Is the social action programme in Pakistan financially sustainable?
Pasha, Hafiz A. ; Hasan, M. Aynul ; Ghaus, Aisha 等
1. INTRODUCTION
Earlier neoclassical, classical, or structuralist theories [due to
Rostow (1960)] considered economic growth to be a result of the right
quantity and combination of saving, investment, and foreign aid, with
surpluses from the primary commodity-producing sectors being channelled
into capital for further growth. Accordingly, the main constraint in
these growth models has been the relatively low level of capital
formation available. While the above paradigm has intuitive appeal, it,
however, ignores the complementarity of social-political influences on
the physical variables (i.e., capital, labour, etc.) in growth and
development. Urquidi (1971) argued that the social progress of a nation
is a necessary condition for sustained economic growth. It is now
increasingly evident that the investment in the social sectors--primary
education, basic health, housing, changes in land-tenure system, social
security, better social relations-are as, if not more, important than
the investment in the commodity-producing sectors or related
infrastructure. In this context, Lloyd-Ellis (1993) noted:
Perhaps the most influential proposition that has come out of the
postwar theories of economic growth is that the accumulation of
human capital, in the form of educational expansion or otherwise,
is a major determinant of overall GNP growth in both developed and
less developed countries...(and) this expansion has contributed to
aggregate economic growth anti, where such investment programmes
have been well-'designed and implemented, the growth encouraged by
them may well have offset any negative effect caused by increased
taxation or debt burden.
The growth experienced by countries like Singapore, Malaysia,
Indonesia; South Korea, Hongkong, and Taiwan is the result of investment
in the social sectors, particularly education and health, and is a
testament to this paradigm.. If Pakistan is to become another Asian
Tiger, it will have to educate and improve the health of its masses
without compromising expenditures on these social services. In recent
years, with the cooperation of donors, Pakistan has taken some positive
initiative in the form of the Social Action Programme (SAP), whereby it
has committed to improve the social conditions of the masses. Under this
accelerated programme, federal as well as provincial governments have
earmarked some of their public expenditures for key social services,
namely, primary education (for girls), basic health (in rural areas),
clean water, Sanitation, and population planning.
Thus, in view of the above, the important public policy issues that
need to be. investigated are:
* If the existing social services are to be expanded and improved,
and if accelerated construction programmes for more schools, basic
health units (BHUs), and other social infrastructure are to be
undertaken, what implications will this have on budget outlays?
* Given high budget deficits,, can the government, particularly
provincial governments, afford recurring expenditure liabilities (e.g.,
teachers, doctors, nurses, medication, books, etc.) on an ongoing basis
due to SAP?
* Are the present public institutions in the country capable of
handling such an accelerated expansion of facilities as proposed by SAP?
All these public policy questions are critical, in terms of the
long-run sustainability of the Social Action Programme. This study
attempts to address these specific issues based on an Integrated Social
Policy Macroeconomic Model developed elsewhere. In particular, as an
example, we investigate, the impact of SAP on the macro-economy in the
form of a three-year special annum development programme for the
provinces. We also explore alternative avenues to examine the
possibilities of making SAP sustainable in the long-run.
2. PAKISTAN'S STANDING IN TERMS OF SOCIAL INDICATORS
How is Pakistan's performance in social indicators in relation
to other neighbouring countries? Does Pakistan spend enough on her human
resource development? These questions are critical, as the "human
capital endowment" of a nation plays a pivotal role in the growth
and development of the country. More significantly, acting as a
complement with physical capital and natural resources, human capital
provides long-term sustainability in economic and social development.
This human capital development, in turn, demands a world where no human
being is denied of basic health care and, more importantly, no child is
deprived of elementary primary education.
Despite an impressive economic growth of over 6.5 percent per
annum, the performance in the social indicators of Pakistan has been
inadequate. In relation to eleven other comparable countries considered
in Table 1, Pakistan's population growth rate has been the highest
at 2.9 percent. The other most discouraging social indicator has been
the literacy rate, particularly for females, which stood at a meagre 22
percent in 1992. Although Pakistan's overall literacy rate has
increased from 21 percent to 36 percent in the last two decades, it is
still one of the lowest, next to Nepal as shown in Table 1. In fact, the
first-grade intake rate (77 percent) is also the lowest among the
countries considered for the analysis.
