Integrated social-sector macroeconometric model for Pakistan.
Pasha, Hafiz A. ; Hasan, M. Aynul ; Ghaus, Aisha 等
1. INTRODUCTION
While the traditional neoclassical production model postulates that
it is the physical inputs such as private capital, labour, land, and
technology that are the key determinants of output and economic
development, in recent years, however, the social sector variables are
also considered to be critical, particularly for the long-run
sustainable growth of the economy. If fact, what has been argued in the
form of "new growth theories" is that social variables (e.g.,
education, health, knowledge, etc.) generate "positive
externalities" and, thus, may facilitate and foster the process of
economic growth and development.
Recently, the World Bank, based on a broad cross-country study,
found some very interesting results in the above context. According to the World Development Report (1991): about fifty percent of the factor
productivity contribution to output growth comes not from traditional
physical inputs (capital, labour and land) but is a residual factor.
This unexplained factor, in the past, has been labelled (or as the
Report called it "baptised") as "technological
change", however, the World Bank (1991, p. 42) claims that:
Technological innovations have no doubt generated some improvement
in total factor productivity. But the main additional element is in
the quality of labour.
Of course, the quality of labour will come about due to education,
skills, and the status of health that the society provides for the
workforce.
Pakistan has traditionally given a relatively low priority to the
social sectors as reflected in poor human development indicators of the
country. However, Pakistan has recorded a respectable economic growth
rate of 6 percent per annum during the decade of the eighties.
Apparently, low levels of literacy and poor health standards have not
acted as a constraint to growth in the past. In fact, the view has
sometimes been put forth that because Pakistan placed higher priority on
public investment in economic and physical infrastructure as opposed to
lager development outlays in the social sectors (see Table 1), it was
able to accelerate its growth rate. Lately, it has been argued that
while this was a successful development strategy in the short run, it
was bound to fail eventually because of lack of human capital to sustain
the process of future economic growth, especially in a changed
international environment with greater competition for export among
developing countries.
Undoubtedly, it is essential to develop a deeper understanding of
the operation of the economy of a developing country like Pakistan and
to analyse, in a long-term macroeconomic setting, the consequences of
public investments in different sectors. In this context, in recent
years, Pakistan has launched a major initiative with international donor
agency support called the Social Action Programme (SAP). The SAP
represents a big push forward of public expenditure in the social
sectors with some diversion of resources from traditional areas of
priority. In the aftermath of the launching of the SAP, concerns have
been voiced by the provincial governments in Pakistan, who are primarily
responsible for the delivery of basic social services such as education,
health, water supply and sanitation, etc., about the financial
sustainability of this programme. These governments have rapidly
realised that, while accelerated development funding could potentially
become available through SAP, there is no obvious source of revenue for
financing the downstream operations and maintenance expenditures of the
facilities created, especially since some of the social sectors like
education and health are highly recurring expenditure intensive. The
lack of recurrent funding could, therefore, adversely affect the fiscal
position of provincial governments and require either larger
inter-governmental revenue transfers or higher resource mobilisation. It
is crucial to project the implications of this programme not only on the
process of social development but also on the overall long-term rate of
future economic growth, especially in a changed international
environment with greater competition for export among developing
countries.
The need has been felt in Pakistan for developing a macroeconomic
model incorporating explicitly the impact of public expenditures (both
social and economic), which are in excess of 30 percent of the GDP.
Given the resource constraints being faced by all levels of government
and the growing pressures to achieve greater macroeconomic stability by
cutting down the national budget deficit, it has become necessary to
evaluate the inter-sectoral priorities of public investment from the
viewpoint of the maximum impact on the long-term growth potential of the
country.
In view of the emerging social development issues and need for
changing public expenditure priorities, this paper describes the
integrated planning macroeconometric model for Pakistan's economy
that has been developed by the Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC). The model clearly establishes linkages among the macroeconomy,
public finances and the social sectors. It addresses a number of major
policy issues including the relative impact of public investments
(economic versus social infrastructure) on economic growth, the
financial sustainability of the SAP, implications of privatisation of
the public ventures and decentralisation of the process of delivery of
services, etc.
