suggested that in the long-run both
the "disembodied" and the "embodied" technical
change in a country are related to its exposure to foreign trade and
investment. Several recent theoretical and empirical contributions link
such exposure to foreign markets, managerial techniques, etc. This link
allows for not only a one-time shift in production possibilities, but
also for sustained increases in growth rates due to dynamic scale
economies and learning by doing [Grossman and Helpman (1990); Edwards
(1992)]. Instead of assuming [gamma] to be constant across countries, in
the empirical specification it is allowed to vary as a function of a
country's trade orientation and the inflow of foreign direct
investment. The procedure adopted is to assume that for the average of
the sample the value for [gamma] assumed by Mankiw, Romer and Weil
(1992)--2 percent a year--holds. Deviations from this average value are
then related to trade orientation measured by the average share of
exports and imports to GDP, and to the inflows of foreign direct
investment relative to GDP.
Following the recent literature on growth, human capital--which has
received considerable emphasis in explaining cross-country differences
in long-run growth--was incorporated as an explanatory variable. (6)
Finally, macroeconomic instability, which has been shown to adversely
affect growth, was also considered. (7) One of the key measures of such
instability--budgetary deficits--was introduced into the equation as an
additional explanatory variable.
III. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
1. Effects on Growth
Consider first the empirical results for the model in Equation (3)
with aggregate investment as the main explanatory variable and
technological change invariant across countries. Columns (1) to (3) in
Table 2 provide these results for three different periods--1970-90,
1970-80, and 1980-90. (8) Column (1) shows that for the 1970-90 period
as a whole, the fit of this equation is quite good; nearly a third of
the cross-country variation in per capita real GDP growth over the past
two decades is explained by the variation in the investment ratio,
initial per capita income, and population growth. All the variables have
the expected signs and are statistically significant. The variable of
special interest is the investment ratio. The estimated coefficient suggests that a one percentage point increase in the investment ratio
across developing countries is associated with an increase in per capita
real GDP of three-quarters of a percentage point. (9) For the
sub-periods the patterns are similar, although the coefficients of the
investment ratio, as well as the fits of the equation, are somewhat
lower than for the full period.
Now one can proceed to consider the separate roles played by public
and private sector investment in determining per capita growth. As
indicated in Column (4) of Table 2, while both types of investment had a
positive impact in the estimates for the full period 1970-90, their
magnitude differed considerably, with private investment having a much
stronger impact than public sector investment. However, the results for
two sub-periods diverge markedly: during the 1970s, both public and
private investment had a similar effect and it was only during the 1980s
that the greater impact of private sector investment emerged. One
explanation for this difference could be that in the earlier period the
stock of infrastructural capital was lower in most developing countries,
and thus the returns from such investment were higher. Put this way, it
can be argued that there was much more complementarity between private
and public investment than was the case during the last decade.
An attempt was made next to see whether allowing technical change
to vary across countries alters these basic results. Assuming a given
average rate of technical change, it was postulated that technical
change was a function of a country's trade orientation and the flow
of foreign direct investment, and a country-specific proxy was
accordingly constructed. In none of the estimates of Equation (3) did
this proxy appear significant, or lead to any change in the relative
effect of public and private investment, compared to the original
assumption of no cross-country variation. This result could be due to
the fact that in the original specification of Equation (3) there is an
implicit restriction that the coefficient on technical change (in
conjunction with population growth) is equal in size to the sum of the
coefficients on public and private investment. The lack of any
statistical significance of this proxy may simply reflect a rejection of
this restriction. When the trade and the direct investment ratios were
entered independently in the regression equation, they had a positive
but statistically weak effect that did not alter the earlier results.
The extent to which taking-into account human capital and budgetary
position changes the basic conclusion was also examined. The stock of
human capital was proxied by the average of the proportion of population
with school enrolment at the primary and secondary school level. The
budgetary variable was the balance of the general government as a
proportion of GDP averaged over the entire period or the two
sub-periods. As shown in Column (7) of Table 3 both these variables
enter the regression with the expected sign, are statistically
significant, and generally improve the explanatory power of the
equation. (10)
2. Regional Variation
An analysis was also undertaken to assess the impact of regional
differences by re-estimating Equation (3) with slope dummies for both
private and public investment for each of the four regions. The results
in Table 3 show that for the 1979-90 period, the regional slope dummies
increase considerably the explanatory power of the Equation, which now
accounts for over half the cross-country variation in per capita growth
of real GDP. The standard "F" test of no differences in the
impact of public and private sector investment was strongly rejected.