Contrary to this, countries like Nigeria and Bangladesh, with a
significantly lower per capita GNP than Pakistan, have a much higher
female and overall literacy rate and first-grade intake rates, as
reported in Table 1. This indicates that there are many countries with
low per capita income but higher human development indicators than
Pakistan.
Another rather serious educational problem of developing nations is
the very high percentage of students who drop-out before completing a
particular cycle. The drop-out problem is more serious mainly because of
poverty and ignorance. This situation is reflected in Table 1, which
ranks Pakistan as the second-lowest country among those whose students
complete primary level. There are actually more mouths to be fed
relative to the income-earners. Hence, as soon as the young ones are
Capable of fend for themselves, they are asked to earn, rather than
involve themselves in the so-called "unproductive work of
learning".
As the above analysis and data suggest, the importance of the
social sector has not been recognised in the past by the
policy-makers in Pakistan as a priority sector. It appears that
there has been a lot of rhetoric, and no concrete efforts have been
made to increase public spending in the social sector while, during
the same period, many countries in the region halve invested
heavily in health, education, training, and skill formation of its
people.
In summary, based on a cross-country comparison of various
indicators, it is clear that Pakistan's performance in the social
sector is less than adequate. Furthermore, Pakistan's spending on
this sector is also one of the lowest in the region. In the present
environment of high budget deficits, concerns have been voiced by the,
provincial governments about the sustainability of the recently
initiated Social Action Programme (SAP). By and large, provincial
governments in Pakistan are primarily responsible for the delivery of
basic social services (e.g., education, health, water supply,
sanitation, etc.). These governments rapidly realised that while
accelerated development funding could potentially become available
through SAP, there was no obvious source of revenue for financing the
downstream operation and maintenance expenditures of the facilities
created, especially since some of the social sectors like education and
health are highly recurring expenditure-intensive, The lack of recurring
funding could, therefore, adversely affect the fiscal position of
provincial governments and require either larger inter-governmental
revenue transfers or higher resource mobilisation.
In order to investigate these key public policy issues, it is
essential to develop a planning framework which clearly highlights the
future implications of expanded development outlays in the social
sectors on recurring expenditures. Furthermore, among other things, it
will also enable Us to quantify the implications of programmes like the
SAP for the budgetary position of provincial governments, and derive
thereby the need for additional resources with provincial governments.
3. SALIENT FEATURES OF THE MODEL
The model used in this study consists of about 200 equations and
covers several aspects of the economy. (1) One of the unique features of
the model is that for the first time in Pakistan, it has provided a
planning tool wherein the social, public finance, 'and
macro-economic dimensions of the economy have been integrated under one
system. The model is dynamic, rich in specification, and based on a
pragmatic approach. Because of its highly disaggregated character,
covering all three levels of government (federal, provincial, and
local), the model is capable of predicting variables in greater detail
even at the level of provision of individual social services. It should
be noted that such a disaggregation of the model at the provincial
level, in terms of revenue and expenditures onsocial services (e.g.,
schools, hospitals, doctors, teachers, enrolment, etc.), is in fact
necessary particularly in order to analyse the impact of SAP on the
macro-economy. The principal links of the model can be traced as
follows.
Macroeeonomy [right arrow] Public Finance [right arrow] Social
Sector Development
The key link here is that developments in the macro-economy
influence the growth of tax bases of taxes (including divisible pool
taxes) and thereby affect the fiscal status of different governments.
Also, the overall rate of inflation in the economy affects the growth of
public expenditure. The level of government expenditure could exert a
demand-side effect on national income while the size of the overall
budget deficit, of the federal and provincial governments combined,
influences the rate of monetary expansion and, consequently, the rate of
inflation in the economy. The availability of resources, both external
and internal, determines the level of development and recurring outlays
to social sectors by different levels of government, especially the
provincial and local governments.