Currently, the only major macroeconomic modelling initiative
undertaken in Pakistan is by the Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics (PIDE). The first attempt was made in 1979 and a completed
document was produced in 1982. The model was relatively small initially
with 53 equations. In the latest vintage of the model see Naqvi et al.
(1993), the size has increased to 97 equations. The model now includes
detailed modules for sectors related to production, expenditure, labour
market, international trade, etc. However, the model does not have a
developed public finance module and does not get into the issue of
public expenditure allocations to different sectors, including the
social sectors. A relatively small 33 equations model has also been
developed by the AERC (1993). Although this model is rich on the public
finance side, including fiscal linkages between federal and provincial
governments, there is only a limited treatment of the macroeconomy.
The paper is organised as follows: Section 2 gives the overall
structure of the model and delineates the linkages of various modules,
blocks and equations. It also describes the special features of the
model including mechanisms for financing of social sectors and
endogenisation of factor productivity by development of a human capital
index which enters explicitly into production functions of the economic
sectors. Section 3 presents the findings of one of the important and
interesting policy simulations. Finally, Section 4 gives the
conclusions.
2. STRUCTURE AND LINKAGES OF THE MODEL
The model used in this study consists of 244 equations and covers
several aspects of the economy. (1) One of the unique features of the
model is that, for the first time in Pakistan, it provides a planning
tool wherein the social, public finance and macroeconomic dimensions of
the economy have been integrated under one system. The model is dynamic,
rich in specification and based on a pragmatic approach. Due to its
highly disaggregated character, covering all three levels of government
(federal, provincial and local), the model is capable of predicting
variables in greater detail even at the level of provision of individual
social services. It should be noted that such a disaggregation of the
model at the provincial level, in terms of revenue and expenditures on
social services (e.g., schools, hospitals, doctors, teachers, enrolment,
etc.) is, in fact, necessary particularly in order to analyse the impact
of SAP on the macroeconomy. The broad links of the model can be traced
as follows (see Figure 1):
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Macroeconomy [right arrow] Public Finance
The key link here is that developments in the macroeconomy
influence the growth of tax bases of taxes (including divisible pool
taxes) and thereby affect the fiscal status of different governments.
Also, the overall rate of inflation in the economy affects the growth of
public expenditure.
Public Finance [right arrow] Social Sector Development
The availability of resources, both external and internal,
determines the level of development and recurring outlays to social
sectors by different levels of government, especially the provincial and
local governments.
Social Sector Development [right arrow] Macroeconomy
Higher output of educated workers and their entry into the labour
force raises the human capital stock and could contribute to
improvements in productivity and higher growth rate of output in the
economy.. Similarly, an improvement in public health standards may also
have a favourable impact on production.
Public Finance [right arrow] Macroeconomy
The level of government expenditure could exert a demand side
effect on national income while the size of the overall budget deficit
of the federal and provincial governments combined influences the rate
of monetary expansion and consequently the rate of inflation in the
economy.
Social Sector Development [right arrow] Public Finance
A vital link in the model is between the rate of social sector
development and the state of public finances, especially of provincial
governments, in terms of implications on the level of debt servicing and
recurring expenditures.
Macroeconomy [right arrow] Social Sector Development
Demographic and other socio-economic changes impact the demand for
social sector facilities like schools, hospitals, etc., and thereby
influence the level of social sector outputs.
2.1. Intra-module Linkages
Apart from these broad linkages among different modules, links
exist between different blocks within each module too. In all, there are
39 major linkages in the model. Seven of these linkages are within the
macro module, fifteen within the fiscal module and two within the social
sector module. Major linkages within the macro module consist of, for
example, the two-way linkage to and from the marco production block and
macro input blocks. This link is due to the dependence of sectoral
value-added on the factors of production and input demand functions on
the value of production. Similarly, two-way linkages between the macro
production and macro expenditure blocks arise due to the partial
dependence of value-added in the services sectors on public expenditure
and the causality between income and private consumption. Link between
macro production block and trade block is due to the fact that value of
imports and exports depend on the level of economic production activity.
