Money supply, deficit, and inflation in Pakistan *.
Chaudhary, Mohammad Aslam ; Ahmad, Naved
1. INTRODUCTION
Inflation is a burning issue in Pakistan. It is generally felt that
for several years Pakistan has had a double-digit inflation. The public
sector has used a mix of policies to control inflation, and it is also
held responsible for its creation. The consumer price index (CPI)
increased over 11 percent in 1981-82, and over 12 percent in 1990-91.
Similarly, sensitive price index (SPI) increased over 15 percent in
1981-82, and over 12 percent in 1990-91. The GDP deflator was also
double-digit for several years. Inflation not only affects sectoral
allocation and distribution of income but also generates poverty. A
prescription might not be appropriate until the roots of the disease are
carefully investigated, which is the very reason for carrying out this
study.
Studies by Hossain (1990) several others concluded that inflation
is a monetary phenomenon in Pakistan, while Bilquees (1988) showed that
structural factors explained the inflationary process in Pakistan. It is
widely disagreed whether money supply is exogenous or endogenous. Vogel
(1974), criticising the monetarist approach, argued that further
research is needed on the determination of money supply. Given this
background, this study is intended to identify the variables leading to
inflation; the nature of money supply, endogenous or exogenous, is also
analysed.
Section 2 of the study provides a brief review of the literature. A
model is developed to study the relationship among fiscal deficit, money
supply, and inflation. Section 3 contains a description of the empirical
results. Section 4 provides the conclusion and policy implications.
2. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND LITERATURE REVIEW (SUMMARY)
The fiscal deficit in Pakistan has been alarming during the last
two decades. The fiscal deficit was around 7.4 percent of the GDP during
the period of 1970-80, and 7.6 percent during the 1980s. It was 8.5
percent in 1987-88 and around 7.9 percent in 199293. Inflation is
considered to be an outcome of the same. Studies on the issue have been
carried out by De Silva (1977), Aghevli (1977), Haan and Zelhorst
(1990), and Chaudhary and Parai (1991) for the LDCs. A similar analysis
was done by Hamburger and Zwick (1981), Protopapadakis and Siegal
(1987), and Burnhart and Darrat (1988) for the developed countries.
Haan and Zelhorst (1990) analysed the relationship between
government budget deficit and money growth in the developing countries.
The overall conclusion of this study did not provide much support for
the hypothesis that government budget deficit influences monetary
expansion and, therefore, create inflation. Chaudhary and Parai (1991)
have used a rational-expectations macro model of inflation to find out
the effect of the anticipated budget deficit on inflation rates for
Peruvian economy. They concluded that the country's huge budget
deficit as well as high rates of growth of money did have a significant
impact on the inflation rate. Similarly, there is much literature of
disagreement on whether money supply is exogenous or endogenous. [Khan
and Siddiqui (1990); Vogal (1974) and De Silva (1977)]. To study the
above issues, the following model is utilised.
The Model
The model described here is based on the monetarist and quantity
theory approach to inflation. Money supply equation may the form.
M = f(TR, GBNB, CR) ... ... ... ... (1)
TR = f(TR, BT, BFT) ... ... ... ... (2)
We take the demand and supply equations in log form. The
coefficient represents the respective elasticities. The demand for money
is a function of income (Y) and expected prices (EP).
M/P =f(Y, EP) ... ... ... ... (3)
The variables are defined as:
TR = International Reserves or foreign assets.
GBNB = Domestic financing of budget deficit including banking and
non-banking systems.
CR = Commercial banks credit to the private sector.
EP is the proxy for the cost of holding real balance. Following
Harberger, public adjust their expectation according to the following
relationship.
EP = [lambda]([EP.sub.t] - [Ep.sub.t-1]); 0 < [lambda] < 1
... ... ... (4)
The price equation is given as in the log forms which includes
lagged money supply (M), import price (PM) and demand shift variable
(CS).