The regional differences were quite marked and accorded with standard
priors. For Africa, and to some extent for the Middle East, both types
of investment exercised a similar impact, while in Latin America public
investment appeared to have had, on average, very limited impact and
private investment a pronounced positive effect. In Asia, public
investment was statistically significant, but had an effect on growth
only about half that of private investment.
A somewhat different picture emerged for the two sub-periods.
During the 1970s, public investment had a statistically insignificant
impact in both Asia and Latin America, but a significant one in Africa,
where the size of the coefficient exceeded that on private investment,
as well as in the Middle East grouping. During the 1980s, for both
Africa and the Middle East the size and significance of the coefficients
of public investment declined, while for the other two regions there is
no noticeable change. This result implies that the difference between
the impact of private and public investment across all developing
countries during the last two decades is largely due to variations in
the effects in the African and Middle Eastern regions.
It is also interesting to consider whether the above regional
differences were associated with differences in income and the level of
development across developing countries. It could be argued that in
low-income countries, regardless of the region, the need for
infrastructure public investment is likely to be greater than in the
high-income countries. Furthermore, in the high-income countries, the
private sector is likely to be sufficiently developed to provide many of
the goods and services which otherwise would have to be provided by the
public sector. Hence, in the low-income countries the impact of public
investment may be greater than in the high-income countries. This
hypothesis was tested by reestimating Equation (3) by including two
slope-dummies for public investment: one for countries in the low-income
group (defined as the bottom one-third of all countries ranked by per
capita GDP in 1970) and the other for countries in the high-income
group. The results showed that the impact of public investment in the
low-income group was noticeably greater than in the high-income
group--the slope coefficients had values of 0.33 and 0.25,
respectively--but it still remained less than the effect of private
investment.
3. Two-stage Least Squares Estimates and Panel Data
There are two types of extensions which can be made to the
empirical analysis. The first is econometric, namely to explicitly take
into account the correlation between the right-hand-side variables such
as private investment and the error term. In order to examine whether
using alternative estimation procedures alters the basic results in any
marked manner, estimates using Two-Stage Least Squares (TSLS) were also
obtained. A second extension would be to use pooled rather than
cross-sectional data, so that information on the dynamics of the growth
process can be taken into account. Although long-run growth is more
appropriately examined in a cross-sectional framework, the relationship
between public and private investment and growth was also examined using
pooled time-series cross-section data to assess the robustness of the
results reported above.
The results of TSLS shown in Table 4 suggest conclusions that are
broadly similar to those obtained using the OLS. Private investment has
a decidedly higher effect on growth compared to public investment, and
the human capital variable has a positive coefficient that is not
statistically significant.
With regard to the use of panel data, there are two additional
issues that should be noted. The first is the period over which the time
series data are averaged, since the use of annual data would be
inappropriate for analysing the growth process and in any case would
exhibit excessive noise. The procedure adopted was to average growth
over a period ranging from three to five years. (11) This is a more
general procedure than that in the literature where growth has been
arbitrarily averaged over five-year periods. The second issue concerns
the use of specific model estimation procedures for panel data. The
results presented use OLS on the full sample. (12)
Since the panel procedures assume common slope coefficients for all
observations, they are rather restrictive. Nevertheless, even with this
restriction, the results presented for the three- and five-year horizons
reinforce the earlier findings using cross-sectional data (Table 4,
Columns (3-4). A number of additional interesting results also emerge.
For instance, given the shorter time horizon, there is now virtually no
relationship between initial GDP and subsequent growth. The human
capital variable, while positive, has a statistically weak effect. An
interesting result is the relatively similar effect of private and
public investment on growth in Asia. For this region, it could be argued
that in the short run public investment provided an equal boost to
growth as did private investment, but this effect was not sustained over
time.