Important linkages in the fiscal module consist of the simultaneous
dependence of revenues of various levels of government and their
expenditures. Non-tax receipts of governments have been made a function
of the recurring expenditure on particular services via cost recovery
ratios. Similarly, the level of government expenditure is affected by
that government's level of resource generation. Important vertical
links between levels of government include the fiscal transfers in the
form of divisible pool transfers, non-development grants and ADP loans
from federal to provincial governments and development grant
requirements (in line with the feasible level of decentralisation) from
provincial to local governments.
2.2. Endogeneity and Factor Productivity of Public Investment
One of the key features of this model is the inclusion of public
sector investments in the form of social (human capital and public
health indices) and economic infrastructure in the value-added
production function. It has been argued that, along with private factor
inputs (labour and capital), public sector investments may also
contribute to the output of the economy. Unlike the private inputs which
directly influence the production, the role of public investments is in
the form of creating positive externalities and favourable environment
(e.g., educated and healthy workers, roads, electricity, etc.). The
model has the ability to estimate the direct and relative factor
productivities of public social vis-a-vis economic infrastructure
investments on the output of the economy.
The two types of public capital (social and economic) included in
the model are endogenised under separate modules for human capital,
public sector health and economic infrastructure. Within the human
capital and public sector health modules, there exists a link between
the level of social sector expenditures and the human capital and public
health indices which, in turn, is expected to influence the productivity
of the economy through the output production function. On the other
hand, acting as a base for the public revenues, the output of the
economy may also indirectly impact on the social variables through
social sector expenditures.
2.3. Financing of Public Social-sector Investments
In Pakistan, the process of financing and execution of social
services is quite complex with involvement of all three levels of
governments (i.e., federal, provincial and local). While the principal
responsibility of operation and maintenance (O&M) of social services
rests with the provincial (state) and local governments, the role of the
federal government is limited to the provision of social services in
federally administered areas. Consequently, over 80 percent of the total
expenditure on social sectors is incurred by the provincial and local
governments, the share of the former being about 65 percent.
The existence of structural imbalance between the functional
responsibilities and fiscal powers at different levels of government has
necessitated the establishment of elaborate inter-governmental
revenue-sharing arrangements particularly between the federal and the
four provincial governments in Pakistan. Provincial governments finance
their expenditures from various tax and non-tax sources
(constitutionally under their fiscal powers), federal revenue sharing transfers (which includes divisible pool and straight transfers), grants
and development transfers (including donor funds) received from the
federal government. In 1994-95, for example, 15 percent of the
provincial recurring expenditures was financed by own sources (8 percent
taxes and 7 percent user charges), 75 percent from revenue sharing
transfers, 11 percent from grants from federal government while almost
all of the provincial development outlays were financed from federal
development transfers, largely consisting of loans and donor funds.
Clearly, the bulk of provincial income comes from the federal government
and is outside the direct control of the provincial governments. As
such, modelling of inter-governmental fiscal transfers is a crucial
feature of the model.
Unlike the provincial governments, local governments are largely
self-financing entities in Pakistan. They mostly rely on own tax and
non-tax revenues to finance their ongoing operation and maintenance
costs and the development of new schemes. Almost 55 percent of the total
(recurring and development) expenditure of local government is financed
by own tax collection, 18 percent by user charges, 6 percent by revenue
sharing transfers from the provincial governments and 8 percent by
grants.
3. POLICY SIMULATIONS
In order to demonstrate the usefulness of the integrated planning
model, as an example, we present results of an interesting policy
simulation, namely, change in investment priorities from economic to
social sector investments. In order to keep the discussion as simple and
intuitive as possible, only the important linkages and impact of a
policy initiative on the GDP will be presented with the help of a
diagram.