Social Sector Development [right arrow] Macroeconomy [right arrow]
Public Finance
Higher output of educated workers and their entry into the labour
force raises the human capital stock and could contribute to
improvements in productivity and higher growth rate of output in the
economy. Similarly, an improvement in public health standards may also
have a favourable impact on production. A vital link in the model is
between the rate of social sector development and the state of public
finances, especially of provincial governments, in terms of the
implications on the level of debt servicing and recurring expenditures.
Demographic and other socioeconomic changes impact on the demand for
social sector facilities like schools, hospitals, etc., and thereby
influence the level of social sector outputs.
3.1. Provincial Governments' Role in the Model
Based on the above linkages, it is possible to get a more
comprehensive understanding of how provincial governments fit into the
national context both in terms of the major elements of the environment
that impact upon them. and in terms of how their actions in turn affect
the macro-economy (see FlowChart 1).
Provincial governments are affected by changes in the level of
output in the productive sectors of the economy, viz., agriculture,
manufacturing, and services. These changes influence the growth of tax
revenues directly and indirectly, via the impact on revenues from
federal divisible pool taxes like income tax, sales tax, and excise
duties. Since the bulk of the revenues of the provincial governments are
in the form of fiscal transfers from the federation, developments in the
national economy have a vital bearing on the budgetary position of
provincial governments. Similarly, developments on the monetary front
are of direct concern to provincial governments as they influence the
rate of inflation in unit costs and wage rates, while changes in
interest rates have consequences on debt servicing liabilities.
Provincial governments influence the macro-economy in a number of
ways. First, via their expenditure, which affects the level of national
income, and through investments in economic and social infrastructure,
which contribute to the rate of economic growth on a more long-term
basis. Second, their combined revenue surplus or deficit influences the
overall national budget deficit and the resulting monetary expansion and
inflation in the economy. Provincial governments also influence
behaviour of local governments via fiscal transfers and provision of
competing services.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
In particular, the model carefully depicts the pattern of
inter-governmental fiscal relations in the country (see Flow Chart 2).
It allows for various types of flows of funds from the federal
government to the provincial governments including divisible pool
transfers, special transfers (like hydro-electricity profits), grants
and cash development loans, and for the reverse flow--from the
provincial governments to the federal government--of debt servicing.
Similarly, flows of funds between provincial and local governments are
also modelled.
The basic conclusion is that projections of the future fiscal
status of provincial governments, collectively or individually, and
assessment of the fiscal consequences of the level and composition of
annual development programme can only be made in the context of a model
which captures all the above-mentioned links. The model developed by us
is a major step forward in achieving this objective.
4. POLICY SIMULATION RESULTS
In order to keep the discussion as simple and intuitive as
possible, in the subsequent sections, only the important linkages and
the impact of a given SAP-type policy initiative on key relevant
variables will be presented with the help of flow charts and tables
containing actual changes in the variables.
4.1. SAP with Development Expenditures
In this section, we investigate whether the SAP-type plan with only
development expenditures will be able to produce long term sustainable
results for the social sectors. This is critical as many of the special
development programmes such as SAP were initially designed with no
specific provisions for recurring expenditure liabilities. In other
words, schools or basic health centres were constructed without giving
due consideration to the ongoing needs for teachers, books, doctors,
nurses, medication, etc. As before, we first explain the transmission
mechanism using a flow chart, through which the above policy will
permeate the macro-economy, and subsequently analyse, the impact of such
a policy in terms of numerical figures. For pedagogical reasons and to
get a deeper insight, we assume a three-year SAP with one billion rupees
additional investment every year, of which fifty percent is borrowed
from the donor and the rest generated domestically by the federal
government.
Flow Chart 3 shows the schematic linkages of the above type of SAP
in the form of a special ADP, which, of course, comes from both external
and internal borrowing. These two types of borrowing each year will add
to the overall deficit of the economy. Since the implementation of SAP
is the responsibility of the provincial governments, federation will
transmit SAP development funds Via special provincial development
transfers. These funds, subsequently, based on some guidelines, will be
divided into three specific social programmes, namely primary schools,
BHUs and RHCs, and other social services (e.g., clean water, sanitation,
and population planning). Construction of this physical social
infrastructure is expected to have an impact on both human capital and
public health endowments of the society (through educated and healthy
labour force) and, thus, in due course, it is expected to have an impact
on the economy's broad macro-economic aggregate such as the GDP.