In (P) = [C.sub.0] - [c.sub.1] hz(Y) + [c.sub.2] In(EP) + [c.sub.3]
In ([M.sub.2])
+ [c.sub.4] ln (PM) + [c.sub.5] ln (CSI) ... ... ... (5)
The output/income is a function of government expenditures (G.
EXP), credit (CR), real price of foreign exchange (RPFE), and exports
(X).
ln (g) = [d.sub.0] + [d.sub.1] In(GEXP) + [d.sub.2] In(CR) + +
[d.sub.3] In (RPFE) + [d.sub.4] In (X) ... ... ... (6)
The balance-of payment deficits is defined by exports, imports
(IC), and capital payments (KT).
Bt = Xt - ([IM.sub.2] + Ict + Kt) ... ... ... (7)
Finally, the supply of exports is a function of income (Y), export
price (PXP), and effective exchange rate (EER), as used by Aghevli
(1977). It is also taken in the log form.
So the complete model becomes:
In (M2) = [a.sub.0] + al In(TR) + [a.sub.2] In(GBNB) + [a.sub.3]
In(CR)
TRt = TRt-1 + bg + Btt
In(Md/P) = b0 + b1 In(Y) - [b.sub.2] In(EPt)
In(PI) = -co -[c.sub.1] In(Y) + [c.sub.2] In(EP) + [c.sub.3]
In([M2.sub.-1] +[c.sub.4] In(PM) + [c.sub.4] In(CSI)
In(Y) = do + dI In(GEXP) + [d.sub.2] In(CR) + [d.sub.3] In(RPFE)
+ [d.sub.4] In(X)
Bt = Xt-(lm2 + Ict + Kt)
In(X) = e0 + el In(Y) + [e.sub.2] In(PXP) + [e.sub.3] In(EER)
where:
Md, Ms, PI, Y, Bt, TR, and Xt are all endogenous, while EP, GENB,
CR, GEXP, PXP, PMt, CSI, RPFE and EER are all exogenous variables, which
have already been defined.
3. EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION AND RESULTS
We estimated the model using annual data for the periods 1973-92,
1973-82, and 1982-92. The basic model is simultaneous, which requires
the use of 2SLS. However, we have used the OLS method because, according
to De Silva (1977), the OLS method yields results roughly comparable to
those obtained from the 2SLS method. The estimated results are shown in
Tables l, 2, and 3.
First we have estimated the given model for the whole time-period
of 1973-92. The results are reported in Table 1. In Equation 1, the
coefficients of GBNB, TR, and CR are all positive and significant at 1
percent level of significance. It indicates that a l0 percent increase
in foreign reserves (TR) will increase each in money supply (M2) by 1.5
percent. GBNB will raise money supply by 1.51 percent, and Commercial
bank credit (CR) will increase the money supply by 6.4 percent. So
around 64 percent change in money supply is triggered by commercial bank
credit and 15 percent each by both domestic financing of budget deficits
(GBNB) and international reserves (TR).
In Equation 2 (Table 1), the signs of coefficient are all expected
and significant at 1 percent level of significance. As the level of
income increases by 10 percent, it will raise demand for money by 11
percent, which means that there are dis-economies of scale in holding
money, as usually happens in less developed economies because the income
elasticity of the demand for money is greater than unity. The expected
price level (as defined by Harberger) exerts negative pressure on real
money demand.
Equation 3 is the price equation. Level of output (Y), lagged money
supply (M2-1), and price of imports (PM) have expected sign and are
significant. To check the monetary model while relaxing the assumption
of the exogeneity of money supply, or to see the relationship between
the monetary and the fiscal policies, we find that a 10 percent increase
in lagged money supply and import prices will increase the price level
by 4.8 percent and 5 percent, respectively.