3.1. Change in Investment Priority
We examine whether shifting funds from public economic
infrastructure investment towards social sector development produces any
positive impact on the macroeconomy, especially in the long run (up to
2002-03). A change in the priority of public investment from economic to
social sectors will simply require a reallocation of resources within
the existing total annual development programme (ADP) which includes
total capital outlays of both the federal and provincial governments.
Since the federal government is primarily responsible for providing
economic infrastructure and since the bulk of the social investment is
provided by the provincial governments, direct transfer of resources
from the former to the latter governments must take place in such a way
so that the total ADP remains unchanged. After the implementation of
this policy, less federal public funds will be available for new
economic infrastructure investment and hence a direct negative impact on
the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is expected.
With more funds now diverted from federal ADP to provincial
governments, specifically earmarked for the social sectors, it will now
enable the provincial governments to undertake an expanded development
programme, particularly in the areas of education, health and other
social sectors (sanitation, clean water, etc.). This type of programme,
of course, is expected to have some immediate positive impact on the
actual provision of social services and, subsequently, after a time lag,
through the human capital and public health indices, it may also
influence the GDP of the economy.
The critical interesting issue that needs to be examined, in this
context, is whether the postulated positive and negative linkages of the
above policy hold true and, if so, what is the duration of the lag. This
is essentially an empirical issue and Figure 2 reports the results of
such a policy on GDP. Clearly, the stipulated linkage is visible as
shown by a dark U shaped curve marked B in Figure 2. This curve simply
represents changes in the GDP from the "baseline" due to the
implementation of the policy. It is important to note that, as a result
of changes in investment priority from the economic to the social
sectors, initially, there is a deterioration in the GDP for about eight
years (up to 2001) after which the changes in GDP become positive.
What is even more interesting and important to note is that, while
the time lag required for GDP to become positive is independent of the
size of the policy changes, the long-run revival of the GDP, however, is
not independent of the initial strength of the policy. In simple words,
what this means is that if the government undertakes a less than
enthusiastic policy of diverting resources from the economic to the
social sector, a long-run positive gain will be made but in small
proportions as shown by curve W in Figure 2. On the other hand, if the
government pursued a more aggressive policy (four times that of the
baseline), in the short to medium run, there will be a sizeable
deterioration initially in the GDP. However, during this period, such
policies will result in improved human capital and public health
endowment of the nation. Consequently, with the enriched social
endowments (educated and healthy workers), once the society crosses the
critical time path of about eight years, the upturn in the GDP will be
significant and long lasting as shown by curve A in Figure 2.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Intuitively, the implications of the above policy are as follows.
Investment in the social sectors have a long gestation period, much
longer than that of investments in economic sectors. No matter what
amount of public investment is made, small or large, for the social
sectors, the realisation of the returns unlike the economic investments
(in the form of robots or machines), will take its own time. An
aggressive policy, however, in this context, (as pursued by countries
like Singapore, South Korea, Malaysia, Taiwan, and others in the region)
may also take the same time but the impact of such concerted and well
designed policies will be much greater and long lasting. In social
sector investment, policy-makers ought to take a long-run, well-thought
visionary approach as the money spent on this sector does not
automatically guarantee future prosperity but without such investments
in human capital, no nation, in recent period, has ever been able to
achieve the status of even a middle income country.
4. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This study represents a first attempt at developing a relatively
large (244 equations) planning macroeconometric model for Pakistan that
integrates the social, public finance and macroeconomic dimensions of
the economy. The model is dynamic, behaviourally rich in specification,
based on a pragmatic approach and incorporates a large number of
inter-module and inter-block linkages. Special features of the model
include the detailed modelling of the process of financing of social
sectors with special emphasis on inter-governmental transfers and
explicit incorporation of the impact of economic and social
infrastructure on the productive sectors, with the latter being captured
by changes in factor productivity measured by human capital and public
health indices, especially developed as part of the model.
