Provision of public goods in an Islamic economy.
Akhtar, Muhammad Ramzan
1. INTRODUCTION
Islam establishes a welfare society. It obligates the society to
make arrangements for need-fulfilment of all citizens. The Islamic
economy working with the market and non-market institutions and guided
by Islamic values meets the personal and public needs of its people. The
market system in a secular economy under appropriate conditions can
efficiently meet personal needs of the people; however, it fails to do
so in case of public goods. While supplementing the market system with
other institutions, the Islamic economy manages to supply optimal
quantity of the public goods. The paper studies this issue in the light
of the Qur'an, the Sunnah, and Islamic history. (1)
2. ISSUES INVOLVED IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS
The public good is defined to be a good the consumption Of which by
one person does not reduce its availability to others in society. If we
denote Z as the total quantity supplied of a pure public good and
[Z.sub.a] and [Z.sub.b] quantity consumed by individuals A and B, then
we can write Z=[Z.sub.a]=[Z.sub.b]. The equality signs show that there
is no extra cost in supplying a given quantity of a public good to
additional people although its production involves extra cost. Moreover,
once a public good is supplied to individual A, it is difficult to
exclude individual B from enjoying its benefits. Defence, lighthouses,
police protection, and clean environment are examples of public goods.
There are very few pure public goods in the real world while many goods
reflect features of both public and private goods. These goods are
called mixed goods. Education and health are examples of such goods.
In our discussion by public goods, we mean both pure and mixed
public goods. Efficient supply of these goods encounters specific
problems in the market-type system. The demand of such goods faces the
free-rider problem. A large umber of people simultaneously participate
in enjoying a public good. Each one knows that it is impossible to
exclude him from its enjoyment. Therefore, he tries to be a free-rider
and avoids payments. Consequently, a smaller quantity of these goods is
produced, the implications of which may be quite dangerous.
The market system tails to meet the social demand of public goods
due to externalities and the market failure problem. Because of these
problems, the market-type system cannot both determine the optimal level
of demand for public goods and deliver its supply. Inevitably, the
political governments make decisions about the optimal level of demand
for public goods and finance their supply through public budget.
3. ISLAMIC VALUES, INSTITUTIONS, AND THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS
Islamic economy supplies the optimal amount of public goods with
the help of the market system. The market institution, while producing a
significant amount of public goods, creates the pollution problem--the
intensity of which can be considerably reduced by the observance of
Islamic values.
Market System
The economic agents in an Islamic economy seek the wider goal of
"pleasing Allah" (2) by serving the humanity. Service to
humanity induces them to expand the useful and contract the harmful
activities. (3) Accordingly, the producers tend to include welfare of
the society as an argument in their profit functions. A Muslim producer
keeping social interest in view restricts or expands output if it
produces pollution or emits beneficial effects. His decision-making is
guided by the principle of equalising market price to the marginal
social cost, which is defined as the sum of private and external
marginal cost.
For an illustration, assume a firm operating in competitive
environment generates a certain quantifiable amount of pollution per
unit of output. A Muslim and secular producer are likely to make
different output decisions in this environment. A Muslim producer is
likely to restrict the level of output while a secular producer will
not. Their likely choices are represented by the points M and S,
respectively, as shown in Figure 1.
The firm is facing a horizontal demand curve DD. Private marginal
cost is represented by PMC. Under the assumption that the firm is
generating a certain amount of pollution per unit of output called
external marginal cost (EMC), the SMC is obtained by adding PMC and EMC.
A Muslim producer chooses point M and a secular producer chooses point S
on the demand curve.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The level of output implied by point M is lower than S because OQ
is to the left of [OQ.sub.1]. It also reflects the optimum level of
output from the social point of view. This means that the quantity of
pollution in an Islamic economy is likely to be lower than in a secular
economy. Thus, the framework of an Islamic economy leads to socially
optimum allocation of resources if there exists a divergence between the
private and the social cost of production.
Islamic State
Islamic state bears ultimate responsibility of need-fulfilment of
its citizens. Normally, it does not interfere with the market forces.
However, in cases of market failures, it plays a proactive role. For
brevity, we focus on its role in the education sector. It is essential
to stress that education is treated as a public good in an Islamic
economy.