IV. IMPLICATIONS FOR THE SPEED OF CONVERGENCE
This section looks at the implications of the above empirical
findings for the speed of convergence of real per capital incomes among
developing countries. Since private investment appears to have had a
considerably larger impact on per capita growth than public investment,
the steady-state growth rate of an economy would increase in proportion
to the share of private investment. However, this result says very
little about the speed with which the steady-state path is attained, or
equivalently, the speed of convergence among countries. For instance,
even if the steady-state growth is significantly higher because of
private investment, the speed of transition towards this steady state,
or the rate of convergence, may remain unaffected.
From a policy-maker's perspective, whether or not the speed
can be affected by policy changes may perhaps be as important as the
effect of policy changes on the growth path itself. This is so since the
transition to an optimal growth path, in the framework utilised above,
is likely to last a considerable length of time, and any measures which
can speed up that process would be regarded as highly desirable. Hence,
in the literature on the determinants of long-run growth and
convergence, while the emphasis has been mainly on factors determining
the steady-state growth path, the issue of the speed of transition has
also received significant attention. [See, for example, Lucas (1988);
Romer (1989); Barro (1991); Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) and Mankiw,
Romer and Weil (1992)].
The methodology for examining this issue is to introduce an
additional regressor in Equation (3), which is an interactive term
consisting of the product of the log of initial income and public
investment ratio. The specific form of this equation is
Ln(y(t)) - Ln(y(0)) = (1 - [e.sup.-[lambda]t) [([alpha] + [beta]/1
- [alpha] - [beta] (Ln(S) - Ln(n + [gamma] + [delta]))] -[Ln(Sg) x
Ln(y(0))] - Ln(y(0))] + [epsilon] ... (4)
If the coefficient on the interactive term in Equation (4), plus
the coefficient on the initial income term, is smaller than that on
initial income term alone (without the additional regressor), it would
mean that countries with more public investment have a higher speed of
convergence. If the combined coefficient is unchanged, it would mean
that the share of public investment does not affect the speed of
convergence. If, however, it is larger, then public investment slows
down the rate of convergence. This procedure is then repeated with
private investment and a comparison is made of the speed of convergence.
The results of estimating Equation (4) are given in Table 5. Column
(1) of this table indicates that without separating the impact of public
and private investment, the implied rate of convergence among the
developing countries was 0.013. However, as Column (2) indicates, when
the interactive term is introduced, although the coefficient on this
term is negative, the combined effect (in terms of the coefficient on
the initial income) is now smaller. This yields a speed of convergence
which is somewhat slower than the speed of convergence without the
interactive term. However, as Column (3) shows, when a similar procedure
is undertaken with private investment, although the coefficient on
private investment is positive, the net effect is greater. Thus an
increase in private investment increases the speed of convergence by
around a third compared to an increase in public investment.
V. CONCLUSIONS
This paper has considered a number of issues relating to the extent
to which public and private investment exert a differential effect on
long-run growth of developing countries. The empirical analysis took
account of other determinants of per capita growth, including population
growth, human capital formation, trade orientation, and measures of
macroeconomic instability.
Utilising a large sample of 95 developing countries over the period
1970-90, a variety of empirical tests were undertaken. The main results
can be summarised as follows.
First, there is a substantial difference in the impact of private
and public sector investment on growth, with private investment having a
much larger impact than public investment, especially during the 1980s.
This finding holds up even when other determinants of per capita growth
are taken into account, alternative estimation techniques are used, and
with data averaged over different periods.
Second, there are significant regional variations in both the
effect of public and private investment on growth. The difference
between the effects is most apparent for Latin America and Asia, but
much less pronounced for Africa and the Middle East country groupings.
There is also a significant difference across different income groups.
Finally, the relative shares of public and private investment
appear to have altered not only the steady-state growth path, but also
the speed of convergence of real per capita incomes among developing
countries. A higher share of private investment in the total appears to
be associated with an increase in the speed of convergence.