Despite the shortness of the time series and softness of some of
the data, the application of a number of formal and informal econometric tests to check for goodness-of-fit, serial correlation,
heteroskedasticity and specification reveal that the model performs
fairly well. The use of a number of dummy variables is justified on the
grounds of random shocks and structural shifts. The validation exercise
.also highlights the high ex post forecasting power of the model.
A number of important policy simulations of the model have been
undertaken which lead to some key insights. For example, a change in
public investment priority from economic towards social infrastructure
depresses the GDP in the short run but pays dividends in terms of a
higher national income after a lag of about eight years. Similarly,
launching of accelerated development programmes in the social sectors
like the SAP have significant GDP impacts but could exacerbat the
problem of the national budget deficit. Altogether, the model has
considerable flexibility and can be used to answer a number of important
policy questions.
Appendix
Data Sources and Definition of Selected Variables
The availability of official statistics in Pakistan is largely the
result of efforts by the Federal and Provincial Bureaus of Statistics in
consolidating information from line and staff departments and publishing
these, to the extent possible, in the Pakistan Statistical Year Book at
the Federal level and the provincial Development Statistics by each of
the federating units. A closer examination of the statistics published
by the primary agencies and the consolidated figures suggests that there
are inconsistencies in the data which result in a number of statistics
being suspect. In addition, data on macroeconomic, financial, money and
fiscal variables are also published by the Ministry of Finance (the
annual Budget, the Pakistan Economic Survey), the provincial Finance
Departments (the annual Budgets) and the State Bank of Pakistan (the
Annual Report). Where inconsistencies between primary agency data and
consolidated data have been observed for some of the years, we have
adopted a general rule that a value which is closer to the trend
revealed by the consolidated data has been assumed to be more reflective
of actual conditions.
Public-sector Health Index
Information on the health status of the population is best measured
through morbidity rates and the incidence (or lack of it) of
communicable diseases. In addition some studies have also used infant
mortality, child-birth deaths, rates of immunisation and such other
indicators as a means to studying the health status of a population. In
the absence of such sophisticated data, an alternative had to be
developed. We have attempted to do this through the Public Health Index
(PHI) which suggests that the inputs into looking after the health of
people or providing health care services are reflective of the health
status of the population. We have constructed the PHI through a factor
analysis technique. The technique draws upon the inter-relationship of a
group of highly correlated variables to band them into one variable and
the cross-relationship this group has with other homogenous vectors of
variables. Each vector of variables (factors) are then considered to be
one homogenous whole and the cross-relationships used to develop a
factor scores (based on coefficients and eigen values) which explain the
impact of each factor on the dependant variable.
The data used to construct the Public Health Index aggregates the
provincial data on Basic Health Units (BHUs), Rural Health Centres
(RHCs), Sub-Health Centres (SHCs), Mother and Child Health Centres
(MCHs), TB centres, Doctors, and Nurses over the period 1971-72 to
1992-93. The factor scores for the country as a whole for each year have
then been used to develop the index with the initial year 1971-72 as the
base.
Human Capital Index
The Human Capital Index (HCI) is used to capture the quality aspect
of labour based on their level of education and professional skills.
Data for the development of this index by economic sectors, namely,
agriculture, manufacturing and others, requires information on the
labour force composition with respect to their skill and education. The
data source is the annual Labour Force Survey undertaken by the
provincial Labour Departments and compiled by the Federal Bureau of
Statistics.
In addition to this, data on relative wages is needed for assigning
weights to individual segments to capture the qualitative human
attributes. This is based on the premise that in a free competitive
market wage rates at the margin must be equal to the value of marginal
productivity of a worker. Presumably, the productivity of labour is a
direct reflection of worker education and skill levels.
Information on wages is obtained from the annual Household Income
and Expenditure Surveys conducted by the Federal Bureau of Statistics.
To offset the inflationary effect, the implicit GDP deflator has been
used to estimate wages at the constant price of 1991-92. The data on GDP
deflator has been compiled from the annual Pakistan Economic Survey
published by the Ministry of Finance and Economic Affairs.