The early Islamic state assigned prime importance to education. The
Prophet (PBUH) freed the educated prisoners of Badar's war on the
condition that each one of them would teach 10 Muslims. The Prophet
(PBUH) sent the Sahabah in different parts of the state to teach
religious and basic knowledge to the people. Similarly, the four
rightly-guided Caliphs also attached great importance to education. Umar
(RA) set up a wide network for public instruction. Primary schools were
opened throughout the state where people were taught in groups while a
Sahabi would watch them. (4) Knowledge of Islamic law was made
compulsory. Every citizen was required to learn at least five Surahs:
al-Baqarah, al-Nisaa, al-Maida, al-Hajj, and al-Nur, as these contained
the core commandments and injunctions of Islam. (5) Governors of
provinces and commanders of the forces were required to teach religion
and law to the people in their jurisdiction. All expenses incurred in
this respect were met by the Bait-al-Mal.
Basic and religious education are activities the social benefit of
which exceeds the private benefit to a recipient. For example, a Muslim
obtains knowledge of saying correct prayer. Later on, he passes it on to
many people inside and outside the family. This leads to correcting of
prayers and other material activities of so many people due to the
effect of prayer. (6) The propagation of religious knowledge and basic
education is thus a case of full subsidisation. Figure 2 illustrates
this case.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In the absence of state intervention, DD and SS represent the
market demand and supply curves for education, respectively. The demand
curve reflects individual's valuation of education, i.e., private
marginal benefits (PMB). The external benefits (provided by the
education to the society) are shown by the external marginal benefit
curve (EMB), while the social marginal benefit (SMB) curve shows the
vertical sum of PMB and EMB. In the absence of any subsidy, OQ quantity
will be demanded and supplied at OP price. Now, the state gives a
subsidy equal to the amount of EMB which will shift the demand curve for
education upwards by the full amount of subsidy to D'D'. The
equilibrium quantity now increases to Pareto-optimal level of [QO.sub.1]
where the marginal social cost and benefit are equal. Net increase in
social welfare due to the extra quantity of education will be equal to
the area lying under triangle ACE.
Non-religious education like scientific and technical education is
essential for economic growth and poverty alleviation. It raises the
earning power of individuals. Moreover, it helps people better use their
nutritional and environmental resources. From the standpoint of society,
the number of people likely to benefit is larger than the number of
educated people. Therefore, for maximising social welfare, even the
nonreligious education cannot be left to be determined by market forces.
It is another case of subsidisation, the logic of which is illustrated
in Figure 3. Figure 3 employs the same set of curves as used in Figure
2. Since SMB exceeds PMB, therefore a subsidy equal to the amount of EMB
is warranted. The grant of this subsidy by the state shifts the demand
curve to D'D'. As a result, equilibrium quantity increases to
[QQ.sub.1] which increases social welfare by an area equal to triangle
ACE. The grant of subsidy again leads to optimal allocation of resources
in this case.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Voluntary Institution
The voluntary institutions have always played a vital role in
poverty alleviation, furthering of knowledge and education, and
promotion of social welfare activities in the Islamic society. These
institutions contribute in the form of charity, gift, grant, a will in
the legacy and awqaf. Here, the interest is to reflect the role of Waqf institution in catering to the demand for drinking-water in the Islamic
economy] It goes without saying that Islam recognises water as essential
for human life. (8) One hadith says: "People are partners in three
things: water, fodder, and fire". (9) Islamic teachings thus
motivate Muslims to extend the fullest co-operation in providing
drinking-water to the people. Companions of the Prophet (PBUH), inspired
by Islamic teachings, made voluntary arrangements for providing
drinking-water facilities. Some of these arrangements are mentioned
below.
Muslims were facing an acute shortage of water after their
migration to Medina. Usman (RA) bought the only drinking-water well in
Medina from a Jew and made it a Waqf for the benefit of all people. In
addition, he arranged for the construction of several other wells and
dedicated them for public use. All (RA) dedicated a well called Bier
Malik. He also dedicated several streams for the purpose. (10)
Similarly, other Companions of the Prophet (PBUH) also dedicated
drinking-water wells for the use of common people. It is important to
note that these voluntary actions took place before the construction of
drinking-water wells by the state. Even after their construction, the
voluntary actions continued and supplemented state efforts to ensure
optimal supply of drinking-water in the economy.