In conclusion, it is evident from the analysis in this paper that
studies of the growth process in developing countries should make a
distinction between the respective roles of public and private capital
formation. Furthermore, the empirical evidence supports the proposition
that private investment has a stronger effect on growth than does public
investment. This result is consistent with the now widely accepted
paradigm that the private sector holds the key to sustained growth and
economic development. Yet at the same time, the government can play a
critical part in the process by identifying much more rigorously the
types of investment that have positive net returns and are likely to be
complementary to the private sector. Public investments that do not meet
these criteria would appear to affect growth and factor productivity
adversely, and thus should be cut or not undertaken. Governments in
developing countries would be well-advised to be guided by this
principle.
Appendix
SAMPLE AND DATA DEFINITIONS
1. Sample of Developing Countries
The sample consists of 95 developing countries. The countries
included are:
(a) Africa
Algeria, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape
Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo, Cote
d'Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia,
Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar,
Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Mauritania, Morocco, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda,
Sao Tome and Principe, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Somalia,
Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Tunisia, Uganda, Zaire, Zambia, and
Zimbabwe.
(b) Asia
Bangladesh, China, Fiji, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia,
Mayanmar, Nepal, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Sri Lanka, and
Thailand.
(c) Latin America
Argentina, Barbados, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica,
Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti,
Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Surinam,
Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela.
(d) Middle East and Europe
Cyprus, Egypt, Hungary, Jordan, Malta, Oman, Poland, Syria, Turkey,
Yemen, and Yugoslavia.
2. Data Definitions and Sources
y : real GDP per capita in (1985 international prices).
n : population growth.
I : ratio of total fixed investment to GDP.
Ig : ratio of public sector fixed investment to GDP (public sector
includes general government, nonfinancial state enterprises, and
principal autonomous agencies).
Ip : ratio of private sector fixed investment to GDP.
[H.sup.P] : gross enrolment ratio at primary level.
[H.sup.s] : gross enrolment ratio at secondary level.
FDI : ratio of foreign direct investment to GDP.
T : trade orientation defined as the ratio of the average of
exports and imports to GDP.
D : ratio of the stock of external debt to GDP.
GBG : public sector balances as a percent of GDP.
For Tables 2 and 3, all ratios and growth rates are averages for
the period 1970-80, 1980-90, and 1970-90; [H.sup.P] and [H.sup.s] are
for the beginning of each period. In Table 5, the ratios are averages
for 3 and 5 years, and [H.sup.P] and [H.sup.s] are again for the
beginning of each period.
Data on y were obtained largely from Summers and Heston (1988) and
(1991) for the period up to 1985 and were extended to 1990 using per
capita growth rates from the IMF's World Economic Outlook (WEO)
database; for some low-income countries data were obtained from Ahmad
(1992). Data on n, FDI, and T were from the WEO database. Data on I, Ig,
Ip, [K.sub.g] and [K.sub.p] were obtained from the World Bank's
"DEC Analytical Database," supplemented by data from the
International Finance Corporation database on private investment and
from the WEO database. Data for [H.sup.P] and [H.sup.s] for the period
up to 1980 are from the UNESCO publication "Trends and Projections
of Enrolment by Level of Education and by Age" (March 1983), and
from UNESCO Statistical Yearbooks thereafter.
Estimates of public and private capital stock were obtained using
the perpetual inventory method, data on public and private gross
investment, and estimates of initial capital stocks in 1960. The
depreciation rate for the two types of capital stock was assumed to be
similar and varied
between 4 and 5 percent per annum.
Comments
This is an interesting paper in an area of vital importance to
policy-makers. The basic objective of the study is to ascertain the
relative importance of public and private investment in promoting and
sustaining growth in the developing countries. To what extent the study
has realised this objective, or the appropriateness of the selection of
the sample of countries, and the methodology used, is examined in the
following.
The paper points out that private investment tends to promote the
GDP more than public investment. However, this result alone can hardly
help in policy formulation especially because of the following results
reported in the study:
(i) The paper suggests quite rightly that public and private
investments are complementary. Seen in that context, would it not mean
that a reduction in public investment implies a fall in the
effectiveness of private sector investment as well?
(ii) The result that growth elasticity of public sector is
relatively smaller may indicate that either public sector is relatively
less efficient or that it has over-expanded. Interestingly enough, the
effectiveness of private and public sector was, the same in the earlier
period, indicating that public investment is not inherently inefficient.