In Equation 4, we have used the Cochran-Orcutt method to take care
of autocorrelation. The sign of commercial credit (CR) is positive and
significant at 1 percent level of significance. Its contribution is 20
percent to the level of output. The government expenditure (GEXP) played
an important role in raising the economy's output. Furthermore,
government expenditures are also a source of inflation because the
government is forced to finance deficit resulting from non-commodity
producing expenditure such as transfer payments, food subsidy, and the
greater participation in social services. Since government expenditure
has a significant impact on Y, which affects the demand for money,
depending on the money market, this results in increasing the price
level.
In our final Equation 5, all coefficients are significant. The
positive sign of the coefficient of the ratio of unit value of exports
to consumer price index shows that as consumer price index increases, it
reduces the relative export prices, which, in turn, reduce the export. A
10 percent reduction in PXP will reduce the export by 4.9 percent. The
sign of output coefficient could either be positive or negative
depending on the income elasticity of domestic demand for exportable
goods. If the domestic demand for exportables rises more than
proportionally as income rises, coefficient of Y will be negative and
fewer goods will be exported. Here our study found a positive
relationship between output and exports.
The above discussion leads us to conclude that the financing of
government budget deficits through domestic sources leads to increases
in money supply and then the generation of inflation, which supports the
accommodation hypothesis. The accommodation hypothesis does not merely
state that budget deficit and money growth are positively correlated,
but also that the higher budget deficits un-directionally cause higher
money growth. Our finding--that long-run positive relationship between
budget deficit and money supply or inflation exists--is consistent with
the studies of De Silva (1977); Protopapadakis and Siegal (1987) and
Haan and Zelhorst (1990).
The model was estimated for two different time-periods, i.e., for
the 1970s and the 1980s. The results are reported in Table 2 and Table
3. The reason for this division of the time-period is that it is assumed
that when there is a balance-of-payments deficit, the only remedy is to
adjust the foreign reserves. This is only possible when we have a fixed
exchange rate. Under flexible exchange rate, the market adjusts to the
changes in the value of currency, which may correct the
balance-of-payments deficit. Here our aim is to analyse the relationship
between inflation and the exchange rate system. We intend to investigate
the issue whether the fixed or the flexible exchange rate system is the
more inflationary in nature.
During the decade of the 1970s, the coefficient of international
reserve (TR) is positive (0.104) and significant (Table 2). Moreover,
during 1980s, the effect of international reserve on money supply is
higher (i.e., 0.115) and significant (Table 3). The reason was that
during the flexible exchange rate system, government could depreciate the currency besides changing the foreign reserves to avoid a
balance-of-payments deficits. This depreciation would prevent a further
decrease in foreign reserves. So the contribution of foreign reserves is
larger. Besides, some deficits could be eliminated by taking advantage
of the flexible exchange rate system.
So far as the inflationary pressure in the flexible exchange rate
system is concerned, our findings showed that during 1980s the prior of
fixed exchange rate, have exerted pressure on the price level than
during 1970s. So here the flexible exchange rate system helped to
overcome the inflationary pressure during the 1980s. It is noticed that
during the flexible exchange rate system, a country is more open to
accommodate inflation.
The contribution of PXP is less (0.208) during the 1970s than in
the 1980s (1.3). It could be a result of the depreciation of the
Pakistani Rupees, when the prices of exports were higher in the
international market. Moreover, inflation is low during 1980s; so the
relative price of exports (PX) increases, which, in turn, increases the
exports, i.e., domestic export's become cheaper. This suggests that
devaluation, despite supply rigidities, raises exports. The empirical
results show that during the 1970s, the relationship between budget
deficit, money supply, and inflation holds, but not during the 1980s.
Our results suggest that there exists a positive relationship between
deficits and inflation for the period of 1970s, when inflation was high.
The relationship of deficit and money supply was not found significant
for the 1980s, when the Government borrowed from non-bank sources.
However, it might have led to crowding-out.