Higher GDP will subsequently enhance the tax bases, thus increasing the
revenues of the provincial governments. An improved revenue position of
the provincial governments may also "help improve the revenue
surplus/deficit of these governments. On the other hand, the development
transfers to the provinces will also have immediate implications for
provincial debt servicing liabilities, placing a negative effect on the
revenue surplus/deficit of these governments. Thus, the net effect on
the revenue surplus/deficit of the provincial governments will be
ambiguous. However, the overall deficit Of the economy will
unambiguously rise at least in the period when the federation is engaged
in borrowing to finance SAP.
[ILLUSTRATIONS OMITTED]
The numerical values of the impact of the above policy on key
variables are reported in Table 2. For convenience, we have provided
simulation results for the short-run (1994-95), long-run (2002-03), and
baseline period (1992-93). As expected, the social infrastructure
variables, namely, schools, hospital beds, and RHCs, have improved and
this is reflected in higher student participation rates, human capital,
and public health indices. It is, however, important to note that the
above type of SAP, having no provision for recurring expenditures (e.g.,
teachers, doctors, etc.), will eventually end up providing facilities of
a lower quality. This is manifested in the decline of ratios of teachers
to school, doctor to beds, and RHCs, as shown in Table 2.
As for the fiscal variables, provincial debt servicing liabilities
will increase up to rupees one-half billion and about Rs 200 million in
use of provincial cash balances by the year 2002-03. Recurring
liabilities have also increased but not commensurate with the initial
development expenditures. This is due to the fact that no funds have
been earmarked for recurring expenditure. It is also interesting to note
that, due to improved provision for human capital, the GDP has increased
by over one-and-half billion and this has also resulted in improved
gross revenue receipts by over half-a-billion by the year 2002-03. The
overall deficit position of the economy has deteriorated by about four
billion rupees.
In summary, then, a SAP policy, with only development expenditures,
is expected to elevate the provision of social physical infrastructure
(schools, beds, (RHCs) without having a corresponding increase in other
recurring-type inputs, namely, teachers; books, doctors, nurses,
medication, etc. Thus, as a result, initially the performance of the
social sector may improve; however, as soon as the development programme
ends after three years, the quality of provision of social services will
decline due to the lack of necessary recurring inputs. The long-term
consequences of such a programme may result in additional schools
without enough teachers and hospitals with inadequate supply of
medicines,-doctors, and nurses. Hence, though this type of SAP programme
may not impart a greater burden to the overall deficit of the economy,
such a programme will certainly not achieve the Stipulated long-run
objective of improving the social conditions of the masses.
4.2. SAP with, Development and Recurring Expenditures
If the SAP-type plan requires both development and earmarked
recurring expenditures to produce the intended long-run positive results
in the social sectors, then the question arises whether such a programme
will be sustainable from the budgetary point of view. In other words,
with ongoing recurring expenditures liabilities, can the provincial
governments be able to meet the additional expenses from the existing
pot, particularly when some of the provinces are already experiencing
deficits? In addition, what will happen to the provincial debt servicing
liabilities and the use of cash balances when the State Bank of Pakistan has already imposed a ceiling on such borrowing facilities. Using Flow
Chart 4 and Table 3, we examine the impact of the above policy
specifically on the issue of the sustainability of SAP.
Under the above type of policy, the SAP funds transferred by the
federation to the provincial governments will be divided into both
development and recurring outlays for the social sectors, as shown in
Flow Chart 4. Once the stipulated period (say three years) for SAP is
over, the ongoing future recurring expenditure liabilities will, become
the provincial governments responsibility. It should be noted, that
these additional SAP expenditures (both development and ongoing
recurring, outlays)are expected to boost, the provision of the social
services, resulting in improved human capital and, public health
indices, and thus a higher GDP. A higher. GDP is also expected to
improve the revenue position. At- the same time, in the absence of any
fiscal effort or other alternatives, the provincial governments'
additional recurring expenditure liabilities will exert a negative
impact on there venue/surplus position, which, may 'force these
governments to engage in borrowing from the State Bank in terms of use of cash balances. This activity of the provincial government will also
influence the overall deficit of the economy, as shown in Flow Chart 4.