(iii) The fall in the growth of elasticity of public investment in
the later periods has been ascribed by the author to relative abundance
of infrastructure in the latter period but no evidence of that has been
presented.
(iv) Has the public investment gone beyond the optimal level? The
paper hardly contains any discussion on that issue. Moreover, this can
only be done by disaggregating the public investment and looking at the
availability of infrastructure compared to requirement. No such analysis
has been done either.
(v) If public investment is less efficient, should the private
sector be inducted in infrastructure development? Would privatisation of
infrastructure result in lower or higher level of industrial growth
because private motive on the part of private sector may result in
higher cost of infrastructures?
Table 2 shows rather interesting results. The growth elasticity
with respect to investment is significantly higher in the earlier
period, i.e., 1970-90, than in either of the two sub-periods. Such a
result is not expected and one wonders if it is the result of some
specification error or some other error. It needs to be looked into.
The elasticity of both public and private investment is very
similar during 1970-80 period, but in the 1980-90 period the elasticity
with respect to public investment falls. Dr Khan has explained this by
referring to inadequacy of infrastructure in 1970-80 which supposedly
was quite adequate in the 1980-90 period. This needs verification
especially because public investment fell in the latter period and in
some cases net investment may have even turned negative. Pakistan
probably provides a clear example of that.
The methodology employed in the paper to determine the impact of
private and public investment on the growth consists of a regression of
growth in a country against the private and public investment. The
problems associated with such a cross-country analysis are quite
well-known.
The analysis assumes that depreciation of the capital stock in
private and public sectors is the same. Such an assumption is not
tenable because public sector investments being in infrastructures have
a longer life. What impact it will have on the analysis needs to be
looked into.
With a view to examining the impact of technical change arising
from the openness of the economy, the deviation from 2 percent technical
change has been used as an explanatory variable. Why the variable had to
be defined in such a way is not very clear.
On page 12 [of the original conference paper] the author suggests
restrictions on the original specification that the magnitude of the
coefficient of technical change would be equal to sum of the coefficient
of public and private investment. This specification may be causing
problems and an equation free from such restrictions may be tried.
How was the sample of the countries chosen? Was it purposive? Why
were just 14 countries from Asia chosen against the 46 from Africa? Does
it not bias the results? If the sample from Asia is enhanced, what would
be the impact on the result? This needs to be examined.
Although an interesting study, it does not succeed much in
realising the objective which it had laid out for itself. It also fails
to take note of the studies already done on Pakistan on this subject.
While earlier studies in Pakistan do show that the private and public
sector investments are complementary, they have not examined their
contribution to growth. Accordingly, disaggregated analysis is required
across the countries, and similar analysis may be done for each of the
countries.
A. R. Kemal
Planning and Development Division, Islamabad.
Author's Note: The views expressed in this paper are the sole
responsibility of the author and do not necessarily reflect the opinions
of the International Monetary Fund. I am grateful to Nadeem Haque, A. R.
Kemal, Ashfaque Hasan Khan, and Manmohan Kumar for helpful comments.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Sultan (1992) Regression Estimates of Per Capita GDP Based
on Purchasing Power Parities. International Economics Department, World
Bank, April. (Unpublished.)
Aschauer, David A. (1989) Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private
Capital. Journal of Monetary Economics September.
Aschauer, David A. (1989a) Public Investment and Productivity
Growth in the Group of Seven. Economic Perspectives: A Review from the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago September/October.
Barro, Robert J. (1991) Economic Growth in a Cross-section of
Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics May.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1992) Convergence.
Journal of Political Economy April.
Blejer, Mario I., and Mohsin S. Khan (1984) Government Policy and
Private Investment in Developing Countries. IMF Staff Papers June.
Cheng, Hsiao (1986) Analysis of Panel Dam Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.)
Coutinho Rui, and Giampiero Gallo (1991) Do Public and Private
Investment Stand in Each Other's Way. 1991 WDR Background Paper,
World Bank, October.
Edwards, Sebastian (1992) Trade Orientation, Distortions and Growth
in Developing Countries. Journal of Development Economics 39.
Fischer, Stanley (1993) The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in
Growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 32.