It is important to stress that the free-rider problem does not
arise if public goods are provided through voluntary institution in
general and through Waqf institution in particular. The reason is that
the dedicator desires that more and more people benefit from the
property dedicated. (11) Islamic history shows that Waqf institution
provided many public goods freely to the people and this resulted in
wide dissemination of positive externalities in the economy. (12)
Unit of Supply
Islamic economy supplies public goods through a network of
inter-related institutions, which reduces the cost of delivering these
goods. This network includes the departments of federal, provincial, and
local governments operating in an integrated structure of the Islamic
state. The structure provides decentralisation and vests wide economic
and administrative powers in the provinces to realise the goals of
need-fulfilment of the people. (13) The central and the provincial
governments supply those goods which they can do efficiently. For
instance, defence and religious education were earlier provided by the
central government while water and non-religious educational facilities
were provided by the provincial governments. The evidence reveals that
the central government allowed the provinces to collect Zakah and other
revenues for the welfare of local people. (14) Provinces had, therefore,
the means to provide specific public goods through these revenues. Many
services like rest houses, health clinics, and schools were voluntarily
provided by Waqf institutions and local people. It appears from the
study of these institutions that the nature of the benefit of public
goods determined the unit of supply. If the benefits of a public good
were widespread, then the central government arranged its supply
throughout the state. On the other hand, if the benefits were localised,
then the provincial or local governments were responsible for its
provision. From the efficiency point of view, this was the best
arrangement.
4. CONCLUSION
This paper has discussed the provision of public goods in an
Islamic economy. It notes an obligation of this economy to satisfy the
basic needs of all people, which in part depends on the satisfaction of
public goods. In this context, it discusses the free-rider and
externality problems. The paper argues that Islamic economy is in a
better position to address these problems than its counterpart secular
economy. Accordingly, this economy can supply the optimal amount of
public goods.
The paper finds an active role for the Islamic state. It acts
independently as well as in conjunction with the market and non-market
institutions in the economic arena. In this context, it discusses the
role of the state in providing religious and basic education, which
brings substantial welfare benefits to the society. In addition to its
role in the public sector, the Islamic state strengthens the role of the
private sector through the incentive system.
The paper finds that the voluntary institutions were the main
source of supply of public goods. Focusing on drinking-water, it finds
that the social demand for drinking-water was initially met through Waqf
institution. Such institution generated long-term benefits for the
maximum number of people.
In sum, it is found that an Islamic economy is capable of meeting
the social demand of public goods with the help of its institutions and
value system.
(1) In all references to the Quran in this paper, the first number
refers to the surah and the second to the ayah.
(2) ".... I may work righteousness such as though mayest
approve ..." the Quran, (46-15).
(3) The Prophet (PBUH) said, "All human beings are dependents
of Allah and the most beloved of them before Him is he who is good to
His dependents." Walial-din-Tabrizi, Mishkat al-Masabih, Vol. 2
0-413m 4998.
(4) Muhammad Bin Yazid al-Qazoni, Sunun Ibn Maja, Vol. 1, p. 81
(224).
(5) Shibli Numani Omar the Great, tr. by Muhammad Saleem, p. 431.
(6) The Quran says, ".... For prayers restrain from shameful
and unjust deeds...." (29:45).
(7) A stimulating account of this institution is given in A.A.
Islahi's paper, "Provision of Public Goods: Role of Voluntary
(Waqf) Sector in Islamic Economy", which was presented at the Third
International Conference on Islamic Economics, held in Malaysia (28-30
January, 1992).
(8) "... We made alive everything with water ..." The
Quran (21 : 30).
(9) Yahya Bin Adam Kitab-ul-Khiraj, p. 123.
(10) Op. cit., p. 63.
(11) A tradition of the Prophet (PBUH) says, "He who grows a
crop or plants a plant which a person or beast or bird eats, that will
be accounted as an act of Sadaqah". (Yahya bin Adam, Kitab al
Khiraj, p. 82.
(12) Abdul Salam Nadvi, "Uswah-i-Sahabah" (Urdu), p. 61.
(13) Abdul Khaliq, "Concept of Regional Rights in Islam",
(Urdu), pp. 18-31.
(14) Ibid.
Muhammad Ramzan Akhtar is Professor of Economics at the
International Institute of Islamic Economics, International Islamic
University, Islamabad.