Table 3 reports the numerical values of key variables due to the
above policy. It is interesting to note that while earmarking of
recurring expenditures improved the provision of the delivery of social
services in terms of more teachers to school, doctors to beds and RHC ratios, the fiscal budgetary positions of the provincial
governments-deteriorated. Debt servicing liabilities as well as the use
of cash -balances of the provinces in the case of the present type of
SAP financing scheme have increased by over 50 percent and 100 percent,
respectively, as compared to the earlier programme as shown in Table 2.
The overall deficit figures have also gone up by over 100 percent. These
rising budgetary, deficits of the provincial and federal governments due
to recurring liabilities are alarming and this will be one of the key
factors in making the SAP-type financing unsustainable in the long run.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
The key public policy issue that needs to be addressed in this
context is the alternative available to the governments to make the SAP
sustainable in the long run. One of the important policies that the
government may undertake in this context is to improve the revenue
position of the governments through higher fiscal efforts.
4.3. SAP with Resource Mobilisation
It is clear that a SAP-type programme, financed largely through
transfer of funds to the sub-national government, is not financially
sustainable in the long run. The high and rising debt servicing
liabilities a long with other operational requirements increase the
fiscal gap not only at the provincial but also at the overall national
level. However, if SAP is launched simultaneously with a strategy of
higher resource mobilisation by the provincial governments, the scenario
can change dramatically. Higher fiscal effort results in not only a
higher provincial expenditure but also prevents a deterioration in the
provincial and national budgetary position. Increased provincial
expenditure implies higher expenditure and higher inputs in social
sectors, and therefore higher social sector outputs, which exacerbates
the stimulatory impact on the GDP and, in turn, gross provincial
receipts (see Flow Chart 5).
In terms of magnitudes, Table 4 shows the key impacts of SAP a long
with higher provincial resource mobilisation. There are gains not only
in the social sector provisions, reflected in the improvement in the
social sector indices, but also in the fiscal status of the provincial
governments. There is an immediate draw down in the use of cash balances
(of over Rs 300 million) and also a substantial reduction in the overall
budget deficit of about Rs 3 billion in the long run. Also, there is a
significant increase in the growth in all the major sectors of the
economy.
On the whole, it appears that social sector development programmes
like the SAP not only have social benefits and improve the quality of
life of the masses, but that they also generate long-run economic
benefits in terms of higher GDP growth. SAP-type of initiative will be
successful if an effort is made by the provincial governments to enhance
their own revenues; otherwise such programmes may affect the public
finances of the country adversely.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This paper demonstrates that Pakistan does poorly in the social
indicators partly because of lower public outlays on the social sectors.
It examines the financial sustainability of a higher level of investment
in these sectors through the Social Action Programme in view of the
absence of any obvious source of revenue for financing the downstream
operation and the maintenance expenditures of the facilities created.
The basic conclusion is that since education and health are recurring
expenditure-intensive, the sustainability of the programme is in doubt.
The issue is quantitatively examined in the context of a large
macro-econometric model, with detailed modules for public finances and
the social sectors.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Policy simulations of the model in a medium- to long-run setting
lead to some striking conclusions. An allocation of funds through the
Social Action Programme can lead to gains in the GDP and improvements in
the social indicators. But this programme can exacerbate the problem of
the budget deficit. Even if some provisions are made for financing the
recurring expenditure within this programme, financial sustainability
will remain a problem after the end of the programme. Consequently, the
study makes a strong case for combining more intensive efforts at
provincial resource mobilisation a long with the launching of the SAP.
Authors' Note: Research support was provided by Nadeem Ahmed,
Nazia Bano, and Naveed Hanif. This study was funded by the Canadian
International Development Agency (CIDA) and the authors wish to thank
the Agency for providing financial support. The authors alone are
responsible for any errors.