Ford, Robert, and P. Poret (1991) Infrastructure and Private-sector
Productivity. OECD Economic Studies 17: Autumn.
Frenkel, Jacob A., and Mohsin S. Khan (1990) Adjustment Policies
and Economic Development. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
Proceedings of the ASSA Winter Meeting (August).
Grossman, A., and E. Helpman (1990) Trade, Knowledge Spillovers and
Growth. (NBER Working Paper No. 3485.) October.
International Monetary Fund (1993) Convergence and Divergence in
Developing Countries. Chapter IV in Worm Economic Outlook May.
Khan, Mohsin S., and Carmen M. Reinhart (1990) Private Investment
and Economic Growth in Developing Countries. Worm Development January.
Khan, Mohsin S., and Manmohan S. Kumar (1997) Public and Private
Investment and the Convergence of Per Capita Incomes in Developing
Countries. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics February.
Kumar, Manmohan S. (1992) Fiscal Adjustment in Developing
Countries. Annex V Worm Economic Outlook May.
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt (1992) A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-country Growth Regressions. American Economic Review September.
Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1988) On the Mechanics of Economic Development.
Journal of Monetary Economics 42.
Mankiw, N. A., D. Romer, and D.N. Weil (1992) A Contribution to the
Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics May.
Ossa, Gistian (1990) The Diversity of Growth Rates Among Developing
Countries. Development Policy Review 8.
Romer, Paul M. (1989) Capital Accumulation in the Theory of
Long-run Growth. In R. Barro (ed) Modern Business Cycle Theory.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Rubin, L. S. (1991) Productivity and the Public Capital Stock:
Another Look. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (Working
Paper No. 118.)
Solow, Robert (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics February.
Serven, L., and A. Solimano (1990) Private Investment and
Macroeconomic Adjustment: Theory, Country Experience, and Policy
Implications. Macroeconomic Adjustment and Growth Division, World Bank.
(Unpublished.)
Summers, Robert, and Alan W. Heston (1988) A New Set of
International Comparisons of Real Product and Price Levels: Estimates
for 130 Countries 1950-1985. Review of Income and Wealth March.
Summers, Robert, and Alan W. Heston (1991) The Penn World Tables
(Mark V): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-88.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 48.
(1) The diversity in performance among developing country regions
has become particularly evident during the 1980s; see, for instance,
Ossa (1990) and Kumar (1992).
(2) Existing studies of convergence have combined developing and
industrial countries, and thus their results are applicable to both
groups; see Barro (1991) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992).
(3) This is based on an unweighted average for the OECD countries
for the 1980s.
(4) See Blejer and Khan (1984). For industrial countries, Aschauer
(1989, 1989a) finds that investment in infrastructure has had a very
strong positive effect on private sector productivity. However, these
findings remain controversial largely because the marginal productivity
of infrastructure implied by his estimates is considered implausibly
high; see, for example, Ford and Poret (1991) and Rubin (1991).
(5) This equation can be derived readily from a Cobb-Douglas
production function. For details, see Khan and Kumar (1997).
(6) For a discussion of the importance of human capital in the
growth process, see Lucas (1988); Barro (1991) and Levine and Renelt
(1992).
(7) For an analysis of the relationship between macroeconomic
stability and growth, see Frenkel and Khan (1990) and Fischer (1993).
(8) For the sample of developing countries and data definitions and
sources, see Appendix.
(9) Note that from the initial income variable, one can obtain the
rate of convergence among developing countries, which turns out to be
0.01. This implies that once the cross-country variation in investment
and population growth is taken into account, the poorer developing
countries (measured by their per capita income in 1970) narrowed the gap
between them and the richer developing countries at a rate of roughly 1
percent a year. For further details, see Khan and Kumar (1997) and
International Monetary Fund (1993).
(10) The average rate of consumer price inflation was also
considered as a proxy for macroeconomic instability. It had the correct
sign and was statistically significant when it was included by itself;
however, when it was included together with budgetary balances, it
became insignificant. Since the fiscal position and inflation are
generally closely related, particularly in developing countries, this
result is not altogether surprising.
(11) When the average is for three years, there are six
observations per country, giving a pooled sample for the 95 countries of
570 observations. With a five-year average, there are four observations
per country giving a sample of 380 observations.