Our results pertaining to money supply indicated that the
phenomenon may not be exogenous but may in fact be determined by TR,
GBNB, and CR. With the changes in the sources of financing the budget
deficit, the signs of GBNB also changed, showing the reversal impact on
money supply. These findings are supported by Equation 1 (Tables 1, 2,
and 3). It is an important contribution to the literature since, so far,
it has always been assumed to be fixed and exogenous, which is not true,
as per our findings.
4. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Our findings suggest that the domestic financing of budget deficit,
particularly from the banking system, is inflationary in the long run.
Our results provide support for a positive relationship between budget
deficit and inflation during acute inflation periods, i.e., 1970s. We
also find that money supply is not exogenous; rather it depends on the
position of international reserves and fiscal deficit, and it has
emerged as an endogenous variable.
The general conclusion emerging from all evidence discussed in this
paper is that the execution of monetary policy may be determined by the
central bank, but the overall formulation of policy is heavily dependent
on the fiscal decisions made by the government. In order to control
inflationary pressure, government needs to cut the size of budget
deficit. It can perhaps be done by denationalising its numerous public
sector activities, and also by cutting down drastically the size of its
bureaucracy. Because there are many public utilities in which prices
tend to be fixed, or at least are not allowed to change with inflation,
a self-generating inflationary tendency occurs. The deficits arising in
public sector need to be made up by government, which increases its own
deficits. To finance this deficit, the money supply normally increases
on action, which itself reinforces inflation. This suggests that
government should take concrete and immediate steps to install a private
business environment, limit its own size, and encourage, initiative in
every sphere of economic life, if it is serious about controlling
inflation.
REFERENCES
Aghevli, B. B. (1977) Money, Prices and the Balance of Payment:
Indonesia 1968-73. Journal of Development Studies 13: 2.
Barnhart, S. W., and A. F. Darrat (1988) Budget Deficits, Money
Growth and Causality: Further OECD Evidence. Journal of International
Money and Finance 7:2.
Bilquees, F. (1988) Inflation in Pakistan: Empirical Evidence on
the Monetarist and Structuralist Hypotheses. The Pakistan Development
Review 27: 2.
Chaudhary, M. A. S., and A. K. Parai (1991). Budget Deficits and
Inflation: The Peruvian Experience. Applied Economics 23.
De Silva, K. E. A. (1977) Money Supply, Inflation and the Balance
of Payments in Sri Lanka 1959-74. The Journal of Development Studies 13:
2.
Haan, J. D., and D. Zelhorst (1990) The Impact of Government
Deficits on Money Growth in Developing Countries. Journal of
International Money and Finance 9: 4.
Hamburger, M. J., and B. Zwick (1982) Deficits, Money and
Inflation, Reply. Journal of Monetary, Economics 10:2.
Hossain, M. A. (1990) The Monetarist versus the Neo-Keynesian Views
on the Acceleration of Inflation: Some Evidence from South Asian
Countries (with special emphasis on Pakistan). The Pakistan Development
Review 29: 1.
Khan, A. H., and A. N. Siddiqui (1990) Money, Prices and Economic
Activity in Pakistan: A Test of Casual Relation. Pakistan Economic and
Social Review 27:2.
Protopapadakis, A. A., and J. Siegal (1987) Are Money Growth and
Inflation Related to Government Deficits? Evidence for Ten
Industrialised Economies. Journal of International Money and Finance
6:1.
Vogel, R. C. (1974) The Dynamics of Inflation in Latin America 1950-60. Applied Economics Review 64: 1.
Comments
In this study a simultaneous equation model has been discussed to
analyse the relationship between money supply, budget deficit, and
inflation. In this model, money supply, money demand, prices, output,
and exports are determined endogenously. The model is similar to the
model reported by the De Silva (1977), except for the price equation.
The authors argue that deficit financing through increase in money
supply is expected to generate inflation. The hypothesis, as suggested
in this study, has been tested in a number of empirical studies in a
simultaneous equation framework. However, the following aspects should
be discussed more clearly in this paper.