REFERENCES
Lloyd-Ellis, H. (1993) Enterprise, Education, and the Distribution
of Gains from Growth. Paper presented at the "Macro-economic
Theory" conference. University of Victoria, Canada.
Pasha, H., M. A. Hasan, A. Ghaus, and A. Rasheed (1995) Integrated
Social Policy Macro-economic Planning Model for Pakistan. Karachi: SPDC publication.
Rostow, W. W. (1960) The States of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist
Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Tan, J., and A. Mingat (1992) Education in Asia: A Comparative
Study of Cost and Financing. The World Bank.
Urquidi, V. L. (1971) The So-called Social Aspects of Economic
Development. In A. B. Mountjoy (ed) Developing the Underdeveloped Countries. Macmillan Press. 76-86.
(1) For details on the specification and other aspects of the
model, readers may refer to Pasha et al. (1995).
Hafiz A. Pasha is Director. Institute of Business Administration,
Karachi. M. Aynul Hasan is Economic Adviser, CIDA. and teaches at Acadia
University in Canada. Aisha Ghaus is Research Economist, Applied
Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi. Ajaz Rasheed is
Systems Analyst, ISSP; Karachi.
Table 1
Socio-economic Indicators
GNP Population GNP
Growth Growth per
Rate Rate Capita
(%) (%) (US$)
Countries 1980-1991 1960-1992 1966 1992
Pakistan 6.5 3 120 420
Bangladesh 4.2 2.5 70 220
China 9.4 1.9 110 480
Egypt 4.5 2.4 180 650
India 5.5 2.2 90 310
Indonesia 5.8 2.1 40 680
South Korea 10 1.8 130 7220
Malaysia 5.6 2.6 340 2830
Nepal 4.7 2.4 80 170
Nigeria 1.4 2.8 70 330
Philippines 1.2 2.6 200 790
Singapore 7.1 1.7 590 16970
Sri Lanka 4.0 1.8 170 560
Adult Literacy Rate
(%)
Male Female Male Female
Countries 1970 1992
Pakistan 40 5 49 22
Bangladesh 15 1 49 23
China 87 * 68 * 92 68
Egypt n.a n.a 66 35
India 47 19 64 35
Indonesia 68 43 91 77
South Korea 94 81 99 95
Malaysia 69 42 89 72
Nepal 22 3 39 14
Nigeria n.a n.a 63 41
Philippines 84 81 90 90
Singapore 83 54 95 * 83 *
Sri Lanka 86 68 94 85
Gross Enrolment Ratios
Primary
Male Female Male Female
Countries 1960 1986-93
Pakistan 39 11 54 30
Bangladesh 80 31 83 71
China 131 90 125 116
Egypt n.a n.a. 101 * t n.a.
India 83 44 113 90
Indonesia 78 58 116 113
South Korea 108 94 101 103
Malaysia 108 79 93 94
Nepal 19 3 121 81
Nigeria n.a n.a 72 * t n.a.
Philippines 98 93 113 111
Singapore 120 101 110 107
Sri Lanka 107 95 109 105
Source: Human Development Report 1994.
Human Development Report 1995.
UNESCO, World Education Report 1992, 1993.
UNICEF, The State of the World Children 1995.
World Tables 1987, IVth Edition (for 1966).
Note: * 1990.
t(male and female combined).