(12) See Cheng (1986) for a discussion of the different procedures
that could be used to estimate the model.
Mohsin S. Khan is Deputy Director, Research Department,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C.
Table 1
Public and Private Investment in Developing Countries, 1970-90
(As Percent of GDP)
Total Public Private
Africa (46) 19.7 10.6 9.1
Asia (14) 20.5 8.6 11.9
Latin America (24) 19.3 7.9 11.4
Europe and
Middle East (11) 24.5 14.1 10.4
All Developing
Countries (95) 20.3 10.0 10.3
Data are unweighted averages. Number of countries is
given in brackets; for sample of countries, see Appendix.
Table 2
Determinants of Per Capita Growth: Single Equation Estimates (1)
(1) (2) (3)
Average Per Capita
Growth during 1970-90 1970-80 1980-90
Constant 3.06 (a) -1.55 (a) -1.61 (a)
(0.78) (0.52) (0.48)
Initial Per Capita GDP -0.18 (a) -0.04 -0.14 (a)
(0.06) (0.04) (0.03)
Implied Rate of 0.010 0.004 0.015
Convergence
Investment (Total) 0.75 (a) 0.44 (a) 0.35 (a)
(0.12) (0.09) (0.08)
Investment (Public)
Investment (Private)
Population and -0.90 (a) -0.30 -0.61 (a)
Technical Change (0.30) (0.19) (0.19)
Human Capital
Fiscal Balance
[R.sup.2] 0.33 0.24 0.27
S.E.E. (0.34) (0.25) (0.23)
(4) (5) (6) (7)
Average Per Capita
Growth during 1970-90 1970-80 1980-90 1970-90
Constant -2.76 (a) -1.23 (a) -1.45 (a) -1.72 (a)
(0.77) (0.51) (0.47) (0.83)
Initial Per Capita GDP -0.20 (a) -0.03 -0.15 (a) -0.23 (a)
(0.06) (0.05) (0.04) (0.06)
Implied Rate of 0.011 0.003 0.016 0.012
Convergence
Investment (Total)
Investment (Public) 0.28 (a) 0.21 (a) 0.13 (a) 0.29 (a)
(0.08) (0.06) (0.05) (0.98)
Investment (Private) 0.43 (a) 0.21 (a) 0.21 (a) 0.40 (a)
(0.07) (0.05) (0.05) (0.07)
Population and -1.08 (a) -0.29 -0.70 (a) -0.79 (a)
Technical Change (0.31) (0.19) (0.19) (0.32)
Human Capital 0.02 (a)
(0.01)
Fiscal Balance 0.03 (a)
(0.01)
[R.sup.2] 0.34 0.23 0.28 0.44
S.E.E. (0.34) (0.25) (0.23) (0.29)
(1) For detailed description of the data see the Appendix. Standard
errors in brackets; (a) denotes statistically significant at the 5
percent level.
Table 3
Regional Variation in the Impact of Investment on Growth (1)
(1) (2) (3)
1970-1990 1970-1980 1980-1990
Constant -1.51 (a) -0.49 -0.88
(0.77) (0.53) (0.50)
Initial Per Capita GDP -0.24 (a) -0.12 (a) -0.17 (a)
(0.07) (0.06) (0.04)
Implied Rate of Convergence 0.014 0.012 0.019
Population and Technical Change -0.72 (a) -0.21 -0.53 (a)
(0.29) (0.19) (0.19)
Human Capital Enrolment Ratio 0.32 (a)
(Secondary) (0.15)
Average Years of Schooling 0.016 (b) 0.02 (a)
(Secondary) (0.009) (0.01)
Fiscal Balance 0.007 (a) 0.02 (a) 0.03 (a)
(0.004) (0.01) (0.01)
Investment Ratio Dummies Public Private Public
Africa 0.32 (a) 0.32 (a) 0.23 (a)
(0.10) (0.08) (0.07)
Asia 0.26 (a) 0.51 (a) 0.14 (a)
(0.14) (0.12) (0.11)
Latin America 0.01 0.65 0.12
(0.11) (0.11) (0.09)
Middle East 0.37 (a) 0.48 (a) 0.27 (a)
(0.11) (0.12) (0.09)
[R.sup.2] 0.55 0.41
S.E.E. (0.30) (0.24)
Investment Ratio Dummies Private Public Private
Africa 0.18 (a) 0.14 (a) 0.16 (a)
(0.06) (0.07) (0.06)
Asia 0.31 (a) 0.12 (a) 0.27 (a)
(0.10) (0.10) (0.09)
Latin America 0.35 0.02 0.28
(0.09) (0.07) (0.07)
Middle East 0.29 (a) 0.19 (a) 0.19 (a)
(0.09) (0.08) (0.09)
[R.sup.2] 0.46
S.E.E. (0.22)
(1) For detailed description of data see the Appendix. Standard
errors are in brackets; (a) and (b) denote statistically significant at
the 5 and 10 percent levels, respectively. For the human capital
variable, various measures identified earlier were included in the
initial estimation. However, only the ones which were significant
were included in the final estimates reported here.