(1) The authors report a simultaneous equation model but they do
not estimate it simultaneously. The authors argue the Full Information
Maximum Likelihood (FIML) estimation method can not be used as it is
sensitive to specification errors. The authors could have used 2SLS
instead of FIML. Another argument is De Silva's assertion that
single equation estimation and simultaneous equation estimation give
similar results. The authors should test whether this is true tot
Pakistan also.
(2) The authors are using De Silva's model specification. They
could have improved the model by respecifying some equations. For
example, domestic demand component could be explicitly included in the
model. The budget deficit can be included in the price-level equation to
examine the direct impact of budget deficit on prices. Similarly, the
import demand function could be explicitly specified to examine the
impact of the price of imports.
(3) The authors also examine whether the changes in exchange rate
regimes (Fixed vs. Floating) affect the price level. For this purpose,
they estimate each equation, for each period separately, i.e., for the
1972-82 period and for the 1982-92 period. I do not understand the
rationale for separate equations for each sub-period when standard dummy
variable techniques can help us to test the hypothesis without the loss
of degrees of freedom. Furthermore, the application of dummy variable
technique can enable us to examine whether the numerical differences in
the coefficients are also statistically significant or not.
(4) The estimated equations should be discussed more clearly and
carefully. This section on results needs clarifications at the following
points:
(a) Table 1 shows that all the variables have expected signs except
for the output equation, where government expenditure and credit have a
negative effect on output. What is the explanation'?
(b) The authors interpret the coefficients as long-run estimates
but, in fact, these are short-run estimates.
(c) The results for sub-period models show a positive effect of
government expenditure and credit on output, but it is negative for the
whole period. What is the justification and rationale?
(5) In order to examine the basic hypothesis of the paper, it would
have been more appropriate to include higher order lagged values of the
explanatory variables. Only then can we say whether budget deficit
affects inflation or not, because it is the adjustment lag between
government expenditure and government revenue which leads to
inflationary financing of deficit. For example, De Silva (1977) and
Bilquees (1988), both, show that a 3-year lag of price of imports has a
statistically significant effect on the price level.
The authors also argue that the reason for the statistically
insignificant relationship between money supply and deficit, during the
1980s, is the rising proportion of public debt. In that case, it may be
more appropriate to include the public debt variable explicitly in the
analysis.
Rehana Siddiqui
Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad.
* Due to the space limitations, only a summary of the main study is
provided here. No detailed explanations are provided.
Mohammad Aslam Chaudhary is Associate Professor at the Quaid-i-Azam
University, Islamabad Naved Ahmad is Lecturer at the University of
Karachi.
Table 1
Results of Regression Analysis (1973-92: Annual Data)
1. Estimates of Money Supply Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.98
D.W. = 1.4
ln (M2) = 2.157 * + 0.151 ln (TR) *
(5.95) (3.44) F-stat = 589.1010
SE = 0.088
+ 0.151 ln (GBNB) *
(2.895)
+ 0.643 ln (CR) *
(11.052)
2. Estimates of Demand for Real Cash [R.sup.-2] = 0.96
Balance Equation D.W. = 1.75
ln (RLM2) = -7.506 * + 1.171 ln (Y) *
(-10.72) (20.824) F-stat = 250.8514
SE = 0.078
- 0.093 ln (EP) *
(-2.889)
3. Estimate of Price Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.99
D.W. = 1.4
ln (PI) = 5.675 ** - 0.712 ln (Y) **
(-2.612) (-2.84) F-stat = 893.0875
SE = 0.039
+ 0.486 ln (M21) *
(-5.301)
+ 0.504 ln (PM) *
(6.472)
4. Estimates of Output Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.98
D.W. = 2.14 (c)
ln (Y) = 7.593 * + 0.445 ln (GEXP) *
(16.555) (3.328) F-stat = 377.001
SE = 0.043
+ 0.205 ln (CR) *
(4.029)
5. Estimates of Export Supply Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.93
D.W. = 2.3
ln (X) = -12.891 * + 1.344 In (Y) *
(-10.66) (14.27) F-stat = 132.2261
SE = 0.134
+ 0.4901n (PXP) ***
(1.475)
Figures in parenthesis are t-values.