Table 2
Impact of SAP Development Expenditure on Macro-economy
1992-93 1994-95 2002-03
A. Social Sector Variable
Primary Participation Rate 99.42 0.00 0.05
104.13 134.47
45.21 1.38 8.95
49.58 67.70
Teacher to School Ratio 2.29 0.000 0.002
2.376 3.085
3.68 -0.318 -0.308
3.542 3.258
Hospital Beds 52228 0 187
55486 68424
Rural Health Centre (RHC) 1375 0 136
1739 3534
Doctor to Bed Ratio 0.438 0.000 -0.001
0.472 0.621
Doctor to RHCs Ratio 8.38 0.000 -0.242
7.974 6.704
Human Capital Index 136.22 0.02 0.70
139.45 189.88
Public Health Index 241.38 0.34 5.83
272.83 410.64
B. Fiscal Variables
Provincial Dev. Expenditure (Social) 18,122 1,009 144
Provincial Rec. Expenditure (Social) 52,442 205 663
Debt Servicing 20,548 203 502
Gross Revenue Receipt 91,223 6 587
Use of Cash Balances 4,239 169 200
C. Macro Variables
Overall Budget Deficit 93,520 1,307 3,841
Value-added in Agriculture 122,894 12 508
Value-added in Manufacturing 85,534 3 340
Value-added in Other Sectors 277,337 12 651
Gross Domestic Product 542,291 28 1,638
Note: Numbers in Italics indicate Baseline Simulation Results.
Numbers in sections B & C represent change from the baseline
simulation due to the Rs 1 Billion increase for three consecutive
years.
Table 3
Impact of SAP Development with Recurring Expenditure on Macro-economy
1992-93 1994-95 2002-03
A. Social Sector Variable
Primary Participation Rate 99.42 0.45 1.20
104.13 134.47
45.21 1.27 6.02
49.58 67.70
Teacher to School Ratio 2.29 0.059 0.021
2.376 3.085
3.68 -0.031 -0.189
3.542 3.258
Hospital Beds 52228 0 142
55486 68424
Rural Health Centre (RHC) 1375 0 69
1739 3534
Doctor to Bed Ratio 0.438 0.013 0.001
0.472 0.621
Doctor to RHCs Ratio 8.38 0.858 -0.085
7.974 6.704
Human Capital Index 136.22 0.04 0.86
139.45 189.88
Public Health Index 241.38 4.98 3.57
272.83 410.64
B. Fiscal Variables
Provincial Dev. Expenditure (Social) 18,122 590 256
Provincial Rec. Expenditure (Social) 52,442 916 1,050
Debt Servicing 20,548 203 775
Gross Revenue Receipt 91,223 30 673
Use of Cash Balances 4,239 444 499
C. Macro Variables
Overall Budget Deficit 93,520 1,577 5,896
Value-added in Agriculture 122,894 27 645
Value-added in Manufacturing 85,534 4 297
Value-added in Other Sectors 277,337 23 709
Gross Domestic Product 542,291 55 1,792
Note: Numbers in Italics indicate Baseline Simulation Results.
Numbers in sections B & C represent change from the baseline
simulation due to the Rs I Billion increase for three consecutive
years.
Table 4 Impact of SAP Development with Resource Mobilisation on
Macro-economy
1992-93 1994-95 2002-03
A. Social Sector Variable
Primary Participation Rate 99.42 0.04 0.75
104.13 134.47
45.21 1.41 9.50
49.58 67.70
Teacher to School Ratio 2.29 0.005 0.039
2.376 3.085
3.68 -0.305 -0.266
3.542 3.258
Hospital Beds 52228 0 217
55486 68424
Rural Health Centre (RHC) 1375 0 151
1739 3534
Doctor to Bed Ratio 0.438 0.001 0.006
0.472 0.621
Doctor to RHCs Ratio 8.38 0.023 -0.19
7.974 6.704
Human Capital Index 136.22 0.02 0.89
139.45 189.88
Public Health Index 241.38 0.59 7.93
272.83 410.64
B. Fiscal Variables
Provincial Dev. Expenditure (Social) 18,122 1,060 587
Provincial Rec. Expenditure (Social) 52,442 429 2,304
Debt Servicing 20,548 183 145
Gross Revenue Receipt 91,223 1,161 6,817
Use of Cash Balances 4,239 -303 -1,634
C. Macro Variables
Overall Budget Deficit 93,520 565 -2,750
Value-added in Agriculture 122,894 18 688
Value-added in Manufacturing 85,534 9 542
Value-added in Other Sectors 277,337 27 970
Gross Domestic Product 542,291 333 2,822
Note: Numbers in Italics indicate Baseline Simulation Results.
Numbers in sections B & C represent change from the baseline
simulation due to the Rs 1 Billion increase for three consecutive
years.