Table 4
Public and Private Investment: TSLS and Panel Data Results (1)
Two-stage
Least Squares
(1) (2)
Constant -9.08 (a) -8.01 (a)
(2.62) (0.61)
Initial Per Capita GDP -0.13 -0.16
(0.13) (0.12)
Population and -3.21 (a) -2.10 (a)
Technical Change (0.89) (0.10)
Human Capital (2) 0.02
(0.01)
Trade Orientation 0.32
(0.36)
Foreign Direct Investment 0.03
(0.05)
Private Investment 0.57 (a) 0.54
(0.28) (0.18)
Public Investment 0.36
Dummies (0.13)
Africa 0.19 (b)
(0.12)
Asia 0.13
(0.20)
Latin America 0.08
(0.14)
Middle East 0.12
(0.19)
[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.37
S.E.E. (0.27) (0.33)
Panel Data
3 Years 5 Years
(3) (4)
Constant -0.38 -0.53 (a)
(0.14) (0.20)
Initial Per Capita GDP -0.003 -0.001
(0.01) (0.10)
Population and -0.11 (a) -0.15 (a)
Technical Change (0.04) (0.07)
Human Capital (2) 0.003 0.001
(0.01) (0.01)
Trade Orientation 0.02
(0.04)
Foreign Direct Investment 0.01
(0.02)
Private Investment 0.05 (a) 0.06 (a)
(0.01) (0.01)
Public Investment
Dummies
Africa 0.02 (a) 0.02 (b)
(0.01) (0.01)
Asia 0.05 (a) 0.06 (a)
(0.01) (0.02)
Latin America 0.01 0.01
(0.01) (0.01)
Middle East 0.04 (a) 0.04 (a)
(0.01) (0.01)
[R.sup.2] 0.12 0.12
S.E.E. (0.13) (0.16)
(1) The Panel data results, in Columns 3 and 4 use data averaged
over 3 years (6 observations per country) and 5 years (4
observations per country). (a) and (b) denote statistically significant
at the 5 and 10 percent level.
(2) Secondary school enrolment ratio.
Table 5
Public and Private Investment and Speed of Convergence (1)
(1) (2) (3)
Constant -2.59 (a) -3.34 (a) -2.31 (a)
(0.89) (0.84) (0.85)
Initial Per Capita GDP -0.23 (a) -0.18 (a) -0.31 (a)
(0.07) (0.07) (0.07)
Investment Ratio (Total) 0.76 (a) 1.01 (a) 0.61 (a)
(0.12) (0.16) (0.14)
Initial GDP and Public Investment -0.03 (a)
(0.01)
Initial GDP and Private Investment 0.03 (a)
(0.01)
Population and Technical Change -0.79 (a) -0.89 (a) -0.92 (a)
(0.32) (0.31) (0.32)
Human Capital 0.18 (b) 0.17 (b) 0.18
(0.10) (0.09) (0.11)
Implied Rate of Convergence 0.013 0.010 0.017
[R.sup.2] 0.35 0.39 0.39
S.E.E. (0.33) (0.41) (0.41)
(1) The dependent variable is per capita GDP growth
during 1970-90. For other notes, see Table 2.