* = Significant at 1 percent.
** = Significant at 5 percent.
**** = Significant at 15 percent.
(c) Adjusted for Auto-correlation.
Table 2
Results of Regression Analysis (1973-82: Annual Data)
1. Estimates of Money Supply Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.99
D.W. = 2.24
ln (M2) = 1.307 * + 0.104 ln (TR) *
(7.428) (5.852) F-stat = 1949
SE = 0.021
+ 0.121 ln (GBNB) *
(8.533)
+ 0.795 ln (CR) *
(35.909)
2. Estimates of Demand for Real Cash [R.sup.-2] = 0.94
Balance Equation D.W. = 2.3
ln (RLM2) = -11.213 * + 1.468 ln (Y) *
(-7.429) (12.089) F-stat = 74.31
SE = 0.059
- 0.117 ln (EP) *
(-3.452)
3. Estimate of Price Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.97
D.W. = 1.7
ln (PI) = 12.077 ** - 1.398 ln (Y) ****
(1.564) (-1.682) F-stat = 112.1160
SE = 0.051
+ 0.668 ln (M21) **
(2.798)
+ 0.573 ln (PM) *
(4.334)
4. Estimates of Output Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.93
D.W. = 1.9 (c)
ln (Y) = 9.13 * + 0.061 ln (GEXP)
(16.69) (0.300) F-stat = 41.5819
SE = 0.041
+ 0.307 ln (CR) *
(3.78)
5. Estimates of Export Supply Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.77
D.W. = 2.2
ln (X) = -12.930 * + 1.347 ln (Y) *
(-4.334) (5.687) F-stat = 16.17
SE = 6.125
+ 0.208 1n (PXP)
(0.545)
Figures in parenthesis are t-values.
* = Significant at 1 percent.
** = Significant at 5 percent.
**** = Significant at 15 percent.
(c) Adjusted for Auto-correlation.
Table 3
Results of Regression Analysis (1982-92: Annual Data)
1. Estimates of Money Supply Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.96
D.W. = 2.4
ln (M2) = 4.069 * + 0.115 ln (TR) ****
(4.631) (1.715) F-stat = 84.54
SE = 0.077
- 0.335 ln (GBNB)
(-0.266)
+ 0.677 ln (CR) *
(6.568)
2. Estimates of Demand for Real Cash [R.sup.-2] = 0.83
Balance Equation D.W. = 2.2
ln (RLM2) = -3.781 *** + 0.879 ln (Y) *
(-2.082) (6.215) F-stat = 25.46
SE = 0.071
- 0.035 ln (EP)
(-0.749)
3. Estimate of Price Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.98
D.W. = 2.01
ln (PI) = 3.675 - 0.541 ln (Y)
(0.936) (-1.116) F-stat = 280.4111
SE = 0.025
+ 0.498 ln (M21) **
(2.742)
+ 0.421 ln (PM) *
(3.891)
4. Estimates of Output Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.97
D.W. = 1.6
ln (Y) = 7.726 * + 0.470 ln (GEXP) ***
(7.853) (1.991) F-stat = 166.8075
SE = 0.033
+ 0.177 ln (CR) **
(2.555)
5. Estimates of Export Supply Equation [R.sup.-2] = 0.80
D.W. = 2.2
ln (X) = -13.300 * + 1.368 ln (Y) *
(-4.04) (5.451) F-stat = 21.17036
SE = 0.149
+ 1.313 1n (PXP) ***
(1.953)
Figures in parenthesis are t-values.
* = Significant at 1 percent.
** = Significant at 5 percent.
**** = Significant at 15 percent.
(c) Adjusted for Auto-correlation.