The HCI has been constructed using the wage rate and number of
employed persons. The labour force and wage rate are divided into eight
separate categories with respect to professional skill, namely:
(a) professional and technical;
(b) administrative and managerial;
(c) clerical;
(d) sales worker;
(e) service worker;
(f) agricultural worker;
(g) production worker; and
(h) other occupation.
The formula for constructing the human capital index for the
'Kth' sector at period 't' can be written as:
[HCI.sub.kt] = ([[summation].sup.8.sub.i][L.sub.k,i,t]([W.sub.ki]/[W.sub.k,ag])) / [L.sub.k]
Where
i = professional occupation;
t = time (I to n); and
k = sectors.
Authors' Note: The authors wish to thank Peter Pauly and
Ashfaque Khan for valuable comments on an earlier version of the paper.
Excellent research support was provided by Nadeem Ahmed and Nazia Bano.
This study is funded by the Canadian International Development Agency (CIDA) and the authors wish to thanks the agency for providing financial
support. Errors are sole responsibility of the authors.
REFERENCES
AERC (1993) A Model of Public Finance in Pakistan. Karachi: Applied
Economic Research Centre, University of Karachi.
Naqvi, S. N. H., A. Khan and A. Ahmed (1993) The Macro-economic
Framework for the Eighth Five-year Plan. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute
of Development Economics.
Pasha, H., M. A. Hasan, A. Ghaus and A. Rasheed (1995) Integrated
Social Policy and Macroeconomic Planning Model for Pakistan. Karachi:
SPDC Publications,
World Bank (1991) World Development Report 1991. New York: Oxford
University Press.
(1) For a detailed discussion on the specification of the
behavioural model, estimated regression equations, other statistical
results, policy simulations etc., the reader may refer to Pasha et al.
(1995).
Hafiz A. Pasha is Deputy Chairman of the Planning Commission,
Government of Pakistan, Islamabad. M. Aynul Hasan is at the Department
of Economics, Acadia University, Canada. Aisha Ghaus is at the Social
Policy and Development Centre, Karachi. M. Ajaz Rasheed is at the Social
Policy and Development Centre, Karachi.
Table 1
Ranking of Countries in Indicators of Development of Social and
Economic Infrastructure
Social Infrastructure
Primary Secondary Hospital
Country Enrolment Enrolment Beds Doctors
Nepal 10 10 10 9
Bangladesh 6 9 8 6
India 5 4 4 2
Nigeria 7 7 7 10
Pakistan 9 6 5 3
Sri Lanka 2 2 1 4
Egypt 4 1 2 1
Indonesia 1 3 6 5
Myanmar 3 8 9 7
Sudan 8 5 3 8
Social Infrastructure
Drinking Overall
Country Nurses Water Sanitation Ranking
Nepal 5 8 10 10
Bangladesh 10 2 8 8
India 6 4 7 3
Nigeria 7 7 4 9
Pakistan 9 6 5 6
Sri Lanka 4 5 2 2
Egypt 1 1 1 1
Indonesia 8 9 3 4
Myanmar 3 3 6 5
Sudan 2 10 9 7
Economic Infrastructure
Electricity
Country Generation Roads Telephones Railways
Nepal 10 8 7 10
Bangladesh 8 10 8 4
India 2 1 5 2
Nigeria 6 3 6 7
Pakistan 3 5 2 3
Sri Lanka 4 2 3 1
Egypt 1 4 1 6
Indonesia 5 7 4 8
Myanmar 7 6 9 5
Sudan 9 9 10 9
Economic Infrastructure
Per Capita
Overall Income
Country Irrigation Ranking Ranking
Nepal 5 9 10
Bangladesh 2 7 8
India 3 1 6
Nigeria 9 6 5
Pakistan 1 2 4
Sri Lanka 4 3 3
Egypt 7 4 2
Indonesia 6 5 1
Myanmar 8 8 7
Sudan 10 10 9